Factor Endowments, Relative Commodity Prices, and Anything Goes (Summary) by Hugo Sonnenschein University of Chicago

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Factor Endowments, Relative Commodity Prices, and Anything Goes (Summary) by Hugo Sonnenschein University of Chicago Factor Endowments, Relative Commodity Prices, and Anything Goes (Summary) by Hugo Sonnenschein University of Chicago Fifty years ago T. M. Rybczynski [3] published a frequently referenced note in which he inaugurated a systematic investigation of the comparative statics associated with a change in the endowment of a factor. The questions that he posed are broad and fundamental: How do the prices and consumptions of final goods depend on factor endowments? How do factor prices and consumer wealth vary with changes in factors endowments? What are the welfare impli- cations of these changes? Rybczynski considered a closed economy with two factors of production A and B and two consumption goods X and Y ,each produced according to constant returns to scale and perfect competition. He argued that if X is A intensive and Y is B intensive, then an increase in A leads to an increase in the equilibrium output of X and a decrease in the equilibrium output of Y , provided that the marginal rate of transformation in production between X and Y (MRT(X, Y )) does not change when one moves from the orig- inal to the new equilibrium. In other words, under Rybczynski’s assumptions, the expanded production possibilities associated with a factor increase, which allows for an increased production of both outputs, leads in equilibrium to an increase in just one of the two outputs (the one that is intensive in the factor that has increased) and a decrease in the other. This unambiguous compara- tive statics result has been applied to the case of international trade in which an economy is small (more properly infinitesimal), so that the MRT at every interior equilibrium is determined by international prices and does not change. Rybczynski understood that in a closed economy MRT(X, Y ) at equilibrium varies with factor endowments (this is a general equilibrium effect), and he pro- vided a rather complete analysis of how outputs (which are equal to consump- tions in a closed economy) and prices will change in a closed economy following an increase in A. In particular, Rybczynski argued that in the absence of inferior goods, an increase in the amount of factor A leads to an increase in X,butthat the effect on Y is ambiguous. Furthermore it is apparent that he understood that with X inferior, an increase in A can lead to an absolute decrease in X and an increase in Y . Wewillcallthisoutcome"reverseRybczynski". Itisanex- ample of "extreme comparative statics". The purpose of this note is to extend the Rybczynski analysis more fully to general equilibrium by considering economies with more than one consumer, and in particular, to extend his analysis to the 2 2 2 Heckscher-Ohlin model of international trade. The investigation is inspired× × by the work of Cheng, Sachs, and Yang [1] who conjecture that in the Heckscher-Ohlin model the relationship between factor endowments, outputs, and commodity prices can be quite arbi- trary. Their conjecture was based on the S-M-D Theorem on the structure of excess demand functions( which has been referred to as "Anything Goes", see [2] 1 and [4]). Cheng and her co-authors observe that the particular functional forms that they use in their presentation restricts their comparative statics. Here, by not restricting functional forms, we are able to obtain more extreme compara- tive statics, even while ruling out inferior goods, and thus we are able to come closer to establishing that "anything goes" in the Heckscher-Ohlin model. One should note that ambitions of this paper are in other ways significantly different than those in [1]; namely, here I faithfully follow the classical Rybczynski pro- gram: transaction costs are ignored and the extreme comparative statics that are illustrated take place at interior equilibria. In the Heckscher-Ohlin model that we consider here production functions are CRS and identical across countries. Factor endowments are different in the two countries and we make the strong assumption that demand in each country is generated by a single consumer with homothetic preferences; in particular, no goods are inferior. (It is this final assumption that gives our result weight.) As before,weassumethatX is A intensive. Nevertheless, we show that in general equilibrium it is possible for an increase in the amount of factor A in the first country to lead to a decrease in the equilibrium output of X in that country (and the other country as well.) In other words, in general equilibrium, and without the small country assumption, the output implications of an increase in a factor endowment can be the reverse of what is established in the Rybczynski analysis; that is, "reverse Rybczynski", even with no inferior goods.1 At the heart of the demonstration is the fact that in general equilibrium an increase in the amount of A in the home country can lead to an arbitrarily large rate of decrease in the relative price of X, and thus a decline in the amount of X produced. The proof uses a homothetic preferences version of "anything goes" (see [4]). Three other comparative statics results are observed. First, if preferences are identical and homothetic in the Heckscher-Ohlin model, then reverse Rybczynski is not possible (since the demand sector of the economy is "as if" there was a single consumer with homothetic preferences: this is Eisenberg’s Theorem, see [4]). Second (with M. Opp), reverse Rybczynski can be obtained in a closed economy with two consumers, each with homothetic preferences.2 To state this more finely: the reversal that Rybczynski observed is possible in a closed economy with an inferior good does not require inferiority. Instead, with non identical preferences, the reversal can be driven by changes in the distribution of income associated with the change in factor prices. Finally, in a closed economy with a single consumer and homothetic preferences, Rybczynski observed that his result is moderated in the sense that following the factor increase, the relative price of the good that is intensive in the factor that is increased must decrease, and so there is a tendency for the output (and consumption) of both goods 1 Furthermore, "reverse Rybczynski" can be demonstrated in an economy in which equi- librium is unique both before and after the increase in A. 2 The closed economy result follows directly from the previous result; however, the con- struction that we use to prove the closed economy result is not sufficient to prove our main theorem. 2 to rise. However, even with homothetic preferences, with two consumers it is possible that the price of the good that is intensive in the factor that is increased will increase, in which case the Rybczynski effect is amplified: the output of Y falls even more. References [1] Cheng, W. L.., Sachs, J., Yang, X.(2000), "A General Equilibrium Re- appraisal of the Stolper-Samuelson Teorem", Journal of Economics, pp.1-18. [2] Mas-Colell, A. et al(1995), Microeconomic Theory,OxfordUniversity Press, Section 17E. [3] Rybczynski, T. M.,(1955), "Factor Endowments and Relative Commodity Prices", Economica, pp. 336-41. [4] W. Shafer and H. Sonnenschein(1982), "Market Demand and Excess De- mand Functions", Handbook of Mathematical Economics,vol.2,K.Arrowand M. Intriligator, eds., Chapter 14. Note: See my web page at the Department of Economics, University of Chicago (http://home.uchicago.edu/~hfsonnen/) for a sketch of the proof of the main result and for various diagrams that are used in the presentation. 3.
Recommended publications
  • BIS Working Papers No 136 the Price Level, Relative Prices and Economic Stability: Aspects of the Interwar Debate by David Laidler* Monetary and Economic Department
    BIS Working Papers No 136 The price level, relative prices and economic stability: aspects of the interwar debate by David Laidler* Monetary and Economic Department September 2003 * University of Western Ontario Abstract Recent financial instability has called into question the sufficiency of low inflation as a goal for monetary policy. This paper discusses interwar literature bearing on this question. It begins with theories of the cycle based on the quantity theory, and their policy prescription of price stability supported by lender of last resort activities in the event of crises, arguing that their neglect of fluctuations in investment was a weakness. Other approaches are then taken up, particularly Austrian theory, which stressed the banking system’s capacity to generate relative price distortions and forced saving. This theory was discredited by its association with nihilistic policy prescriptions during the Great Depression. Nevertheless, its core insights were worthwhile, and also played an important part in Robertson’s more eclectic account of the cycle. The latter, however, yielded activist policy prescriptions of a sort that were discredited in the postwar period. Whether these now need re-examination, or whether a low-inflation regime, in which the authorities stand ready to resort to vigorous monetary expansion in the aftermath of asset market problems, is adequate to maintain economic stability is still an open question. BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy, Relative Prices and Inflation Rate: an Evaluation Based on New Keynesian Phillips Curve for the U.S
    Monetary policy, relative prices and inflation rate: an evaluation based on New Keynesian Phillips Curve for the U.S. economy Tito Belchior Silva Moreira* Department of economy, Catholic University of Brasilia, Brazil: [email protected] Mario Jorge C. Mendonça Department of economics, Institute for Applied Economic Research, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil: [email protected] Adolfo Sachsida Department of economics, Institute for Applied Economic Research, Brasília, Brazil: [email protected] Paulo Roberto Amorim Loureiro Department of economics, University of Brasilia, Brasília, Brazil: [email protected] Abstract This paper investigates the direct impact of monetary policy on variation to the relative prices and, in turn, the direct effect of the change in relative prices on the inflation rate considering the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC). Thus, we analyze the indirect impact of the change of Federal Funds Rate on the inflation rate through the change in relative prices. We use GMM with instrumental variables to estimate several systems of two equations for the U.S. economy based on quarterly time-series from 1975 to 2015. The empirical results show that a change of the Funds Rate has a direct effect on change in relative prices and that, in turn, affects indirectly the inflation rate, through the change in relative prices. Hence, change in the relative prices affects directly the inflation rate via NKPC. In this context, variations of relative prices can be interpreted as a transmission channel of monetary policy. Furthermore, there are empirical evidences that the change of relative prices Granger-cause the inflation rate. Key words: Monetary policy, relative prices, inflation rate, NKPC, U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The Ricardian Model
    Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Preview • Opportunity costs and comparative advantage • Production possibilities • Relative supply, relative demand & relative prices • Trade possibilities and gains from trade • Wages and trade • Misconceptions about comparative advantage • Transportation costs and non-traded goods • Empirical evidence Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 3-2 Introduction • Sources of differences across countries that lead to gains from trade: – The Ricardian model (Chapter 3) examines differences in the productivity of labor (due to differences in technology) between countries. – The Heckscher-Ohlin model (Chapter 5) examines differences in labor, labor skills, physical capital, land, or other factors of production between countries. Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 3-3 Ricardian Model Assumptions 1. Two countries: domestic and foreign. 2. Two goods: wine and cheese. 3. Labor is the only resource needed for production. 4. Labor productivity is constant. 5. Labor productivity varies across countries due to differences in technology. 6. The supply of labor in each country is constant. 7. Labor markets are competitive. 8. Workers are mobile across sectors. Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 3-4 Comparative Advantage • Suppose that the domestic country has a comparative advantage in cheese production: its opportunity cost of producing cheese is lower than in the foreign country. * * aLC /aLW < a LC /a LW When the domestic country increases cheese production, it reduces wine production less than the foreign country does because the domestic unit labor requirement of cheese production is low compared to that of wine production.
    [Show full text]
  • On Using Relative Prices to Measure Capital-Specific Technological
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES On Using Relative Prices to Measure Capital-Specific Technological Progress Milton Marquis Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and Florida State University and Bharat Trehan Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco March 2005 Working Paper 2005-02 http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/2005/wp05-02bk.pdf The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. On Using Relative Prices to Measure Capital-Specific Technological Progress Milton Marquis∗ Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and Florida State University and Bharat Trehan∗∗ Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco March 2005 Abstract Recently, Greenwood, Hercowitz and Krusell (GHK) have identified the rela- tive price of (new) capital with capital-specific technological progress. In a two- sector growth model, however, the relative price of capital equals the ratio of the productivity processes in the two sectors. Restrictions from this model are used with data on wages and prices to construct measures of productivity growth and test the GHK identification, which is easily rejected by the data. This raises ques- tions about various measures of the contribution that capital-specific technological progress might make to the economy. This identification also induces a negative correlation between the resulting measures of capital-specific and economy-wide technological change, which potentially explains why papers employing this iden- tification find that capital-specific technological change accelerated in the mid- 1970s.
    [Show full text]
  • The Limit-Price Dynamics - Uniqueness, Computability and Comparative Dynamics in Competitiive Markets Gaël Giraud
    The Limit-Price Dynamics - Uniqueness, Computability and Comparative Dynamics in Competitiive Markets Gaël Giraud To cite this version: Gaël Giraud. The Limit-Price Dynamics - Uniqueness, Computability and Comparative Dynamics in Competitiive Markets. 2007. halshs-00155709 HAL Id: halshs-00155709 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00155709 Submitted on 19 Jun 2007 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Documents de Travail du Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne The Limit-Price Dynamics — Uniqueness, Computability and Comparative Dynamics in Competitive Markets Gaël GIRAUD 2007.20 Maison des Sciences Économiques, 106-112 boulevard de L'Hôpital, 75647 Paris Cedex 13 http://ces.univ-paris1.fr/cesdp/CES-docs.htm ISSN : 1955-611X The Limit-Price Dynamics | Uniqueness, Computability, and Comparative Dynamics in Competitive Markets GaÄelGiraud1), 2)¤ 1) Paris School of economics, CNRS 2) Universit¶eParis-1 Panth¶eon-Sorbonne [email protected] April 30, 2007 Abstract.| In this paper, a continuous-time price-quantity trading process is de¯ned for exchange economies with di®erentiable characteristics. The dynamics is based on boundedly rational agents exchanging limit-price orders to a central clearing house, which rations in¯nitesimal trades according to Mertens (2003) double auction.
    [Show full text]
  • The Law of One Price Without the Border: the Role of Distance Versus Sticky Prices
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LAW OF ONE PRICE WITHOUT THE BORDER: THE ROLE OF DISTANCE VERSUS STICKY PRICES Mario J. Crucini Mototsugu Shintani Takayuki Tsuruga Working Paper 14835 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14835 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 April 2009 We are indebted to Chikako Baba, Paul Evans and Masao Ogaki for valuable comments on the earlier draft. We also thank seminar participants at Hitotsubashi, Osaka, Queen's, and Tohoku University and Bank of Canada and Bank of Japan for helpful comments and discussions. Mario J. Crucini and Mototsugu Shintani gratefully acknowledge the financial support of National Science Foundation (SES-0136979, SES-0524868). Takayuki Tsuruga gratefully acknowledges the financial support of Grant-in-aid for Scientific Research. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2009 by Mario J. Crucini, Mototsugu Shintani, and Takayuki Tsuruga. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. The Law of One Price Without the Border: The Role of Distance Versus Sticky Prices Mario J. Crucini, Mototsugu Shintani, and Takayuki Tsuruga NBER Working Paper No. 14835 April 2009 JEL No. D4,F40,F41 ABSTRACT We examine the role of nominal price rigidities in explaining the deviations from the Law of One Price (LOP) across cities in Japan.
    [Show full text]
  • More Examples
    Microeconomics and Macroeconomics What is microeconomics? Microeconomics deals with the behavior of individual consumers, households, and businesses. What is macroeconomics? Macroeconomics deals with national economic policy and growth. Both microeconomic and macroeconomic principles can affect consumer decision making. This chapter deals with microeconomic concepts that affect consumer decision making. Concept 1: Nominal Price vs. Relative Price What is nominal price (NP)? Notations The prices we see in stores. Example: Nominal price of pork: $2.00, Nominal price RPx=relative price of commodity x of beef: $3.00 NPx=nominal price of commodity x What is relative price (RP)? NP b=nominal price of the base commodity The price of one commodity is compared to the price of another commodity (base commodity). Note: Base commodity is whatever commodity you RPx = NPx / NP b choose as the comparison basis. Example: If we use pork as the base commodity, then the relative price of beef RPbeef=NPbeef/NPpork=$3.00/$2.00=1.5 This means the price of beef is 1.5 times the price of pork. What are the implications of More Examples Relative Prices (RP)? If the nominal price of pork (NPpork) is $2.00, the Consumers make decisions based on relative prices rather nominal price of chicken (NPchicken) is $1.50, and the than nominal prices nominal price of shrimp (NPshrimp) is $6.00. Using For example, the price of beef stays the same at $3.00/lb over time. If pork price has changed from $2.00/lb to $10.00/lb, pork as the base commodity, what is the relative price consumers will buy more beef instead because beef is now (RP) of chicken and shrimp? relatively a lot cheaper compared to pork.
    [Show full text]
  • Relative Prices in the Classical Theory: Facts and Figures
    RELATIVE PRICES IN THE CLASSICAL THEORY: FACTS AND FIGURES CHRISTIAN BIDARD AND HANS G. EHRBAR Current version available at http://www.econ.utah.edu/˜ehrbar/rpff.pdf Abstract. This paper surveys, extends and illustrates recent results on the movement of relative prices of production when distribution changes. Date: September 1996 (literature list updated January 2007). 1 2 Contents 1. Curves of Prices of Production 3 1.1. Representation of the Technology 3 1.2. Definition of Prices of Production 4 1.3. Normalizations 4 1.4. Barycentric Coordinates 5 1.5. Special Normalizations 6 2. Intersections of Price Curves 7 2.1. Same Input Matrix: At Most One Intersection Point 7 2.2. A Surprising Collineation 8 2.3. Radial “Stretching” of the Price Curves 8 2.4. Nonintersection of “Long” Price Curves 9 3. The Shapes of the Price Curves 12 3.1. The Degree of Regularity of an Economy 12 3.2. Orientation 14 3.3. Discussion of the Case n = 3 14 3.4. Projective Geometry: Classification of all Collineations 14 3.5. Two Types of Transition 15 4. Comparative Statics 15 4.1. Attractive Hyperplanes and Hyperellipses 16 4.2. Euclidean Angles Between Price Vectors 17 4.3. Arbitrary Normalization 18 4.4. The Inverse Problem: Determining Input Coefficients from Prices 18 5. Hilbert Circles 19 5.1. Definition 19 5.2. Hilbert Circles are Attractive 21 5.3. Speed of Convergence 22 6. Outlook: Additional Results for n = 3 23 7. Conclusion 23 Appendix A. Mathematical Proofs 24 Representations of the Technology 24 Normalizations 24 The Price Space of an Economy 26 Identification of Price Curves and of Technical Data 28 Intersection of Price Curves 29 Tangents 31 Decomposition of Price Curves 32 Degrees of Regularity 2 and 3 34 Euclidean Angle Between Price Vectors 34 Hilbert Circles 34 Conics 37 References 39 Whereas labor values are independent of distribution, prices of production vary if profits rise at the expense of wages or vice versa.
    [Show full text]
  • Notation Guide This Notation Guide Is Taken from Foundations of International Macroeconomics,Bymaurice Obstfeld and Kenneth Rogo® (°C MIT Press, September 1996)
    Foundations of International Macroeconomics Notation Guide This notation guide is taken from Foundations of International Macroeconomics,byMaurice Obstfeld and Kenneth Rogo® (°c MIT Press, September 1996) Maurice Obstfeld Kenneth Rogo® University of California at Berkeley Princeton Unviversity 1. Introduction This notation guide and symbol glossary provides a brief summary of the book's basic notational conventions. Symbol usage is generally covered by the self- contained discussion within each chapter, but for convenience we also include here a listing of major symbol conventions that recur throughout the book. 2. Label Conventions A number of our basic conventions for labeling variables can best be explained using consumption as an example. 2.1. One-Good, Representative-Agent Models ci: Consumption of agent i c: Average per capita consumption. C: Total aggregate consumption. However, in representative-agent models, we typically normalize the population size to 1 and use C to denote both aggregate as well as individual consumption. (Nuance: In Chapters 4 and 10, C is a repre- sentative agent's consumption of a utility-weighted basket of di®erent goods.) c: The lowercase sans serif font refers to log C (or, in Chapters 7 and 10, an approximate log deviation of C from an initial baseline path). 2.2. Subscripts Ct:Datetconsumption (or Cs; for date s consumption) Subscripts alongside t or s denote a type of good. For example: Cn,t: Consumption of nontradables on date t. (T is used for traded goods, H for home goods, F for foreign goods) 2.3. Superscripts Superscripts other than i or j refer to a type of agent, for example: co,i: Consumption of agent i, a member of the old generation.
    [Show full text]
  • Ricardian Model – Part 1
    Lecture 2a: Ricardian Model – part 1 Thibault FALLY C181 – International Trade Spring 2018 In this chapter we will examine the following topics: • Brief summary of reasons to trade and specialize • Brief history of Ricardian model • Ricardian model In this chapter we will examine the following topics: • Brief summary of reasons to trade and specialize • Brief history of Ricardian model • Ricardian model: • PPF • Autarky equilibrium • Export patterns • Wages • International prices • Equilibrium with international trade • Gains from trade in the Ricardian model 1 Reasons for Trade Reasons countries trade with each other include: ■ Differences in the technology used in each country ■ Differences in the total amount of resources (including labor, capital, and land) ■ Differences in tastes ■ Imperfect competition, product differentiation 1 Reasons for Trade Reasons countries trade more with some countries than others include: ■ Proximity of countries to each other ■ Low communication/coordination costs ■ Low bilateral tariffs and FTA, etc. 1 Reasons for Trade Resources • Natural resources (e.g. land and minerals) - Includes energy resources (e.g. coal, petroleum) • Labor resources (by skill level) • Capital (machinery and structures) Vocabulary: Resources = “Factors of production” = “Endowments” 1 Reasons for Trade Technology? Two aspects: • Absolute advantage When a country has the best technology for producing a good. • Comparative Advantage A country has a comparative advantage in producing those goods that it produces best compared with
    [Show full text]
  • The Relative Price of Services
    bs_bs_banner Review of Income and Wealth Series 60, Number 4, December 2014 DOI: 10.1111/roiw.12012 THE RELATIVE PRICE OF SERVICES by Robert Inklaar* and Marcel P. Timmer Groningen Growth and Development Centre, University of Groningen Prices of GDP relative to the exchange rate increase with income per capita, which is known as the Penn-effect. This is generally attributed to services being cheaper relative to goods in poorer countries. In this paper we re-examine the Penn-effect based on a new set of PPPs for industry output. These are estimated in an augmented Geary–Khamis approach using prices for final goods, exports, and imports. The resulting multilateral PPPs cover 35 industries in 42 countries for the year 2005. We find large variation in relative prices of various services industries. In particular the Penn-effect appears to be mostly due to the rapidly rising output prices of non-market services. This seems related mainly to the high labor intensity of that sector. JEL Codes: C43, F4, O11, O47 Keywords: Geary-Khamis system, Penn-effect, PPP, prices, services 1. Introduction A stylized fact that has proven very durable in the economic literature is that price levels of GDP relative to the exchange rate rise with income per head, with empirical support going back as far as (at least) Balassa (1964).1 This empirical regularity is known as the “Penn-effect” (Samuelson, 1994). It has been explained by arguing that rising income is related to technical change that leads to higher productivity growth in the tradable goods sector, relative to non-tradables.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction
    Introduction Countries engage in international trade for two basic reasons: • They are different from each other in terms of climate, land, capital, labor, and technology. • They try to achieve scale economies in production. The Ricardian model is based on technological differences across countries. • These technological differences are reflected in differences in the productivity of labor. Copyright © 2003 Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 2-1 The Concept of Comparative Advantage On Valentine’s Day the U.S. demand for roses is about 10 million roses. Growing roses in the U.S. in the winter is difficult. • Heated greenhouses should be used. • The costs for energy, capital, and labor are substantial. Resources for the production of roses could be used to produce other goods, say computers. Copyright © 2003 Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 2-2 The Concept of Comparative Advantage Opportunity Cost • The opportunity cost of roses in terms of computers is the number of computers that could be produced with the same resources as a given number of roses. Comparative Advantage • A country has a comparative advantage in producing a good if the opportunity cost of producing that good in terms of other goods is lower in that country than it is in other countries. Copyright © 2003 Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 2-3 The Concept of Comparative Advantage Suppose that in the U.S. 10 million roses can be produced with the same resources as 100,000 computers. Suppose also that in Mexico 10 million roses can be produced with the same resources as 30,000 computers. This example assumes that Mexican workers are less productive than U.S.
    [Show full text]