Sovereign Debt Restructuring: a Model-Law Approach

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: a Model-Law Approach JGD 2016; aop Steven L. Schwarcz* Sovereign Debt Restructuring: A Model-Law Approach DOI 10.1515/jgd-2015-0031 Abstract: Unlike individuals and corporations, countries indebted beyond their ability to pay cannot use bankruptcy laws to restructure unsustainable debt. The United Nations and the International Monetary Fund have attempted to propose treaties to enable that debt restructuring, but the political difficulties of reaching a worldwide consensus have stymied their efforts. This article argues that a model- law approach to restructuring unsustainable sovereign debt should be feasible and effective because the vast majority of sovereign debt contracts are governed by the laws of either the debtor-state or two other jurisdictions. Those jurisdic- tions individually could enact a model law to give struggling nations a real pros- pect of equitably restructuring their debt to sustainable levels. By ena bling such debt restructuring, that enactment would also help to foster the norms required to facilitate the development of international treaties. 1 Introduction Recent court decisions in the UK regarding the illegality of exit consents1 and in the US regarding pari passu clauses in Argentine sovereign debt,2 as well as 1 The Chancery Division of the English High Court held, in the Anglo Irish case Assénagon Asset Man- agement S.A. v. Irish Bank Resolution Corporation Limited (formerly Anglo Irish Bank Corporation Lim- ited) [2012] EWHC 2090 (Ch), that exit consents are illegal, casting doubt on the effectiveness of exit consents to restructure debt under English law. See, e.g. Patrick S. Kenadjian, The Aggregation Clause in Euro Area Government Securities, in Collective Action Clauses and the Restructuring of Sovereign Debt 143 (Patrick S. Kenadjian, Klaus-Albert Bauer and Andreas Cahn, eds. 2013) (observing that the judge in the Anglo Irish case “held that it was not lawful for the majority to aid in the coercion of a mi- nority by voting for a resolution which expropriates the majority’s rights for nominal consideration[,] thus cast[ing] doubt on the legality under English law of any form of exit consent that imposes less favorable conditions on those who refuse to par ticipate in the associated exchange offer.”). Al though exit consents have been severely criticized in the US, they have survived judicial challenges made by minority bondholders. See Katz v. Oak Indus. Inc., 508 A.2d 873 (Del. Ch. 1986). 2 NML Capital, Ltd. v. Republic of Argentina, No. 08–CV–6978 TPG, 2012 WL 5895786 (S.D.N.Y. Nov. 21, 2012) (holding that the pari passu clause in Argentina’s defaulted bonds contract *Corresponding author: Steven L. Schwarcz, The Stanley A. Star Professor of Law and Business, Duke University School of Law, P.O. Box 90360, Durham, NC 27708-0360, USA, e-mail: schwarcz@ law.duke.edu; and The Centre for International Governance Innovation (CIGI), Waterloo, Canada Brought to you by | Duke University Authenticated Download Date | 2/23/16 9:31 PM 2 Steven L. Schwarcz the ongoing Greek debt crisis, have dramatically highlighted the risks of an inad- equate legal resolution framework for restructuring unsustainable sovereign debt.3 Even those who are not adherents of sovereign “bankruptcy” believe that the status quo contractual approach is “deeply dysfunctional and produces bad law.”4 Unresolved sovereign debt problems are hurting individual debtor nations and their citizens, as well as their creditors.5 A sovereign debt default can also pose a serious systemic threat to the international financial system.6 Few dissent from these views.7 The main impediment is that the existing “contractual” approach to sover- eign debt restructuring – the use of so-called collective actions clauses (“CAC”s) – “ prohibits Argentina, as bond issuer, from formally subordinating the bonds by issuing superior debt” and “prohibits Argentina, as bond payor, from paying [restructured] bonds without paying on the [holdout] Bonds”). Thus Argentina must pay all outstanding sums on its defaulted bonds simultaneously if it makes any payment on its restructured bonds. That decision was affirmed in its entirety by NML Capital, Ltd. v. Republic of Argentina, 727 F.3d 230 (2d Cir. 2013), cert. denied in Republic of Argentina v. NML Capital, Ltd., 134 S. Ct. 2819 (2014). 3 For an analysis of what constitutes “unsustainable” sovereign debt, see text accompanying notes 90–93, infra. This article refers to a nation obligated to repay that debt as a “debtor-state.” 4 Anna Gelpern, A Skeptic’s Case for Sovereign Bankruptcy, in A Debt Restructuring Mechanism for Sovereigns: Do We Need a Legal Procedure? 262 (Christoph Paulus, ed. 2014). 5 Cf. Joseph E. Stiglitz et al., Frameworks for Sovereign Debt Restructuring, IPD-CIGI-CGEG Policy Brief from a November 17, 2014 conference held at Columbia University, at 1 (stating that “[p]oorly designed arrangements for resolving sovereign debt problems can lead to inefficiencies and in- equities . Delays in restructuring can be very costly. Insufficiently deep restructuring can force the economy through multiple crises and restructuring – at a high cost.”). 6 See, e.g. Jay L. Westbrook, Sovereign Debt and Exclusions from Insolvency Proceedings, in A Debt Restructuring Mechanism for Sovereigns: Do We Need a legal Procedure?, at 251 (Christoph Paulus, ed. 2014). Cf. e-mail from Eva Hüpkes, Adviser on Regulatory Policy and Cooperation at the Financial Stability Board (FSB), to the author (July 14, 2015) (observing that “doubts about the ability of states to provide additional resources can make financial institutions more fragile, in particular where there are no regimes in place that provide authorities with powers and tools to resolve financial firms without use of public funds”). 7 One prominent dissenter is Hung Tran, the executive managing director of the Institute of Inter- national Finance (IIF). Tran argues that all of the ad hoc bond restructurings since the first bond exchange of modern times (Mongolia 1997) have worked reasonably well, with the exception of Argentina in the 2000s. Hung Tran, Presentation at the Peterson Institute for International Eco- nomics (April 8, 2014), available at http://www.iie.com/events/event_detail.cfm?EventID=318. He admits that the existing market-based approach is not perfect. However, he contends that breaking contracts should not be easy to do and that making sovereign debt restructuring less costly will inadvertently increase moral hazard by motivating nations to engage in riskier bor- rowing; and that, in turn, would eventually lead to more defaults – which would increase the cost of sovereign debt and make the development of emerging markets more challenging. Ibid. Brought to you by | Duke University Authenticated Download Date | 2/23/16 9:31 PM Sovereign Debt Restructuring: A Model-Law Approach 3 is insufficient to solve the holdout problem.8 CACs are clauses in debt contracts that enable a specified supermajority, such as two-thirds or three-quarters, of the contracting parties to amend the principal amount, interest rate, maturities, and other critical repayment terms.9 The holdout problem is a type of collective action problem in which certain creditors, such as vulture funds, refuse to agree to a reasonable debt restructuring plan that proposes to change critical terms, hoping to receive more than their fair share of a settlement.10 For several reasons, CACs are insufficient to solve the holdout problem. Notwithstanding decades of efforts to include such clauses in sovereign debt contracts, many contracts lack them, requiring unanimity to change criti- cal repayment terms – and thus enabling any party to the contract to act as a holdout.11 Even in sovereign debt contracts that include CACs, the supermajority requirement may be so high (e.g. three-quarters) that vulture funds are able to purchase vote-blocking positions that enable them to act as holdouts.12 Finally, a CAC ordinarily binds only the parties to the particular contract that includes it. The parties to any given sovereign debt contract therefore could act as holdouts in 8 Westbrook, supra note 6, at 255. For a discussion of the variety of issues that cannot be solved by CACs, see Guzman, Martin and Joseph E. Stiglitz (2016). “Fixing Sovereign Debt Restructur- ing”, in Too Little, Too Late: The Quest for Resolving Sovereign Debt Crises; Chapter 1. Columbia University Press. New York. Forthcoming. 9 Steven L. Schwarcz, Sovereign Debt Restructuring: A Bankruptcy Reorganization Approach, 85 Cornell Law Review 956, 960 (2000), also available at http://scholarship.law.duke.edu/faculty_ scholarship/508/ (hereinafter “Sovereign Debt Restructuring”). 10 Ibid. Economists regard this as a form of “rent-seeking” behavior. Kenneth M. Kletzer, Sover- eign Bond Restructuring: Collective Action Clauses and Official Crisis Intervention, IMF Working Paper, at 4 (2003). 11 Steven L. Schwarcz, Sovereign Debt: The Statutory Solution, International Financial Law Re- view (Dec. 2014b); also available at http://www.iflr.com/Article/3405641/Sovereign-debts-statu- tory-solution.html. Cf. Text accompanying note 98, infra (observing that even after years of trying to include CACs, relatively few Greek debt agreements actually contained such clauses). 12 See, e.g. John A. E. Pottow, Mitigating the Problem of Vulture Holdout: International Certifica- tion Boards for Sovereign Debt Restructurings, Law & Economics Working Papers 81 (2013), avail- able at http://repository.law.umich.edu/law_econ_current/81 (vulture funds “may easily be able to marshal blocking positions, especially when a sovereign has issued multiple rounds of debt”). Cf. John Muse-Fisher, Starving the Vultures: NML Capital v. Republic of Argentina and Solutions to the Problem of Distressed-Debt Funds, 102. Cal. L. Rev. 1671, 1707 (2014) (illustrating how holdouts can “bid up the price of defaulted bonds in order to achieve a blocking position”); Molly Ryan, Sovereign Bankruptcy: Why Now and Why Not in the IMF, 82. Fordham L. Rev. 2473, 2502 (2014) (stating that “Greek bonds governed by UK law restructured in 2012 contained a CAC, but holdout investors successfully purchased blocking minorities in individual bond series that could not be offset by pro-restructuring majorities”).
Recommended publications
  • How Should Property Be Valued in a Cram Down?
    Mercer Law Review Volume 49 Number 3 Article 16 5-1998 How Should Property Be Valued In a Cram Down? Mark E. Beatty Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.mercer.edu/jour_mlr Part of the Bankruptcy Law Commons Recommended Citation Beatty, Mark E. (1998) "How Should Property Be Valued In a Cram Down?," Mercer Law Review: Vol. 49 : No. 3 , Article 16. Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.mercer.edu/jour_mlr/vol49/iss3/16 This Comment is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at Mercer Law School Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Mercer Law Review by an authorized editor of Mercer Law School Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Comments How Should Property Be Valued In a Cram Down? I. INTRODUCTION One of the most intriguing topics in bankruptcy law is the valuation of property in cram down cases, specifically Chapter 13 cases. This article will first present and discuss the different methods of valuation employed by the circuit courts before Associates Commercial Corp. v. Rash (Rash II)' was decided by the Supreme Court and the reasoning behind these methods. The next section will discuss the opinion in Rash and the chosen method of valuation in Chapter 13 cram down cases. The third section will discuss the implications of the decision in Rash. The Article will conclude with a proposed solution to the problems presented by the decision. 1. 117 S. Ct. 1879 (1997). 891 892 MERCER LAW REVIEW [Vol. 49 II. THE CIRcurr COURTS A.
    [Show full text]
  • Irish Examinership: Post-Eircom a Look at Ireland's Fastest and Largest
    A look at Ireland’s fastest and largest restructuring through examinership and the implications for the process Irish examinership: post-eircom A look at Ireland’s fastest and largest restructuring through examinership and the implications for the process* David Baxter Tanya Sheridan A&L Goodbody, Dublin A&L Goodbody [email protected] The Irish telecommunications company eircom recently successfully concluded its restructuring through the Irish examinership process. This examinership is both the largest in terms of the overall quantum of debt that was restructured and also the largest successful restructuring through examinership in Ireland to date. The speed with which the restructuring of this strategically important company was concluded was due in large part to the degree of pre-negotiation between the company and its lenders before the process commenced. The eircom examinership demonstrated the degree to which an element of pre-negotiation can compliment the process. The advantages of the process, having been highlighted through the eircom examinership, might attract distressed companies from other EU jurisdictions to undertake a COMI shift to Ireland in order to avail of this process. he eircom examinership was notable for both the Irish High Court just 54 days after the companies Tsize of this debt restructuring and the speed in entered examinership. which the process was successfully concluded. In all, This restructuring also demonstrates the advantages €1.4bn of a total debt of approximately €4bn was of examinership as a ‘one-stop shop’: a flexible process written off the balance sheets of the eircom operating that allows for both the write-off of debt and the change companies.
    [Show full text]
  • Summary Rescue Process”
    COMPANY LAW REVIEW GROUP REPORT ADVISING ON A LEGAL STRUCTURE FOR THE RESCUE OF SMALL COMPANIES 22 OCTOBER 2020 1 | P a g e Contents Chairperson’s Letter to the Minister for Business, Enterprise and Innovation 4 1. Introduction to the Report 5 1.1. The Company Law Review Group ................................................................... 5 1.2 The Role of the CLRG ...................................................................................... 5 1.3 Policy Development........................................................................................ 5 1.4 Contact information ....................................................................................... 5 2. The Company Law Review Group Membership…………………………………………….….6 2.1 Membership of the Company Law Review Group ............................................ 6 3. The Work Programme ............................................................................................. 8 3.1 Introduction to the Work Programme ............................................................ 8 3.2 Company Law Review Group Work Programme 2018-2020 .............................. 8 3.3 Additional item to the Work Programme ........................................................ 9 3.4 Decision making process of the Company Law Review Group……………… ... ……..9 3.5 Committees of the Company Law Review Group ..... ….………………………………..…9 4. A Rescue Plan for SMEs ............................................................................................... 10 4.1 Introduction ................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Services Alert a PUBLICATION of VENABLE's FINANCIAL SERVICES GROUP
    financial services alert A PUBLICATION OF VENABLE'S FINANCIAL SERVICES GROUP TEAM …………………………………… Please contact any of the WHAT THE CRAM-DOWN LEGISLATION Venable lawyers named below if you have any MEANS TO MORTGAGE LENDERS, SERVICERS questions about the Cram- Down legislation. AND INVESTORS Banking and Financial There is a sense of inevitability that Congress will pass legislation allowing a Chapter Services Group: 13 bankruptcy plan (also referred to as a wage-earner’s plan) to "cram-down" the value of a mortgage on a consumer's principal residence to its market value and/or Ronald R. Glancz reset debtor interest rate and monthly payments to an amount that permits them to 202.344.4947 remain in their homes. This alert summarizes the latest version of H.R. 200 that emerged from a mark-up in the House Judiciary Committee this week, and analyzes John B. Beaty how it may affect loan portfolios, servicing and the recovery of the mortgage market, 202.344.4859 and also offers recommendations on how to prepare for the change. John F. Cooney Experts in the mortgage market believe there is the potential for between 2 and 3 million Chapter 13’s after the legislation is enacted (it is on a fast track) as 202.344.4812 homeowners who receive foreclosure notices and otherwise qualify for protection. This likely will mean a wave (or tsunami) of Chapter 13 cases that might be filed in Peter E. Heyward the immediate future by home borrowers seeking relief from residential mortgage 202.344.4616 debt. Bruce O. Jolly, Jr.
    [Show full text]
  • Make Wholes / Prepayment Premiums and Cram Down 1 Make Wholes / Prepayment Premiums and Cram Down November 19, 2014
    MCLE Information The Handout. Participants must download the PowerPoint as the handout for this webinar to comply with MCLE requirements. Click on “File” in order to “Save As” to your computer. Sign-In Sheet. Participants should download the MCLE Sign-In Sheet, complete it and email it to Jeanine McKeown. Certificate of Attendance. Most participants should anticipate receiving their certificate of attendance in 3 to 4 weeks following the webcast. (Virginia Bar members should anticipate receiving it in ~6 weeks following the webcast.) NY Compliance. Individuals seeking credit in New York can expect to hear the key word during the webinar. Questions. Direct MCLE questions and forms to Jeanine McKeown (her contact information is found on all MCLE forms provided ): Jeanine McKeown at 213-229-7140 or [email protected] Gibson Dunn: Make Wholes / Prepayment Premiums and Cram Down 1 Make Wholes / Prepayment Premiums and Cram Down November 19, 2014 David M. Feldman Robert A. Klyman Matthew J. Williams Agenda Introduction Typical Prepayment Provisions Prepayment Premiums in Bankruptcy Cram Down: Momentive Implications 3 Introduction In our presentation today we will cover the following three main topics: • Typical Prepayment Provisions and Construction • Enforceability of Prepayment Premiums Outside and Inside of Chapter 11 • Cramdown and Implications of Recent Caselaw Gibson Dunn: Make Wholes / Prepayment Premiums and Cram Down 4 Typical Prepayment Premiums 5 Typical Prepayment Premiums • New York law generally prohibits voluntary prepayment of fixed maturity term debt without lender consent. • Debt instruments – if they allow prepayment -- often provide that they can not be prepaid without prepayment of a premium, such as a “make-whole” premium (a present value calculation that discounts the payments that would have been received if the bond had not been redeemed, calculated based on comparable treasury yields).
    [Show full text]
  • Restructuring and Insolvency Regimes in South East Asia
    © Rajah & Tann Singapore LLP 1 CONTENTS INTRODUCTION 3 PART I – Cambodia, Myanmar, Laos, Philippines and Vietnam 4 PART II – Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia and Singapore 16 KEY CONTACTS 24 OUR REGIONAL OFFICES 25 DISCLAIMER 26 INTRODUCTION As business and commerce becomes increasingly cross-border in nature, it is important for businesses to have knowledge of restructuring and insolvency regimes of foreign jurisdictions. This is particularly relevant in the Southeast Asia region, given the close connection and links amongst the Southeast Asian states. In this publication, we take a broad look at the key areas of interest in the restructuring and insolvency regimes across the region. The comparative overview covers various differences and similarities in the respective restructuring and insolvency frameworks in these jurisdictions. Rajah & Tann Asia, as a regional network of law firms, has an established presence across Southeast Asia. Our regional offices have the requisite restructuring and insolvency expertise to assist with your queries and restructuring and insolvency needs across these jurisdictions. This publication is up to date as of September 2020. © Rajah & Tann Asia 3 PART I – Cambodia, Myanmar, Laos, Philippines and Vietnam Areas Cambodia Laos Myanmar Philippines Vietnam Rehabilitation A plan of compromise Upon the Court Rehabilitation Court-supervised Court-convened and can be proposed by accepting the petition process can be voluntary rehabilitation Creditors’ Meeting Restructuring the debtor, the or request for initiated (i) voluntarily (court administration). (court administration). Regime administrator or a adjudication and by the company; (ii) creditor (court declaration of by a secured creditor Court-supervised administration). bankruptcy, the debtor who holds security involuntary may apply for Court over all or majority of rehabilitation (court A plan of compromise sanctioned mediation.
    [Show full text]
  • Section 1129(A)(10) of the Bankruptcy Code
    September 13, 2016 In re Transwest Resort Properties, Inc.: Arizona District Court Interpretation of “Impaired Accepting Class” for Plan Confirmation Purposes Threatens Senior Mortgage Lender Protections in Common Real Estate Financing Structures By: Lawrence Mittman and Geoffrey Raicht The enactment of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, which ended the many tax shelter advantages previously available to real estate investors, coupled with the savings and loan crises, effectively collapsed the real estate boom of the early-to-mid 1980’s. From 1988 to 1993, countless numbers of real estate loans went into default and many real estate borrowers sought to involuntarily restructure their loans through the “cram-down” provisions of Chapter 11 under title 11 of the United States Code (the “Bankruptcy Code”). At that time, the typical real estate borrower structure contained a single asset, with senior and junior mortgages against it, and a month or two’s worth of non-material, in dollar amount, of trade payables. By the time of the commencement of the typical Chapter 11 case of this period, property values had so plummeted from when the mortgage loans were first made, a year or two beforehand, that the senior mortgage often found itself without collateral coverage (i.e. undersecured) for half its outstanding debt, and the junior mortgage were inevitably totally “underwater”- - without any collateral coverage (i.e. fully unsecured). Thus, if a foreclosure were to have occurred, the senior mortgagee would be able to “bid-in” or “credit bid” the full amount of its mortgage debt, and unless the junior mortgage were willing to pay-off the senior mortgage in full (principle, interest – simple and default – plus the fees, costs and expenses of the senior mortgagee), the junior mortgagee would be wiped out entirely.
    [Show full text]
  • Sovereign Debt Restructuring
    Sovereign debt restructuring Benu Schneider The views expressed do not necessarily represent those of the Financing for Development Office, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, UN Restructuring options by compositon of debt Debt to official Debt to commercial Debt to Multilaterals Bond debt creditors Banks Yes, with and No, it cannot be Yes, London Club without collective restructured except Yes, at the Paris Club action clauses for HIPC countries The terms of treatment e.g. Pakistan are determined on Ukraine the basis of per capita Ecuador and debt ratios Belize (require bilateral agreements after Paris Club agreements) Covers only PC members Implications of the Argentine Debt Litigation • Consensus that this is game changer – will impact future debt restructurings by strengthening the hands of holdout creditors – illustrates the legal gaps in architecture • Support improvement in contractual technology but something else is needed in addition – moreover there is still the problem of the existing debt stock + voluntarity Diversity in debt restructurings • Those without nominal haircuts move rapidly, fewer holdouts, but need multiple restructurings. Costly in the long run for both debtors and creditors. For deeper “haircuts” negotiations are protracted. • There have been a substantial number of “voluntary” restructurings, as the fall-back position has been protracted legal processes characterized by uncertainty. • Deeper haircuts - creditor cajoling, Growth and defaults • Default and restructuring appears to be negative for debt and positive for growth. • There is always a massive reduction in growth before a default. Is this inevitable? • Could be Pareto improving if we could design a debt restructuring system that minimized that deep decline in growth before default Litigation in sovereign debt defaults is more common than the general perception • In recent times 50% of debt crises involved legal disputes affecting 25 countries(data base covers US and UK).
    [Show full text]
  • Corporate Recovery & Insolvency 2019
    ICLG The International Comparative Legal Guide to: Corporate Recovery & Insolvency 2019 13th Edition A practical cross-border insight into corporate recovery and insolvency work Published by Global Legal Group, in partnership with INSOL International and the International Insolvency Institute, with contributions from: Ali Budiardjo, Nugroho, Reksodiputro Macfarlanes LLP Allen & Gledhill LLP McCann FitzGerald AZB & Partners Miyetti Law Barun Law LLC Mori Hamada & Matsumoto Benoit Chambers Noerr LLP Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP De Pardieu Brocas Maffei Aarpi Pirola Pennuto Zei & Associati Dirican | Gozutok SCA LEGAL, SLP ENGARDE Attorneys at law Schindler Rechtsanwälte GmbH Gall SOLCARGO Gilbert + Tobin Stibbe Hannes Snellman Attorneys Synum ADV INSOL International Thornton Grout Finnigan LLP International Insolvency Institute (III) Zepos & Yannopoulos Kennedys Law Office Waly & Koskinen Ltd. Lenz & Staehelin Loyens & Loeff Luxembourg The International Comparative Legal Guide to: Corporate Recovery & Insolvency 2019 Editorial Chapters: 1 INSOL’s Role Shaping the Future of Insolvency – Adam Harris, INSOL International 1 2 International Insolvency Institute – An Overview – Alan Bloom, International Insolvency Institute (III) 4 General Chapters: 3 Directors and Insolvency: Dangers and Duties – Jat Bains & Paul Keddie, Macfarlanes LLP 7 Contributing Editor Jat Bains, Macfarlanes LLP 4 “Cross”-Border Wall? Not for U.S. Recognition of Foreign Insolvency Proceedings – Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP 12 Publisher Rory Smith Country Question and Answer Chapters: Sales Director Florjan Osmani 5 Australia Gilbert + Tobin: Dominic Emmett & Alexandra Whitby 18 Account Director 6 Austria Schindler Rechtsanwälte GmbH: Martin Abram & Florian Cvak 26 Oliver Smith Senior Editors 7 Belgium Stibbe: Pieter Wouters & Paul Van der Putten 32 Caroline Collingwood 8 Bermuda Kennedys: Alex Potts QC & Mark Chudleigh 38 Rachel Williams Sub Editor 9 Canada Thornton Grout Finnigan LLP: Leanne M.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 9 Bankruptcy Strategies: a Big Stick, Rarely Used
    I N S I D E T H E M I N D S Chapter 9 Bankruptcy Strategies A Big Stick, Rarely Used Leading Lawyers on Navigating the Chapter 9 Filing Process, Counseling Municipalities, and Analyzing Recent Trends and Cases John J. Rapisardi Partner Lary Stromfeld Partner Douglas S. Mintz Special Counsel Terence L. Workman Special Counsel Cadwalader, Wickersham & Taft LLP 2011 Thomson Reuters/Aspatore All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. No part of this publication may be reproduced or distributed in any form or by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, except as permitted under Sections 107 or 108 of the U.S. Copyright Act, without prior written permission of the publisher. This book is printed on acid free paper. Material in this book is for educational purposes only. This book is sold with the understanding that neither any of the authors nor the publisher is engaged in rendering legal, accounting, investment, or any other professional service. Neither the publisher nor the authors assume any liability for any errors or omissions or for how this book or its contents are used or interpreted or for any consequences resulting directly or indirectly from the use of this book. For legal advice or any other, please consult your personal lawyer or the appropriate professional. The views expressed by the individuals in this book (or the individuals on the cover) do not necessarily reflect the views shared by the companies they are employed by (or the companies mentioned in this book). The employment status and affiliations of authors with the companies referenced are subject to change.
    [Show full text]
  • Restructuring Plan EMEA – UK – 29 June 2020
    Changes to the UK Insolvency Regime – Restructuring Plan EMEA – UK – 29 June 2020 On 25 June 2020 the Corporate Insolvency and Governance Act Benefits (the Act) received Royal Assent. The Act makes both temporary and permanent changes to the UK insolvency laws. • The “cross-class cram down” (see further below), which is a new concept compared to schemes of arrangement, allows a degree of greater flexibility. As part of these measures, a new restructuring plan (RP) has been inserted into existing legislation to enable companies to enter into • The RP may also give more manoeuvrability to a creditor of a class who can pass the “75% value” test, an arrangement with their creditors. The RP (similar to a scheme of without needing to also pass the “majority in number” test of a scheme of arrangement. arrangement) will, if approved by the court, enable companies to bind all creditors (including potentially both secured and other dissenting Eligibility creditors) by “cramming down” their debts. This note is not intended to, and does not, constitute legal advice • The RP will apply to most UK companies who have encountered, or are likely to encounter, financial difficulties and Squire Patton Boggs (UK) LLP accepts no liability for any losses that are affecting, or will or may affect, their ability to carry on business as a going concern. occasioned to any person by reason of any action or inaction as a result • There are a handful of restrictions and the Secretary of State can make regulations to exclude certain of the contents of this note. companies from the scope of the RP.
    [Show full text]
  • Not for Publication United States
    So Ordered. Dated: June 23rd, 2020 NOT FOR PUBLICATION UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT EASTERN DISTRICT OF WASHINGTON In re: Lead Case No. 19-02949-WLH12 KEY FARMS, INC., (Substantively Consolidated) -and- MEMORANDUM DISPOSITION REGARDING CRAMDOWN ARTHUR & PATRICIA KEY, ISSUES Debtors. One of the more colorful expressions in the bankruptcy lexicon is “cramdown” – a term obviously adopted for its descriptive value and representing a mechanism to impose debt restructuring terms on a nonconsensual basis. As the term suggests, the cramdown process and ultimate plan treatment are often unpleasant for the affected creditors, a result achieved by Congressional design. The issue here involves the debtors’ efforts to cramdown their principal secured creditor in a chapter 12 plan. The secured creditor contends that the proposed plan treatment does not satisfy the statutory requirements for cramdown, including because the new interest rate for the restructured indebtedness is too low. For the reasons discussed below, the court concludes the plan is generally confirmable other than with respect to the proposed cramdown interest rate. BACKGROUND & PROCEDURAL POSTURE The debtors in these substantively consolidated chapter 12 cases are Key Farms, Inc. and Arthur and Patricia Key. Key Farms is a longstanding family farm MEMORANDUM DISPOSITION REGARDING CRAMDOWN ISSUES Page 1 19-02949-WLH12 Doc 128 Filed 06/23/20 Entered 06/23/20 15:41:19 Pg 1 of 12 operating near Pasco, Washington. The farm produces a variety of apples, cherries, alfalfa, seed corn, and other crops. Arthur and Patricia Key together own a 100% interest in Key Farms. In mid-2014, Key Farms switched its banking relationship such that HomeStreet Bank became its primary financial lender.
    [Show full text]