Technical Notes Interest Rate Volatility and Bond Prices

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Technical Notes Interest Rate Volatility and Bond Prices Technical- Notes Interest Rate Volatility and Bond Prices Francis A. Longstaff, allel shifts. Furthermore, because shifts were always parallel, Associate Professor, Ander• duration and convexity analyses changes in volatility would not be son Graduate School of focus on the risk of changes in the useful in explaining yield move• Management, UClA and level of interest rates, they ignore ments, after controlling for the Eduardo S. Schwartz, other types of relevant risks, in• effects of a change in r, and y cluding changes in the frequency would equal zero. California Chair Professor in Real Estate and of large movements in interest rates. Table I gives the results of this Professor of Finance, regression, estimated using Trea• Anderson Graduate School This paper shows that the price sury yield data, for the 1964-89 of Management, UCLA risk inherent in a default-free period. Note that the parameter {3 bond has two major sources-the is always less than one, and gets - risk of changes in the level of smaller as we go farther out along The risk of a defaultfree interest rates and the risk of the yield curve. Table I implies, bond stems from two major changes in the volatility of inter• for example, that if the one• sources-interest rate shifts est rates. The volatility risk of a month T-bill yield increased by and changes in bond mar• bond can be an important com• 100 basis points, the one-year ponent of its total risk, but few yield would increase by only 52.2 ket volatility. The first type managers currently hedge fixed• basis points, while the five-year of risk is well known. The income portfolios against volatil• yield would increase by only 25.4 second is lessfamilia1~ al• ityrisk. basis points. This is clear evi• though it can represent a dence that shifts in the yield curve major component of the Historical Volatility Risk are dramatically different from To demonstrate that interest rate parallel shifts-a fundamental as• total risk of a fixed-income volatility has a significant effect on sumption of standard duration portfolio. bond prices, we first examine the and convexity analyses. historical relation between vola• - tility and yields. In doing this, we Table I also shows that, even after The past 15 years have included let AYT represent the monthly considering the effects of changes some of the most volatile periods change in the T-maturity Treasury in the level of the yield curve as fixed-income portfolio managers yield; Ar the monthly change in measured by r, there is a signifi• have experienced this century. the one-m,onth Treasury-bill cant relation between yields and One-month Treasury-bill yields yield; and I1V the change in the interest rate volatility for all ma• have been higher than 16% and volatility of interest rates. 1 turities. This is direct evidence m(Y) m lower than 4%. As a result, fixed• that prices of Treasury bonds are income managers have become Now consider the following re• affected by both the level of inter• acutely aware of interest rate risk gression equation: est rates and the volatility of inter• and their exposure to it. est rates. AYT = a + {3Ar+ yAY + E. Managing interest rate risk re• Interestingly, Table I indicates quires measuring it first. Duration In this regression, {3 measures that the relation between yields analysis has become an important how sensitive changes in T-matu• and volatility is negative. This tool, allowing portfolio managers rity Treasury yields are to changes means that an increase in the to measure the sensitivitv of their in the short-term interest rate r. If uncertainty about interest rate t•V> V> portfolios to changes in 'the level shifts in the yield curve were al• changes leads to a decrease in ~ of interest rates. But duration ways parallel, there would be a z« bond yields. This makes sense, « analysis has a number of serious one-to-one relation between AYT because it means that investors «--' drawbacks. Standard duration and Ar, and the slope parameter are willing to pay more for secu• zo analysis, for instance, allows for (3 would equal one. The regres• rities that allow them to lock in a z« only parallel shifts in the term sion parameter y is a measure of long-term, guaranteed rate of re• i:L structure. Thus portfolio manag• how sensitive changes in yields turn when the uncertainty about ers may remain exposed to sub• are to changes in interest rate future money-market yields in• 70 stantial risk arising from nonpar- vOlaLility,2Again) if term structure creases. Table I Regression of Changes in Short-Term Interest Rate and Glossary Changes in Interest Rate Volatility on Changes in Yields to Maturity, 1964 to 1989 ~ Closed-Form Solution: An explicit formula that in• ~ Y T = a + f3~r + y~ V + E volves only simple and easily programmable mathematical 22.5117.2111.9214.6515.3411.16937.5629.40.328.254.666.278f3.377.514.522-1.141-3.01-2.50~to<-2.69-.991-2.29-962-3.09-3.08-.788-.777-.730-.731-2.51.451305.504.239.3433.29.41.422.46.24633663031.000.000a Maturity t /3-3.41-.820ty.34y expressions. 3942561 YearsMonthsYear 3 Months ~ Convexity: A measure of the nonlinear effect on bond prices of changes in the level of the yield curve . ~ Duration: A measure of the percentage senSitivity of a bond price to This negative relationship, how• sions-the risk of changes in in• changes in the level of the ever, does not grow in line with terest rates and the risk of yield curve. the maturity of the bond. In par• changes in interest rate volatility. ticular, y is -0.730 for three• To give a historical perspective of ~ Interest Rate Volatility: month yields, increases to a max• how variable these two sources of The variance of changes in the imum of -1.141 for one-year risk are, Figure A plots the one• level of the yield curve. yields, and then decreases for month Treasury-bill yield during longer maturities. Table I shows the 1964-89 period, and Figure B ~ Macaulay Duration: that three-month and four-year plots the volatility of interest rates The simplest and most com• yields are almost equally sensitive over the same period. Note that mon approach to measuring to changes in volatility. the one-month rate and the vola• bond duration, the Macaulay tility measure move together but duration measure assumes These results demonstrate that are not perfectly correlated. Fur• that all yield curve shifts are the price risk of default-free thermore, while interest rates ex• parallel. bonds has two important dimen- perience dramatic changes, the ~ Volatility Risk: The relation between bond Figure A One-Month Treasury-Bill Rate prices and interest rate volatil• ity makes fixed-income portfo• lios susceptible to changes in 0.120.18 1970197519801985 volatility. ~" 0::0E 0.080.1 0) =?>="" 1965 i:ii 0.06 ~ Yield Sensitivity: ." 0.140.040.160.02 The relation between yields and the level of interest rate volatility. - level of interest rate volatility is even more variable. The Longstaff-Schwartz Model To manage the price risk of a t•V'> fixed-income portfolio, a man• V'> ager clearly needs to be able to ~ z<!' estimate the sensitivity of the <!' --' portfolio to changes in interest <!' rate volatility. In developing tools zo for measuring volatility risk, we z<!' draw upon a recent paper by u:: Longstaffand Schwartz that devel• ops a simple general-equilibrium, 71 Figure B Variance of Changes in One-Month Treasury-Bill Rate basis-point change in the stan• dard deviation of interest rate changes for bonds with varying 0.014 maturities and coupon rates, holding r constant. In computing these price changes, we used pa• 0.012 rameter values for the Longstaff• Schwartz model that allowed the model to match the one-month, one-year, two-year, three-year, 0.0060.0080.01 1975197019801985 ~ 0;0::., I@'" four-year and 30-year Treasury ~ 19650;., 0.004 yields as of January 15th, 1992, as .q well as imply long-run average 0.0020 values for r and the standard de• viation of changes in r of 0.05 and 0.0225, respectively.5 As Table II shows, percentage changes in bond values increase with maturity. For example, a 25• basis-point increase in volatility increases a six-month, zero• coupon bond price by 0.19%, a one-year, zero-coupon bond price by 0.49%, and a 30-year, zero-coupon bond price by 1.31%. Similar results hold for the other coupon bonds. The table also shows that the percentage change in bond price is smaller, the larger the coupon rate of the term-structure model that explic• Measuring Volatility Risk bond. Observe that the percent• itly captures the effect on bond Since the Longstaff-Schwartz age changes increase rapidly out prices of changes in interest rate model results in simple, closed• to about five years, and then level volatility.3 form solutions for the value of off. bonds in terms of the variables r The Longstaff and Schwartz arid V, it is easy to use the model Table III shows the effects of a model starts from fundamental to compute the price effect of a 25-basis-point increase in the economic considerations' about change in interest rate volatility. standard deviation of interest rate investment opportunities, inves• Table II shows the percentage volatility on bond prices. For the tors' risk preferences, technolog• price change resulting from a 25- zero-coupon bond, the price ef- ical change, the nature of finan- cial .markets, arid investment uncertainty in the economy.
Recommended publications
  • Managing Volatility Risk
    Managing Volatility Risk Innovation of Financial Derivatives, Stochastic Models and Their Analytical Implementation Chenxu Li Submitted in partial fulfillment of the Requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY 2010 c 2010 Chenxu Li All Rights Reserved ABSTRACT Managing Volatility Risk Innovation of Financial Derivatives, Stochastic Models and Their Analytical Implementation Chenxu Li This dissertation investigates two timely topics in mathematical finance. In partic- ular, we study the valuation, hedging and implementation of actively traded volatil- ity derivatives including the recently introduced timer option and the CBOE (the Chicago Board Options Exchange) option on VIX (the Chicago Board Options Ex- change volatility index). In the first part of this dissertation, we investigate the pric- ing, hedging and implementation of timer options under Heston’s (1993) stochastic volatility model. The valuation problem is formulated as a first-passage-time problem through a no-arbitrage argument. By employing stochastic analysis and various ana- lytical tools, such as partial differential equation, Laplace and Fourier transforms, we derive a Black-Scholes-Merton type formula for pricing timer options. This work mo- tivates some theoretical study of Bessel processes and Feller diffusions as well as their numerical implementation. In the second part, we analyze the valuation of options on VIX under Gatheral’s double mean-reverting stochastic volatility model, which is able to consistently price options on S&P 500 (the Standard and Poor’s 500 index), VIX and realized variance (also well known as historical variance calculated by the variance of the asset’s daily return).
    [Show full text]
  • Hedging Volatility Risk
    Journal of Banking & Finance 30 (2006) 811–821 www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf Hedging volatility risk Menachem Brenner a,*, Ernest Y. Ou b, Jin E. Zhang c a Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, NY 10012, USA b Archeus Capital Management, New York, NY 10017, USA c School of Business and School of Economics and Finance, The University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong Received 11 April 2005; accepted 5 July 2005 Available online 9 December 2005 Abstract Volatility risk plays an important role in the management of portfolios of derivative assets as well as portfolios of basic assets. This risk is currently managed by volatility ‘‘swaps’’ or futures. How- ever, this risk could be managed more efficiently using options on volatility that were proposed in the past but were never introduced mainly due to the lack of a cost efficient tradable underlying asset. The objective of this paper is to introduce a new volatility instrument, an option on a straddle, which can be used to hedge volatility risk. The design and valuation of such an instrument are the basic ingredients of a successful financial product. In order to value these options, we combine the approaches of compound options and stochastic volatility. Our numerical results show that the straddle option is a powerful instrument to hedge volatility risk. An additional benefit of such an innovation is that it will provide a direct estimate of the market price for volatility risk. Ó 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: G12; G13 Keywords: Volatility options; Compound options; Stochastic volatility; Risk management; Volatility index * Corresponding author.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns
    THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE • VOL. LXI, NO. 1 • FEBRUARY 2006 The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns ANDREW ANG, ROBERT J. HODRICK, YUHANG XING, and XIAOYAN ZHANG∗ ABSTRACT We examine the pricing of aggregate volatility risk in the cross-section of stock returns. Consistent with theory, we find that stocks with high sensitivities to innovations in aggregate volatility have low average returns. Stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility relative to the Fama and French (1993, Journal of Financial Economics 25, 2349) model have abysmally low average returns. This phenomenon cannot be explained by exposure to aggregate volatility risk. Size, book-to-market, momentum, and liquidity effects cannot account for either the low average returns earned by stocks with high exposure to systematic volatility risk or for the low average returns of stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility. IT IS WELL KNOWN THAT THE VOLATILITY OF STOCK RETURNS varies over time. While con- siderable research has examined the time-series relation between the volatility of the market and the expected return on the market (see, among others, Camp- bell and Hentschel (1992) and Glosten, Jagannathan, and Runkle (1993)), the question of how aggregate volatility affects the cross-section of expected stock returns has received less attention. Time-varying market volatility induces changes in the investment opportunity set by changing the expectation of fu- ture market returns, or by changing the risk-return trade-off. If the volatility of the market return is a systematic risk factor, the arbitrage pricing theory or a factor model predicts that aggregate volatility should also be priced in the cross-section of stocks.
    [Show full text]
  • Do Equity Prices Reflect the Ultra-Low Interest Rate Environment?
    27 FEBRUARY 2020 — N O . 1 Do equity prices reflect the ultra-low interest rate environment? Søren Lejsgaard Autrup Jonas Ladegaard Hensch The viewpoints and conclusions stated are the responsibility Principal Economist Economist of the individual contributors, and do not necessarily reflect ECONOMICS AND ECONOMICS AND the views of Danmarks Nationalbank. MONETARY POLICY MONETARY POLICY [email protected] [email protected] ECONOMIC MEMO — DANMARKS NATIONALBANK 27 FEBRUARY 2020 — N O . 1 Do equity prices reflect the ultra-low interest rate environment? The equity risk premium has Investors face a choice when deciding where to about doubled after the financial invest today: Get a certain return on bonds crisis, amid a sharp decline in offering very low or negative returns, or buy a interest rates and an unchanged risky equity and expect to get around 7 per cent per annum, but with downside and upside required return on equities. risks. Before the financial crisis of 2007-08, the trade-off looked different: The expected return The increase in the premium on equities was at the same level, but the entailed a lower pass-through of alternative looked much more favorable with monetary policy rates to the total bond yields around 4 per cent. In other words, financing costs of corporations. the equity risk premium, defined as the That may help to explain why additional return required as compensation for corporate investments have not investing in equities rather than risk-free assets rebounded faster and stronger (bonds), has about doubled to around 7 per after the financial crisis. cent. Still, bonds are in high demand and no major, global rotation between asset classes has taken place so far.
    [Show full text]
  • Risk Management of Investments in Structured Credit Products
    Risk Management of Investments in Structured Credit Products Background A growing number of FDIC-supervised institutions are experiencing deterioration in financial performance as a result of investments in structured credit products.1 The underlying collateral of certain structured credit products has performed poorly. As a result, the level of credit support for senior tranches has diminished, the volume and severity of credit rating downgrades have increased, liquidity has declined, prices are not transparent, and price volatility has increased. Consequently, an increasing number of financial institutions are recognizing other-than-temporary impairment (OTTI) charges and substantial fair value markdowns. Some institutions have invested in structured products in volumes representing concentrations of capital. In some cases, significant purchases were initiated after the credit market turmoil began and, in some cases, funding came from brokered deposits or other volatile funding sources. The FDIC is concerned that financial institutions are not appropriately identifying and controlling the risks inherent in complex structured credit products. Examiners are identifying weaknesses in management’s understanding of product risks, due diligence efforts, portfolio diversification standards, and application of proper accounting standards. Purpose This letter clarifies the application of existing supervisory guidance to structured credit products. Guidance referenced comes primarily from the 1998 “Supervisory Policy Statement on Investment Securities and End-User Derivatives Activities” (Policy Statement), and the “Uniform Agreement on the Classification of Assets and Appraisal of Securities” (Uniform Agreement).2 Topics addressed in this letter include investment suitability and due diligence, the use of external credit ratings, pricing and liquidity, and adverse classification of investment securities. FDIC-supervised institutions should revisit outstanding guidance and incorporate this document’s clarifications into existing policies and processes.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Portfolio Theory, Part One
    Modern Portfolio Theory, Part One Introduction and Overview Modern Portfolio Theory suggests that you can maximize your investment returns, given the amount of risk (or volatility) you are willing to take on. This is the idea to be developed and evaluated during this 10-part series. Part One provides an introduction to the issues. by Donald R. Chambers e are inundated with advice ory” or MPT. The most important advances emerged: efficient market Wregarding investment deci- point of MPT is that diversification theory and equilibrium pricing sions from numerous sources (bro- reduces risk without reducing expected theory. kers, columnists, economists) and return. MPT uses mathematics and Led by Professor Eugene Fama, through a variety of media (televi- statistics to demonstrate diversifica- MPT pioneers established a frame- sion, magazines, seminars). But tion clearly and carefully. work for discussing the idea that the suggested answers regarding This series focuses on relatively security markets are informationally investment decisions not only vary simple and easy-to-implement efficient. This means that secu- tremendously but often rity prices already reflect directly conflict with each MPT does not describe or prescribe invest- available information and other—leaving the typical that it is therefore not investor in a quandary. ing perfectly. But even if it’s not perfect, possible to use available On top of this MPT has major implications that should be information to identify complexity, conditions under-priced or over- change. Markets crash considered by every investor. priced securities. and firms once viewed as In the wake of difficult providing solutions, such as Merrill investment concepts.
    [Show full text]
  • Volatility and the Alchemy of Risk
    Volatility and the Alchemy of Risk Reflexivity in the Shadows of Black Monday 1987 Christopher Cole The Ouroboros, a Greek word meaning ‘tail debt expansion, asset volatility, and financial Artemis Capital Managment devourer’, is the ancient symbol of a snake engineering that allocates risk based on that consuming its own body in perfect symmetry. volatility. In this self-reflexive loop volatility The imagery of the Ouroboros evokes the can reinforce itself both lower and higher. In infinite nature of creation from destruction. The a market where stocks and bonds are both sign appears across cultures and is an important overvalued, financial alchemy is the only way to icon in the esoteric tradition of Alchemy. feed our global hunger for yield, until it kills the Egyptian mystics first derived the symbol very system it is nourishing. from a real phenomenon in nature. In extreme The Global Short Volatility trade now heat a snake, unable to self-regulate its body represents an estimated $2+ trillion in financial temperature, will experience an out-of-control engineering strategies that simultaneously exert spike in its metabolism. In a state of mania, the influence over, and are influenced by, stock snake is unable to differentiate its own tail from market volatility.2 We broadly define the short its prey, and will attack itself, self-cannibalizing volatility trade as any financial strategy that until it perishes. In nature and markets, when relies on the assumption of market stability to randomness self-organizes into too perfect generate returns, while using volatility itself symmetry, order becomes the source of chaos.1 as an input for risk taking.
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity Effects in Options Markets: Premium Or Discount?
    Liquidity Effects in Options Markets: Premium or Discount? PRACHI DEUSKAR1 2 ANURAG GUPTA MARTI G. SUBRAHMANYAM3 March 2007 ABSTRACT This paper examines the effects of liquidity on interest rate option prices. Using daily bid and ask prices of euro (€) interest rate caps and floors, we find that illiquid options trade at higher prices relative to liquid options, controlling for other effects, implying a liquidity discount. This effect is opposite to that found in all studies on other assets such as equities and bonds, but is consistent with the structure of this over-the-counter market and the nature of the demand and supply forces. We also identify a systematic factor that drives changes in the liquidity across option maturities and strike rates. This common liquidity factor is associated with lagged changes in investor perceptions of uncertainty in the equity and fixed income markets. JEL Classification: G10, G12, G13, G15 Keywords: Liquidity, interest rate options, euro interest rate markets, Euribor market, volatility smiles. 1 Department of Finance, College of Business, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, 304C David Kinley Hall, 1407 West Gregory Drive, Urbana, IL 61801. Ph: (217) 244-0604, Fax: (217) 244-9867, E-mail: [email protected]. 2 Department of Banking and Finance, Weatherhead School of Management, Case Western Reserve University, 10900 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland, Ohio 44106-7235. Ph: (216) 368-2938, Fax: (216) 368-6249, E-mail: [email protected]. 3 Department of Finance, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, New York University, 44 West Fourth Street #9-15, New York, NY 10012-1126. Ph: (212) 998-0348, Fax: (212) 995-4233, E- mail: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Two Harbors Investment Corp
    Two Harbors Investment Corp. Webinar Series October 2013 Fundamental Concepts in Hedging Welcoming Remarks William Roth Chief Investment Officer July Hugen Director of Investor Relations 2 Safe Harbor Statement Forward-Looking Statements This presentation includes “forward-looking statements” within the meaning of the safe harbor provisions of the United States Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995. Actual results may differ from expectations, estimates and projections and, consequently, readers should not rely on these forward-looking statements as predictions of future events. Words such as “expect,” “target,” “assume,” “estimate,” “project,” “budget,” “forecast,” “anticipate,” “intend,” “plan,” “may,” “will,” “could,” “should,” “believe,” “predicts,” “potential,” “continue,” and similar expressions are intended to identify such forward-looking statements. These forward-looking statements involve significant risks and uncertainties that could cause actual results to differ materially from expected results. Factors that could cause actual results to differ include, but are not limited to, higher than expected operating costs, changes in prepayment speeds of mortgages underlying our residential mortgage-backed securities, the rates of default or decreased recovery on the mortgages underlying our non-Agency securities, failure to recover certain losses that are expected to be temporary, changes in interest rates or the availability of financing, the impact of new legislation or regulatory changes on our operations, the impact
    [Show full text]
  • Asset Pricing Implications of Volatility Term Structure Risk
    Asset Pricing Implications of Volatility Term Structure Risk CHEN XIE ABSTRACT I find that stocks with high sensitivities to changes in the VIX slope exhibit high returns on average. The price of VIX slope risk is approximately 2.5% annually, statistically significant and cannot be explained by other common factors, such as the market excess return, size, book-to-market, momentum, liquidity, market volatility, and the variance risk premium. I provide a theoretical model that supports my empirical results. The model extends current rare disaster models to include disasters of different lengths. My model implies that a downward sloping VIX term structure anticipates a potential long disaster and vice versa. The current level of market volatility is a standard indicator of market-wide risk. The market volatility term structure, which is calculated from prices of options with different expirations, reflects the market's expectation of future volatility of different horizons. So the market volatility term structure incorporates information that is not captured by the market volatility itself. In particular, the slope of the volatility term structure captures the expected trend in volatility. I investigate in this paper whether the market volatility term structure slope is a priced source of risk. The time-varying market volatility term structure slope reflects changes in expectations of future market risk-return, thus, it should induce changes in the investment opportunity set and should be a state variable. The Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model (ICAPM) of Merton (1973) then predicts that changes in the market volatility term structure must be a priced risk factor in the cross-section of risky asset returns.
    [Show full text]
  • Portfolio Optimization: Thinking Outside the Style Box
    Portfolio Optimization: Thinking Outside the Style Box Asset Allocation, Portfolio Optimization and Optimization Through Hedged Equity By Micah Wakefield, CAIA®, AAMS®, AWMA® February 23, 2017 February 2017 Portfolio Optimization Thinking Outside the Style Box - 2 CONTENTS Revisions 3 Objectives 4 Portfolio Optimization 5 An Alternative Approach to Portfolio Optimization 10 Portfolio Improvement through Hedged Assets 12 Specific Asset Comparisons for Use in Alternative Portfolio Optimization 16 The Defined Risk Portfolio 18 Swan Global Investments | 970-382-8901 | swanglobalinvestments.com February 2017 Portfolio Optimization Thinking Outside the Style Box - 3 REVISIONS A. Initial Release January 31, 2015 Micah J. Wakefield, AWMA®, AAMS® Director of Research and Product Development Swan Global Investments B. Second Release October 1, 2016 Micah J. Wakefield, CAIA®, AWMA®, AAMS® Director of Research and Product Development Swan Global Investments C. Third Release February 23, 2017 Micah J. Wakefield, CAIA®, AWMA®, AAMS® Director of Research and Product Development Swan Global Investments Swan Global Investments | 970-382-8901 | swanglobalinvestments.com February 2017 Portfolio Optimization Thinking Outside the Style Box - 4 OBJECTIVES Swan is focused on helping provide financial advisors with the thought leadership necessary to differentiate themselves and make their businesses stronger and more valuable. The purpose of this document is to highlight our theoretical view that a diversified hedged assets portfolio is a more effective and
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity and Volatility
    Liquidity and Volatility Itamar Drechsler, Alan Moreira, Alexi Savov∗ October 2020 Abstract Liquidity provision is a bet against private information: if private information turns out to be higher than expected, liquidity providers lose. Since information gen- erates volatility, and volatility co-moves across assets, liquidity providers have a neg- ative exposure to aggregate volatility shocks. As aggregate volatility shocks carry a very large premium in option markets, this negative exposure can explain why liquid- ity provision earns high average returns. We show this by incorporating uncertainty about the amount of private information into an otherwise standard model. We test the model in the cross section of short-term reversals, which mimic the portfolios of liquidity providers. As predicted by the model, reversals have large negative be- tas to aggregate volatility shocks. These betas explain their average returns with the same risk price as in option markets, and their predictability by VIX in the time series. Volatility risk thus explains the liquidity premium among stocks and why it increases in volatile times. Our results provide a novel view of the risks and returns to liquidity provision. JEL Codes: Keywords: Liquidity, volatility, reversals, VIX, variance premium ∗Drechsler: University of Pennsylvania and NBER, [email protected]; Moreira: Uni- versity of Rochester, [email protected]; Savov: New York University and NBER, [email protected]. We thank Markus Brunnermeier, Pete Kyle, Mathieu Fournier, Yunzhi Hu, David Schreindorfer, Daniel Schmidt, Mark Westerfield, and Zhaogang Song for discussions; Kent Daniel, Greg Duffie, Ron Kaniel, Bryan Kelly, Maureen O’Hara, and Christian Opp for their comments; as well as partici- pants at NBER Asset Pricing, Cornell, CBOE Derivatives Conference, European Finance Association, Insead Finance Conference, American Finance Association, University of Texas at Austin, Washington University at St.
    [Show full text]