Competition and Cooperation on Predation: Bifurcation Theory of Mutualism Author: Srijana Ghimire Xiang-Sheng Wang University of Louisiana at Lafayette

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Competition and Cooperation on Predation: Bifurcation Theory of Mutualism Author: Srijana Ghimire Xiang-Sheng Wang University of Louisiana at Lafayette Competition and Cooperation on Predation: Bifurcation Theory Of Mutualism Author: Srijana Ghimire Xiang-Sheng Wang University of Louisiana at Lafayette Introduction Existence and Stability of E1,E+ and E− Existence and property of Hopf bifurcation 3. R > 1 and R > 3R − 2R2. In this case, Q = Q , 1 2 1 1 c 1 points We investigate two predator-prey models which take into con- xc = 1/R1, E1 always exists, E1 is locally asymptotically H E + H E E sideration the cooperation between two different predators and stable if and only if Q < Q1, E− does not exist, and E+ exits + + R H within one predator species, respectively. Local and global dy- if and only if Q > Q1. 2.0 E E E - namics are studied for the model systems. By a detailed bi- - - Q Q Q Q Q Q furcation analysis, we investigate the dependence of predation + + h + h1 h2 1.5 no Hopf bifurcation Existence conditions of positive equilibria. (a) case 1(a) (b) case 1(b) (c) case 1(c) dynamics on mutualism (cooperative predation). H H E R + 2 E E two supercritical + + 1.0 R2 > 1 Q H E+ E - E Q1 - E y y - First Predator-Prey Model with Competition 1 E 1 E 1 1 y 1 E 1 0.5 one supercritical NA Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q and Co-operation 1 + 1 + 1 h + h1 1 h2 R2 < one Q R1 NA if Q < Q1 (d) case 2(a) (e) case 2(b) (f) case 2(c) E± subcritical E+ if Q ≥ Q1 E+ d 0 H 0 2 4 6 8 E x = 1 − x − p xy − p xz − 2qxyz, (1) + 1 2 Q+ E Q1 + 0 Figure: Existence and property of Hopf bifurcation points in the (d, R) y = p xy + qxyz − d y, (2) 2 1 1 R2 = 3R1 − 2R NA 1 H parameter space. The red solid, blue dashed and black dotdashed curves are R y 0 1 1 y 2 2 p E 1 z = p xz + qxyz − d z, (3) 1 E R = d(d − 2)/(d − 1) , R = d(4 − d)/[5d − d − 2 + (d − 3) d(d − 3), 2 2 1 R2 = R1 Q Q Q Q and R = d/4, respectively. Where, x(t) is the ratio of prey density with respect to the 1 1 h1 h2 NA if Q < Q+ NA if Q < Q+ (g) case 3(a) (h) case 3(c) carrying capacity, y(t) and z(t) is the density of first kind and if if E± Q ≥ Q+ E± Q+ ≤ Q < Q1 Figure: E1(red),E+(red) and E−(green), with projection on y-Q plane if second kind of predators which compete for the prey x(t). E+ Q ≥ Q1 Existence and Stability of E+ and E− R Predation rate and death rate for each predator are pi and di 1 1.5 1 with i = 1, 2 respectively . In the absent of cooperative pre- Figure: Existence conditions of positive equilibria. Global Stability of E0 and E1 E E E + dation i.e. q = 0. The Gauss’s law of competitive exclusion + + H H principle holds.The basic reproduction numbers for the preda- E E - - E tors: R1 = p1/d1 and R2 = p2/d2. Stability of E+ Lyapunov function for the global stability of E0 : - Q Q Q Q Q V (x, y, z) = c (x − ln x + y + z) + (x + y + z − 1)2/2 + + h,+ + h,+ Lemma: Consider an ordinary differential system with a pa- 0 0 (a) case I.1 (b) case I.2 (c) case I.3 . E E Existence and Stability of E0,E1,E2,E+,E− rameter Q. Assume that an equilibrium E(Q) exists for Q in + + H Lyapunov function for the global stability of E1 : H E an interval I ⊂ R with characteristic polynomial p(ł,Q) = + 3 2 2 H Consider model (1)-(3) with R1 > R2. Denote Q = q/(d1d2) H ł + Q)a2(Q)ł + (Q)a1(Q)ł + Q)(Q)a0(Q). Assume that Q), V1(x, y, z) = c1(x−x1 ln x+y−y1 ln y+z)+(x+y+z−x1−y1) /2. 2 E and let s± is the root of f(s) = 2s − (Q + R1 + R2)s + Q = 0, (Q), a2(Q), a1(Q)¯and a0(Q) are all¯ positive and differentiable - Q Q Q 0 Q Q R1(R1−R2) Theorem: Assume R1 > R2 and the initial values + h,- h,+ 0 h,- h,+ Q1 = , ¯functions for Q ∈ I. Define g(Q) = a (Q)−a (Q)a (Q). Then √R1−1 0 1 2 (x(0), y(0), z(0)) are positive. If R ≤ 1 and q satisfies (d) case I.4 (e) case II.1 (f) case II.2 q 2 1 Q± = ( 2 ± 2 − (R1 + R2)) and the equilibrium E(Q) is locally asymptotically stable when g(Q) Figure: E+(blue) and E−(green), with projection on y-Q plane r 2 8 (d1+1) 2 is negative and unstable when g(Q) is positive. If g(Q) has a d1 + d2 + 2 d2[d1 − ] 2 <Q ,R ≥ 3R − 2R , 4(c0+1) d + 1 (d − 1) Q = 1 2 1 1 . q ≤ , c = max{ 2 , 1 }. c 2 simple root Qh ∈ I, then Hopf bifurcation occurs at Q = Qh 0 Q ,R ≤ 3R − 2R . 2c0 d2 − p2 4d1 : + 2 1 1 with crossing number Sign[g0(Q )]. Conclusion ¯ h Set xc = χ(Qc), Gc = G(xc) and G = maxx∈[0,x ] G(x), where , then E0 = (1, 0, 0) is globally asymptotically stable. If R1 > 1 c The stability condition of E+ is given in the following cases. the functions χ(Q) = x+ and and q satisfies 1. In both models cooperative predation may increase the survival a. G¯ < 0. In this case, E+ is always locally asymptotically stable. 2 2−R1x 2−R2x r 2 G(x) = 4x − (R1 + R2)x − − . (d1+1) probability of predators in the severe environment when non d2(1−R1x) d1(1−R2x) d1 + d2 + 2 d2[d1 − ] b. Gc > 0. In this case, G has a unique root, denoted by xh, on 4(c1/x1+1) The predator-free equilibrium E0 = (1, 0, 0) always exists, and q ≤ , cooperative predation is not efficient to battle with the natural (0, xc). E+ is locally asymptotically stable for Q ∈ (Qh, ∞) E is locally asymptotically stable if and only if R ≤ 1. 2c1x1 death. 0 1 and unstable for Q ∈ (Q ,Q ), where Q = φ(x ) is a Hopf 2 + h h h (d2 + 1)x1 + (d1 + d2)y1 x1(d1 − 1) The competitive-predation equilibrium E2 = (x2, 0, z2) with and, c = max{ , }. 2. Cooperative predation may destabilize a positive equilibrium bifurcation point. 1 d − p x 4d x2 = 1/R2 and z2 = 1/d2 − 1/p2 exists if and only if R2 > 1, 2 2 1 1 and induce a Hopf bifurcation.Depending on the model param- c. Gc < 0 and G¯ > 0. In this case, G has two roots, xh1 > and it is always unstable whenever it exists. , then E1 = (x1, y1, 0) is globally asymptotically stable. eters, the limit cycles bifurcated from the Hopf points may or x , on (0, x ). E is locally asymptotically stable for Q ∈ The existence conditions of another competitive-predation equi- h2 c + may not be stable. (Q ,Q )∪(Q , ∞) and unstable for Q ∈ (Q ,Q ), where librium E = (x , y , 0) with x = 1/R and y = 1/d − 1/p + h1 h2 h1 h2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Q = φ(x ) and Q = φ(x ) are two Hopf bifurcation Special Case and the cooperative-predation equilibria E = (x , y , z ) with h1 h1 h2 h2 ± ± ± ± points. References x± = 1/s±, y± = (s±−R2)/(d1Q) and z± = (s±−R1)/(d2Q). Biologically, we assume that the two predators can be regarded The stability conditions of E1 and E− are given in the following as the same. Thus, we can reduce the three-dimensional system • Beauchamp14 G. Beauchamp,Social Predation: How Group Living Benefits Predators cases. Direction of Hopf bifurcation and stability of and Prey, Academic Press, 2014. q (1)-(3) to a planar system 1. R ≤ 1. In this case, Q = Q , x = 2/Q , E does • Lo25 A. Lotka, Elements of Physical Biology, Williams and Wilkins, Baltimore, 1925. 1 c + c + 1 periodic solution x0(t) = 1 − x(t) − 2px(t)y(t) − 2qx(t)[y(t)]2, (4) • MTSS14 D. R. MacNulty, A. Tallian, D. R. Stahler, and D. W. Smith, Influence of group not exist, E exist if and only if Q ≥ Q , and E is always size on the success of wolves hunting bison, PLOS ONE 9 (2014), e112884. ± + − y0(t) = px(t)y(t) + qx(t)[y(t)]2 − dy(t). (5) unstable whenever it exists. Diagonalize the Jacobian matrix of (1)-(3). We calculate the • PR88 C. Packer and L. Ruttan, The evolution of cooperative hunting, Am. Nat. 132 (1988), 159–198. 2 Diagonalize the Jacobian matrix of (4)-(5). We calculate the 2. R1 > 1 and R2 ≤ 3R1 − 2R1. In this case, Qc = Q+, xc = first Lyapunov coefficient l1. The Hopf bifurcation is supercrit- • Sm95 H. Smith, Monotone Dynamical Systems. An Introduction to the Theory of Com- q first Lyapunov coefficient l . The Hopf bifurcation is supercrit- petitive and Cooperative Systems, Mathematical Surveys and Monographs, vol. 41, Amer- 2/Q , E always exists, E is locally asymptotically stable ical when l1 < 0 and subcritical when l1 > 0 where, 1 + 1 1 ican Mathematical Society, Providence, RI, 1995.
Recommended publications
  • Nudging Cooperation in Public Goods Provision
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Barron, Kai; Nurminen, Tuomas Article — Accepted Manuscript (Postprint) Nudging cooperation in public goods provision Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Barron, Kai; Nurminen, Tuomas (2020) : Nudging cooperation in public goods provision, Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, ISSN 2214-8043, Elsevier, Amsterdam, Vol. 88, Iss. (Article No.:) 101542, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2020.101542 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/216878 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von
    [Show full text]
  • Game-Theoretic Analysis of Cooperation Incentive Strategies in Mobile Ad Hoc Networks
    1 Game-Theoretic Analysis of Cooperation Incentive Strategies in Mobile Ad Hoc Networks Ze Li and Haiying Shen Dept. of Electrical and Computer Engineering Clemson University, Clemson, SC 29631 fzel,[email protected] F Abstract—In mobile ad hoc networks (MANETs), tasks are conducted nodes will decrease the throughput of cooperative nodes and lead based on the cooperation of nodes in the networks. However, since the to complete network disconnection [6]. Therefore, encouraging nodes are usually constrained by limited computation resources, selfish nodes to be cooperative and detecting selfish nodes in packet nodes may refuse to be cooperative. Reputation systems and price-based transmission is critical to ensuring the proper functionalities of systems are two main solutions to the node non-cooperation problem. A reputation system evaluates node behaviors by reputation values and uses MANETs. a reputation threshold to distinguish trustworthy nodes and untrustworthy Recently, numerous approaches have been proposed to deal nodes. A price-based system uses virtual cash to control the transactions with the node non-cooperation problem in wireless networks. of a packet forwarding service. Although these two kinds of systems have They generally can be classified into two main categories: reputa- been widely used, very little research has been devoted to investigating the tion systems and price-based systems. The basic goal of reputation effectiveness of the node cooperation incentives provided by the systems. systems [7–18] is to evaluate each node’s trustworthiness based In this paper, we use game theory to analyze the cooperation incentives provided by these two systems and by a system with no cooperation on its behaviors and detect misbehaving nodes according to rep- incentive strategy.
    [Show full text]
  • A Value-Based Framework for Understanding Cooperation
    CDPXXX10.1177/0963721420906200Pärnamets et al.Value-Based Framework for Cooperation 906200research-article2020 ASSOCIATION FOR PSYCHOLOGICAL SCIENCE Current Directions in Psychological Science A Value-Based Framework for 2020, Vol. 29(3) 227 –234 © The Author(s) 2020 Article reuse guidelines: Understanding Cooperation sagepub.com/journals-permissions DOI:https://doi.org/10.1177/0963721420906200 10.1177/0963721420906200 www.psychologicalscience.org/CDPS Philip Pärnamets1,2, Anastasia Shuster3, Diego A. Reinero2 , and Jay J. Van Bavel2 1Division of Psychology, Department of Clinical Neuroscience, Karolinska Institutet; 2Department of Psychology, New York University; and 3Department of Psychiatry, Icahn School of Medicine at Mt. Sinai Abstract Understanding the roots of human cooperation, a social phenomenon embedded in pressing issues including climate change and social conflict, requires an interdisciplinary perspective. We propose a unifying value-based framework for understanding cooperation that integrates neuroeconomic models of decision-making with psychological variables involved in cooperation. We propose that the ventromedial prefrontal cortex serves as a neural integration hub for value computation during cooperative decisions, receiving inputs from various neurocognitive processes such as attention, memory, and learning. Next, we describe findings from social and personality psychology highlighting factors that shape the value of cooperation, including research on contexts and norms, personal and social identity, and intergroup relations. Our approach advances theoretical debates about cooperation by highlighting how previous findings are accommodated within a general value-based framework and offers novel predictions. Keywords cooperation, preferences, norms, social neuroscience, neuroeconomics Cooperation is a central feature of group living and map for psychologists and help promote cumulative involves any action that benefits other people while science.
    [Show full text]
  • International Cooperation Among Botanic Gardens
    INTERNATIONAL COOPERATION AMONG BOTANIC GARDENS: THE CONCEPT OF ESTABLISHING AGREEMENTS By Erich S. Rudyj A thesis submitted to the Faculty of the University of elaware in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree Master of Science in Public Horticulture Administration May 1988 © 1988 Erich S. Rudyj INTERNATIONAL COOPERATION~ AMONG BOTANIC GARDENS: THE CONCEPT OF EsrtBllSHING AGREEMENTS 8y Erich S. Rudyj Approved: _ James E. Swasey, Ph.D. Professor in charge of thesis on behalf of the Advisory Committee Approved: _ James E. Swasey, Ph.D. Coordinator of the Longwood Graduate Program Approved: _ Richard 8. MLfrray, Ph.D. Associate Provost for Graduate Studies No man is an /land, intire of it selfe; every man is a peece of the Continent, a part of the maine; if a Clod bee washed away by the Sea, Europe is the lesse, as well as if a Promontorie '-"Jere, as well as if a Mannor of thy friends or of thine owne were; any mans death diminishes me, because I am involved in Mankinde; And therefore never send to know for whom the bell tolls; It tolls for thee. - JOHN DONNE - In the Seventeenth Meditation of the Devotions Upon Emergent Occasions (1624) iii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I wish to express my sincerest thanks to Donald Crossan, James Oliver and James Swasey, who, as members of my thesis committee, provided me with the kind of encouragement and guidance needed to merge both the fields of Public Horticulture and International Affairs. Special thanks are extended to the organizers and participants of the Tenth General Meeting and Conference of the International Association of Botanical Gardens (IABG) for their warmth, advice and indefatigable spirit of international cooperation.
    [Show full text]
  • Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoner's Dilemma
    Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma Matthew Embrey Guillaume R. Fr´echette Sevgi Yuksel U. of Sussex ................................ NYU ................................... UCSB June, 2017 Abstract More than half a century after the first experiment on the finitely repeated prisoner’s dilemma, evidence on whether cooperation decreases with experience–as suggested by backward induction–remains inconclusive. This paper provides a meta-analysis of prior experimental research and reports the results of a new experiment to elucidate how coop- eration varies with the environment in this canonical game. We describe forces that a↵ect initial play (formation of cooperation) and unraveling (breakdown of cooperation). First, contrary to the backward induction prediction, the parameters of the repeated game have a significant e↵ect on initial cooperation. We identify how these parameters impact the value of cooperation–as captured by the size of the basin of attraction of Always Defect–to account for an important part of this e↵ect. Second, despite these initial di↵erences, the evolution of behavior is consistent with the unraveling logic of backward induction for all parameter combinations. Importantly, despite the seemingly contradictory results across studies, this paper establishes a systematic pattern of behavior: subjects converge to use threshold strategies that conditionally cooperate until a threshold round; and conditional on establishing cooperation, the first defection round moves earlier with experience. Sim- ulation results generated from a learning model estimated at the subject level provide insights into the long-term dynamics and the forces that slow down the unraveling of cooperation. We wish to thank the editor, anonymous referees, James Andreoni, Yoella Bereby-Meyer, Russell Cooper, Pedro Dal B´o, Douglas DeJong, Robert Forsythe, Drew Fudenberg, Daniel Friedman, P.J.
    [Show full text]
  • Caring Economics, Cooperation, and the Covid-19 Pandemic
    Volume 8, Issue 1 Spring pubs.lib.umn.edu/ijps CARING ECONOMICS, COOPERATION, AND THE COVID-19 PANDEMIC Silvia Hedenigg, PhD Abstract For centuries, Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations shaped profit maximization as the standard of economic action. The concept of caring economics published by the feminist law and systems scientist Riane Eisler under the title The Real Wealth of Nations: Creating a Caring Economics (2007) contrasts this neoliberal, dominance-oriented model of society with the idea of partnership-oriented societies. The concept of caring economics was widely influenced by the social, economic, and welfare systems of the Nordic countries. In 2015-2016, the author of this article conducted a pilot study interviewing scientists from different disciplines with the aim of investigating whether the conditions in these countries reflect Eisler’s theoretical model (Hedenigg, 2019). While Eisler emphasized empathy and care as essential orientations of partnership societies, several of the interviewed scholars, in contrast, stressed cooperation, trust, solidarity, and functioning institutions as essential elements in addition to Eisler’s concept. This article hypothesizes that Eisler’s conception of caring economics should be supplemented by the elements mentioned above, in particular, cooperation. The aim is to identify, in a theory-guided manner, the elements that constitute the central operative mechanisms of the extended conception of caring economics. Resulting conclusions are discussed in the context of the Covid-19 pandemic. Norway and Finland are among the 10 most successful nations in epidemic containment. This article assumes that the extended conceptualization of caring economics does not only allow us to gain insight into the complexity of the pandemic, but also to identify various successful containment mechanisms.
    [Show full text]
  • Real-Time Monitoring in a Public Goods Game*
    Real-time Monitoring in a Public Goods Game* Simin He† and Xun Zhu‡ July 28, 2020 Abstract Public goods problems are prevalent in economics and are challenging to resolve. In this study, we investigate a novel continuous-time incremental commitment mecha- nism. Within a fixed time period, people can choose when to stop their contributions from increasing exogenously, and their actions are observed by others. We show both theoretically and experimentally that it is a very effective mechanism to help improve contribution. Moreover, we compare this mechanism with other mechanisms under similar real-time environment, and find that the mechanism becomes ineffective when the incremental commitment feature is absent. Our findings can be potentially extended to other social dilemma situations. Keywords: Public goods, continuous time, incremental commitment, cheap talk. JEL codes: C72, C92, D82. *The authors sincerely thank Syngjoo Choi, Bin Miao, Lan Yao, and the participants of the Nottingham CeDEx China Workshop on Behavioral and Experimental Economics and the Virtual East Asia Experimental and Behavioral Experimental Seminar Series for their helpful comments. †School of Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, 111 Wuchuan Rd, 200433 Shanghai, China. E-mail: [email protected]. ‡School of Management, Fudan University, 670 Guoshun Rd, 200433 Shanghai, China. E-mail: zhuxun [email protected]. 1 Introduction Public goods games are very prevalent in economics, and their desired outcome requires people to contribute to a public pool efficiently. For example, building a dam that benefits people living around it requires everyone to contribute; fighting global warming problem requires all countries to reduce their carbon emissions.
    [Show full text]
  • Cooperation Under Predation Risk: Experiments on Costs and Benefits
    Cooperation under predation risk: experiments on costs and benefits MANFRED MILINSKI1, JEAN H. LUTHI¨ 1, ROLF EGGLER1 and GEOFFREY A. PARKER2 1Abteilung Verhaltens¨okologie, Department of Zoology, University of Bern, CH-3032 Hinterkappelen, Switzerland ([email protected]) 2Population Biology Research Group, School of Biological Sciences, University of Liverpool, Liverpool L69 3BX, UK SUMMARY Two fish that cooperatively inspect a predator may have negotiated the share of the risk that each takes. A test of both the costs of predator inspection dependent on the distance from which the preda- tor is approached and the potential benefits of cooperation was carried out strictly experimentally. We made either singletons or pairs of dead sticklebacks, Gasterosteus aculeatus, approach hungry pike, Esox lucius, by remote control according to an algorithm that mimicked natural inspection. The predation risk of both single inspectors and parallel inspecting pairs increased with closer inspection distances. A member of an inspecting pair had only about half the risk of that of a single inspector. In pairs, a companion diluted the lead fish’s risk of being caught, depending on its distance behind the leader. The absolute risk difference between leader and follower was greatest for close inspection distances and decreased further away from the predator. The leader’s relative risk increased with its distance ahead of the laggard. However, for a given distance between leader and laggard, the relative risks to the two fish remained similar with distance from the predator. The cost side of the inequalities that define a ‘Prisoner’s Dilemma’ has thus been measured for this system.
    [Show full text]
  • Cooperation in a Repeated Public Goods Game with a Probabilistic Endpoint
    W&M ScholarWorks Undergraduate Honors Theses Theses, Dissertations, & Master Projects 5-2014 Cooperation in a Repeated Public Goods Game with a Probabilistic Endpoint Daniel M. Carlen College of William and Mary Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.wm.edu/honorstheses Part of the Behavioral Economics Commons, Econometrics Commons, Economic History Commons, Economic Theory Commons, Other Economics Commons, Political Economy Commons, and the Social Statistics Commons Recommended Citation Carlen, Daniel M., "Cooperation in a Repeated Public Goods Game with a Probabilistic Endpoint" (2014). Undergraduate Honors Theses. Paper 34. https://scholarworks.wm.edu/honorstheses/34 This Honors Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Theses, Dissertations, & Master Projects at W&M ScholarWorks. It has been accepted for inclusion in Undergraduate Honors Theses by an authorized administrator of W&M ScholarWorks. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Carlen 1 Cooperation in a Repeated Public Goods Game with a Probabilistic Endpoint A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirement for the degree of Bachelor of Arts in the Department of Economics from The College of William and Mary by Daniel Marc Carlen Accepted for __________________________________ (Honors) ________________________________________ Lisa Anderson (Economics), Co-Advisor ________________________________________ Rob Hicks (Economics) Co-Advisor ________________________________________ Christopher Freiman (Philosophy) Williamsburg, VA April 11, 2014 Carlen 2 Acknowledgements Professor Lisa Anderson, the single most important person throughout this project and my academic career. She is the most helpful and insightful thesis advisor that I could have ever expected to have at William and Mary, going far beyond the call of duty and always offering a helping hand.
    [Show full text]
  • Cooperative Games: Core and Shapley Value
    COOPERATIVE GAMES: CORE AND SHAPLEY VALUE Roberto Serrano CEMFI Working Paper No. 0709 July 2007 CEMFI Casado del Alisal 5; 28014 Madrid Tel. (34) 914 290 551. Fax (34) 914 291 056 Internet: www.cemfi.es CEMFI Working Paper 0709 July 2007 COOPERATIVE GAMES: CORE AND SHAPLEY VALUE Abstract This article describes the basic elements of the cooperative approach to game theory, one of the two counterparts of the discipline. After the presentation of some basic definitions, the focus will be on the core and the Shapley value, two of the most central solution concepts in cooperative game theory. JEL Codes: C7. Keywords: Game theory; cooperative game; characteristic function; solution concept; core; Shapley value; axiomatics; equivalence principle; non-cooperative implementation. Roberto Serrano Brown University and IMDEA [email protected] COOPERATIVE GAMES: CORE AND SHAPLEY VALUE by Roberto Serrano Department of Economics, Brown University and IMDEA-Social Sciences July 2007 (to appear in Encyclopedia of Complexity and Systems Science, Springer, Berlin) Outline: 1. Introduction. 2. Cooperative Games. 2.1. Representations of Games. The Characteristic Function. 2.2. Assumptions on the Characteristic Function. 2.3. Solution Concepts. 3. The Core. 3.1. Non-Emptiness. 3.2. The Connections with Competitive Equilibrium. 3.3. Axiomatic Characterizations. 3.4. Non-Cooperative Implementation. 3.5. An Application. 4. The Shapley Value. 4.1. Axiomatics. 4.2. The Connections with Competitive Equilibrium. 4.3. Non-Cooperative Implementation. 4.4. An Application. 1 Glosary of keywords: game theory; cooperative game; characteristic function; solution concept; core; Shapley value; axiomatics; equivalence principle; non-cooperative implementation. Summary: This article describes the basic elements of the cooperative approach to game theory, one of the two counterparts of the discipline.
    [Show full text]
  • Fear Effect in Prey and Hunting Cooperation Among Predators in A
    MBE, 16(5): 5146–5179 DOI: 10.3934/mbe.2019258 Received: 22 December 2018 Accepted: 29 May 2019 http://www.aimspress.com/journal/MBE Published: 06 June 2019 Research article Fear effect in prey and hunting cooperation among predators in a Leslie-Gower model Saheb Pal1, Nikhil Pal1, Sudip Samanta2 and Joydev Chattopadhyay3;∗ 1 Department of Mathematics, Visva-Bharati, Santiniketan 731235, India 2 Department of Mathematics, Faculty of Science and Arts-Rabigh, King Abdulaziz University, Rabigh-25732, Saudi Arabia 3 Agricultural and Ecological Research Unit, Indian Statistical Institute, 203, B. T. Road, Kolkata 700108, India * Correspondence: Email: [email protected]; Tel: +91-33-25753231; Fax: +91-33-25773049. Abstract: The predation strategy for predators and the avoidance strategy of prey are important topics in ecology and evolutionary biology. Both prey and predators adjust their behaviours in order to gain the maximal benefits and to increase their biomass for each. In the present paper, we consider a modified Leslie-Gower predator-prey model where predators cooperate during hunting and due to fear of predation risk, prey populations show anti-predator behaviour. We investigate step by step the impact of hunting cooperation and fear effect on the dynamics of the system. We observe that in the absence of fear effect, hunting cooperation can induce both supercritical and subcritical Hopf- bifurcations. It is also observed that fear factor can stabilize the predator-prey system by excluding the existence of periodic solutions and makes the system more robust compared to hunting cooperation. Moreover, the system shows two different types of bi-stabilities behaviour: one is between coexisting equilibrium and limit cycle oscillation, and another is between prey-free equilibrium and coexisting equilibrium.
    [Show full text]
  • Explaining Public Goods Game Contributions with Rational Ability
    games Article Explaining Public Goods Game Contributions with Rational Ability Hannes Lang 1,* ID , Gregory DeAngelo 2 and Michelle Bongard 3 1 School of Life Sciences Weihenstephan, Technische Universität München, Alte Akademie 12, 85354 Freising, Germany 2 Department of Economics, 1601 University Avenue, Morgantown, WV 26506, USA; [email protected] 3 RAND Corporation, 4570 Fifth Ave #600, Pittsburgh, PA 15213, USA; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +49-8161-71-5135 Received: 19 March 2018; Accepted: 6 June 2018; Published: 10 June 2018 Abstract: As the link between psychology and economics has grown, so too has research on the link between personality traits and economic behavior. We build on this previous work, bringing to light the relationship between personality traits and contributions in a one-shot public goods game. We find that contributions to the public good are smaller for rational participants as measured by the Rational-Experiential Inventory—revised 40 (REI-40) item scale. We find no effect on contributions for the measures of the Big Five personality traits or the remaining measures from the REI-40. Keywords: public good; cooperation; psychological traits; REI-40; Big Five 1. Introduction The public goods game has become a classic laboratory environment for studying collective group decisions where participants decide how much to contribute to a common pool. The countervailing effect, however, is that there is an incentive for group members to free-ride on individuals that are contributing positive amounts to the common pool. The Nash Equilibrium for this game is to invest an amount of zero to the public good so long as the marginal per capita return is less than one.
    [Show full text]