<<

ISSN 2318-2377

TEXTO PARA DISCUSSÃO N 612

HOW BECAME AN INTERVENTIONIST SCIENCE (AND HOW IT CEASED TO BE)

Rafael Galvão de Almeida

Setembro de 2019

Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais Textos para Discussão

Jaime Arturo Ramírez (Reitor) A série de Textos para Discussão divulga resultados Sandra Regina Goulart Almeida (Vice-reitora) preliminares de estudos desenvolvidos no âmbito Faculdade de Ciências Econômicas do Cedeplar, com o objetivo de compartilhar ideias e obter comentários e críticas da comunidade Hugo Eduardo Araujo da Gama Cerqueira (Diretor) científica antes de seu envio para publicação final. Kely César Martins de Paiva (Vice-Diretora) Os Textos para Discussão do Cedeplar começaram

a ser publicados em 1974 e têm se destacado pela Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento diversidade de temas e áreas de pesquisa. Regional (Cedeplar) Ficha catalográfica

Frederico Gonzaga Jayme Jr (Diretor) A447h Almeida, Rafael Galvão de. Gustavo de Britto Rocha (Vice-Diretor) 2019 How economics became an interventionist science (and how it Laura Rodríguez Wong (Coordenadora do ceased to be) / Rafael Galvão de Programa de Pós-graduação em Demografia) Almeida . - Belo Horizonte : UFMG/CEDEPLAR, 2019. Gilberto de Assis L.ibânio (Coordenador do 23 p. - (Texto para discussão, 612) Programa de Pós-graduação em Economia) Inclui bibliografia (p. 19-23)

ISSN 2318-2377 Adriana de Miranda-Ribeiro (Chefe do Departamento de Demografia) 1. Política econômica 2. Planejamento econômico. 3. Liberalismo I. Universidade Bernardo Palhares Campolina Diniz (Chefe do Federal de Minas Gerais. Centro de Departamento de Ciências Econômicas) Desenvolvimento e Planejamento Regional. II. Título. III. Série. Editores da série de Textos para Discussão CDD: 338.9 Aline Souza Magalhães (Economia) Ficha catalográfica elaborada pela Biblioteca da Adriana de Miranda-Ribeiro (Demografia) FACE/UFMG RSS117/19

Secretaria Geral do Cedeplar As opiniões contidas nesta publicação são de Maristela Dória (Secretária-Geral) exclusiva responsabilidade do(s) autor(es), não Simone Basques Sette dos Reis (Editoração) exprimindo necessariamente o ponto de vista do Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento

Regional (Cedeplar), da Faculdade de Ciências http://www.cedeplar.ufmg.br Econômicas ou da Universidade Federal de Minas

Gerais. É permitida a reprodução parcial deste texto

e dos dados nele contidos, desde que citada a fonte. Reproduções do texto completo ou para fins comerciais são expressamente proibidas.

Opinions expressed in this paper are those of the

author(s) and do not necessarily reflect views of the

publishers. The reproduction of parts of this paper

of or data therein is allowed if properly cited.

Commercial and full text reproductions are strictly

forbidden.

2

UNIVERSIDADE FEDERAL DE MINAS GERAIS FACULDADE DE CIÊNCIAS ECONÔMICAS CENTRO DE DESENVOLVIMENTO E PLANEJAMENTO REGIONAL

HOW ECONOMICS BECAME AN INTERVENTIONIST SCIENCE (AND HOW IT CEASED TO BE)*

Rafael Galvão de Almeida

Mestre em Economia, PPGEC/UFSCar-Sorocaba Doutorando em Economia, CEDEPLAR/UFMG

CEDEPLAR/FACE/UFMG BELO HORIZONTE 2019

* Work in progress. 3

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

SUMÁRIO

1. INTRODUCTION ...... 6

2. ECONOMICS IN THE 1930S ...... 7 2.1. Importance of Keynes ...... 8 2.2. Socialist economic calculation debate ...... 9 2.3. Quantitative methods ...... 9

3. DEVELOPMENT OF THE THEORY OF ECONOMIC POLICY ...... 11 3.1. Theoretical developments ...... 11 3.2. Theory and ideology ...... 13

4. THE RETURN OF FREE-MARKET TO A RELEVANT POSITION ...... 14 4.1. Fall in the 1930s and reorganization ...... 14 4.2. Public choice and political business cycles ...... 14 4.3. Friedman and rational expectations ...... 16

5. CONCLUSION: ECONOMICS AND ITS POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS CHANGE ...... 17

REFERENCES ...... 19

4

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

ABSTRACT

The relationship between economics and State has been intimate ever since classical political . However, perceptions about the role and size of the State have changed according to the epoch. In other words, economic theory assigned a bigger or a smaller role to the State depending on the political situation. This article analyses the change in and economic theory’s perception of the role of the State in the economy, from favoring an interventionist approach from the 1930s to the 1960s, and a liberal approach from 1970s, in order to understand the factors behind this change.

Keywords: theory of economic policy; economic planning; liberalism; neoliberalism

RESUMO

O relacionamento entre ciência econômica e o Estado tem sido íntimo desde a economia política clássica. Porém, as percepções sobre o papel e o tamanho do Estado mudaram de acordo com a época. Em outras palavras, a teoria econômica aceitou um papel maior ou menor ao Estado dependendo da situação política. Esse artigo analisa a mudança da percepção dos economistas e da teoria econômica do papel do Estado na economia, de uma abordagem intervencionista da década de 1930 até a década de 1960, e uma abordagem liberal da década de 1970 em diante, a fim de entender os fatores por trás dessa mudança.

Palavras-chave: teoria da política econômica; planejamento econômico; liberalismo; neoliberalismo

JEL: B22

5

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

The world under heaven, after a long period of division, tends to unite; after a long period of union, tends to divide. Luo Guanzhong, Romance of Three Kingdoms

1. INTRODUCTION

Economics and public policy have had an intimate relationship ever since the establishment of the classical political economy. The current attitude towards State intervention in the economy is not positive towards it:

“In an article published in the New York Times not long before the financial crisis exploded, some interviews with eminent economists implied that rules in favor of ‘free markets’ had become social norms. Princeton professor Alan Blinder declared that ‘anyone who says anything even obliquely that sounds hostile to free trade is treated as an apostate’. David Card, a professor at Berkeley, said, ‘You lose your ticket as a certified if you don’t say any kind of price regulation is bad and free trade is good.” (Dequech, 2017, p. 1638-9).

The stereotype of the economist is someone who is a supporter of the free-market, that problems eventually will solve themselves through supply and demand (Klein, Stern, 2007), exemplified by Margaret Thatcher’s famous dictum: “there is no alternative”1. However, it was not always like that. By the 1940s, Durbin (1949, p. 41) wrote “we are all planners now”, Alvin Hansen pronounced the death of individualism in his textbook on economic policy (Hansen, 1947, p. 14), and Seymour Harris claimed that the invisible hand abandoned its followers in the hour they needed it most (Harris, 1949, p. 15). Frank Knight wrote in 1933: “We cannot go back to laissez-faire in economics even in this country…Now it seems to me inevitable that we must go to a controlled system” (apud Burgin, 2012, p. 4). Stigler complained about the conservatism of economists in policy, part of their stereotype of the time, and how they do not give the due attention to entrepreneurs, instead focusing on bureaucrats (Stigler, 1959, p. 522).

For an economist in our current age, the idea that free-market used to be a heterodox idea seems a bit weird. It shows how the perception of economists towards their own discipline tends to change over time. In contrast, Tinbergen (1956, p. 6, emphasis added) was blunt on what entails economic policy: “economic policy consists of the deliberate manipulation of a number of means in order to attain certain aims”. What cause this change?

The primary objective of this article is to show how this change occurred in time, so it is, by no means, an extensive history of all the changes related to the interventionist-liberal dichotomy, only the ones we considered to be most important. This article has 5 sections besides this introduction: Section 2 explores, in a summarized way, the source of the transformations in economic theory in the 1930s that

1 “This is the mantra chanted by 'dries' during the prime ministerial reign of Margaret Thatcher, by which they demonstrated their belief that free-market capitalism was the only possible economic theory. It was said so often amongst them that it was shortened to TINA”. Source: , accessed March 16th, 2018. 6

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

led to the development of the interventionist logic; Section 3 is about the theory of economic policy, elaborated in Northern Europe by names like Jan Tinbergen and ; Section 4 writes about how liberal and free-market ideas were ignored and how they resurged in the 1970s with rational expectations and public choice theory; Section 5 concludes, wondering about the possibility that economic theory may or may not be influence by trends and vogue.

2. ECONOMICS IN THE 1930S

As Acoccella (2017) showed, it is fundamental to start our research from the 1930s, even in a summarized way. The 1930s was a singular time where both theoretical and practical changes happened in economics, because it occurred concurrent to one of the most important economic crisis of recent history: The Great Depression. The crash of 1929 initiated the Great Depression, an economic crisis that plunged practically the entire world in an economic depression, with millions of unemployed, a halt to world trade and a worsening of social conditions that led to the rise of fascism and Nazism in many countries.

The economic theory did not remain passive against the economic situation. The failure of most economists in foreseeing the crash of 1929 was not the only reason that created a crisis in economics. New theories went and to-and-fro, debates changed the way people understood economics, and economists became professionals in different parts of the world (e.g. Fourcade, 2009). The result was that many authors consider that the interwar period was pluralistic because it is difficult to characterize “interwar economics or economists in any convincing way” (Morgan, Rutherford, 1998, p. 2). It was a crisis that would change the face of economics.

It should be noted that the economic role of the State has been changing during the Great Depression, in a process that started with the formation of modern national states, translating into an unprecedented growth in the middle of the 20th century, more than any time before. Tanzi (2011) attributed this change to the obsolescence of artisanship, that lead to many workers to become unemployed; fearing these workers might cause unrest, thus many governments created a safety net by means of retirement and unemployment support programs, in national accounts term, increased the transferences to the population, a process that increased after the Second World War, after the Allied governments wanted to compensate the soldiers that fought in there (and thus had to grow its bureaucracy to manage this increase in social security demand), and thus increasing taxes; in addition to it, Tanzi identified another factor which was the increase of universal suffrage, which led to greater political demands from the poor population. It should be noted that Tanzi wrote in the context of Western developed countries (in which the most known related document is the Beveridge Report), but the process was not different in underdeveloped countries, to which it can be added development policies. These changes in the way of conducting policy also reflected changes in the way economic theory evolved.

7

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

2.1. Importance of Keynes

The economists affiliated to the German Historical School were the first economists to provide an important contestation of the laissez-faire, in their indictment of English liberal economics and that “the economy wrought by industrial capitalism was a new economy, and a new economy necessitated a new relationship between the state and economic life.” (Leonard, 2016, p. 21). Although they never went as far to propose a theoretical system, their influence was important in German and American progressivist thought. But, according to authors such as Burgin (2012) and Pierson (2012), the modern view on interventionism came to be with the work of in the 1920s. His thought on economic policy started in The Economic Consequences of Peace (Keynes, 1920), in which Keynes criticized the harshness of war reparations imposed on Germany in the aftermath of World War One. He blamed not only on a vengeful spirit but also on bad policy choices, relying on the laissez-faire orthodoxy.

In the 1926’s essay “The End of Laissez-Faire” he wrote “The world is not so governed from above that private and social interest always coincide.” (Keynes, 1932, p. 287, emphasis in the original), thus rejecting the premise that self-interest is enlightened, that the ‘invisible hand’ automatically moves society in the best possible path and that it should not suffer interference from the government. The laissez-faire narrative seemed more “natural” because it established a narrative in which the unbounded market creates wealth, and much stronger narrative than its opponents, viz. protectionism and Marxism.

He criticized not only the theoretical foundation of the laissez-faire but also the attitude of its supporters: “devotees of Capitalism are often unduly conservative, and reject reforms in its technique, which might really strengthen and preserve it, for fear that they may prove to be first steps away from Capitalism itself.” (p. 294). Keynes wanted, above all, the establishment of an alternative between laissez-faire and socialism that preserved the individual rights and entrepreneur spirit and a more just income distribution.

The origin of those challenges to laissez-faire also had their influence thanks to the climate in Cambridge, which fostered a pro-intervention ideology, especially in face of the Great Depression. Richard Kahn, one of Keynes’s professors and collaborators, wrote on how an increase of government spending (like building roads) can make improve the national economic situation by increasing the investment and all the secondary markets surrounding it (by building a road, not only it employs the workers that are working directly on building road, but also the infrastructure surrounding it, like restaurants and hotels), and thus helping to improve the state of general confidence of a country (Kahn, 1931).

The neoclassical synthesis by Hicks (1937) allowed to build a model capable of combining the original Keynesian political activism with a theoretical base to justify intervention according to economic models, making it a synthesis of theory and practice, with the aim of full employment. Klein (1966 [1949], ch. 7) argued Keynesian reforms would not lead to socialism or the loss of individual rights, and they were needed to combat unemployment, which was an evil that led to fascism and war; planning, then, would be the best tool for this objective. And the socialist economic calculation debate validated research on planning from the theoretical point of view.

8

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

2.2. Socialist economic calculation debate

The socialist economic calculation debate happened during the 1920s and 1930s decades and it opposed socialists and laissez-faire economists on the question whether a socialist economy would be possible. It started when Mises argued that a moneyless economy would be impossible. Socialists ignored the practical problem of the economy. He argued that they ignored the real nature of prices: they serve as a benchmark on how to compare alternative projects. Since resources are limited, prices could be used to determine the opportunity cost of projects, prices permit calculation. “Without economic calculation there can be no economy.” (Mises, 1990 [1920], p. 18).

Mises’s article elicited a series of debates in the following years. Barbieri (2004, p. 82) argued that the English debate was the most important because it had a greater audience and because it applied the Walrasian general equilibrium to a socialist economy and the socialists proved that from a theoretical point of view, for the Walrasian model, there is no difference between socialists and capitalist .

This result had been already advanced by the Italian economist Enrico Barone (1935 [1908]), that the socialist State would have the same role of the producer-consumer agent in the general equilibrium model and would become the ‘benevolent dictator’ or the ‘Walrasian salesman’2. Authors such as Fred Taylor, Henry Dickinson and Oskar Lange expanded the claim of equivalence between capitalist and socialist economies to a theoretical level. Among them, Lange (1936) proposed the definitive socialist answer to Mises’s challenge. In his two-part article, On the economic theory of socialism, he argued that if we understand prices as opportunity costs, establishing centrally-fixed prices would not be something only present in a socialist system. Under the management of a central planning board, the government would use historical prices to fix prices in a socialist economy and then instruct the managers of the factories to find an optimal combination of inputs.

Although Hayek would give a reply based on the diffusiveness of information, that would give origin to the concept of a knowledge-based economy (Hayek, 1945), due to this equivalence between capitalist and socialist economies explained by the general equilibrium model, the socialists were seen as the “winners” of the debate for a good period of time. Their victory meant that manipulation of economic variables was a viable way to do economic policy, either for a capitalist or socialist society. Bockmann (2013) showed how the teaching of economics, especially the Walrasian paradigm, was almost identical in the West and the Iron Curtain. As we shall see in the next section, Western socialists were pivotal in creating tools of economic intervention.

2.3. Quantitative methods

The rise of , input-output analysis and national accounts were also important for the establishment of an interventionist economic science. It should be noted that most of these advances in quantitative methods were related to statistics and would find use later to policymaking. This should

2 Walras himself had socialist leanings and defended a central distribution of goods coexisting with a perfectly competitive market. See Cirilo (1980). 9

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

not surprise because historical research shows that “statistics was born as an auxiliary tool to the State” (Duarte, 2011, p. 230, translated). Earlier pre-econometrics economic statisticians, like Henry Ludwell Moore, defended “that complex mathematical theories could in fact be given substantive empirical content to yield concrete results for social policy.” (Epstein, 1987, p. 13).

The foundation of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) by Wesley Mitchell in the 1920s, and lots of similar statistical bureau throughout the world, inaugurated an age where compilation of statistical data was a primary objective of economists. A lot of statistical, monetary, socioeconomic and financial data was available for researchers, thanks to Mitchell and his institutionalist associates (Rutherford, 2003, p. 366). And this availability of data allowed the development of a theory to test it, since the main concern of the institutionalists was to gather data on the business cycle, instead of testing economic theories that might explain the business cycle (Morgan, 1990, p. 45).

And the founders of the econometrics saw an opportunity to use the data available. Two of the most important founders were Ragnar Frisch and Jan Tinbergen, both of them would end up winning the Nobel Memorial prize in economics in 1969 for their contributions to the establishment of the econometrics.

Frisch was one of the “founding fathers” of the , of the Econometrica journal (Louçã, 2007, p. 9-25) and Hoover (2012) credits him for creating the terms econometrics, microeconomics and macroeconomics in their current incarnation. Meanwhile, Tinbergen was a physicist of formation (having , one of the pioneers of quantum mechanics, as his advisor) and went to economics to think about solutions for the problem of and unemployment, thinking it would be more useful to the society as an economist than a physicist (Boumans, 1993; Magnus, Morgan, 1987).

It is worth to note that some of the fathers of econometrics had an ideological inspiration. Unlike Moore, who was an avowed antisocialist, Jan Tinbergen’s motivations to study quantitative methods and to develop econometrics were political, since he was associated with the Dutch socialist party; Frisch also had connections with Norwegian socialist parties as well (Magnus, Morgan, 1987; Alberts, 1994; Louçã, 2007).

Tinbergen also produced two of the most important policy models of the 1930s. The first was the 1936 model, in the article “An economic policy for 1936” (Tinbergen, 1959 [1936]). It is credited to be the first macroeconometric model ever developed and it had an attempt to influence national policymaking with policy recommendations. Tinbergen developed the model under request from the Dutch Economic Association, in an attempt to understand the bad economic situation of the and provide scenarios for its recovery (Magnus, Morgan, 1987, p. 122). In spite of being a rough and problematic effort and because it was addressed to a national audience, the impact of the model was minor, although Tinbergen still considered that it was accurate enough to the actual economic situation (Tinbergen, 1959 [1936], p. 45), and it did help to settle foundations for future models, such as the 1939 model (Dhaene, Barten, 1989).

The 1939 model present in the two-volume report Statistical testing of business-cycle theories (Tinbergen, 1939) was commissioned by the , in order to empirically test theories on

10

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

the business cycles. It should be noted that there was no consensus amongst the economists about which variables were the cause of business cycles (Boumans, 2005, p. 45), so an empirical analysis would be useful to find, at least, negative evidence (that some theories are wrong) through econometrics (Tinbergen, 1939, p. 11). The effort was considered an important mark in the history of econometrics and the debate that followed from Keynes’s negative review (Keynes, 1939) helped to establish econometrics as a viable tool for policy (see Louçã, 2007, ch. 7). Without it, the developments in the theory of economic policy (which will be the next section) would be impossible.

3. DEVELOPMENT OF THE THEORY OF ECONOMIC POLICY

3.1. Theoretical developments

With the prevalence of the synthesis of interventionist Keynesian policy, validation of planning through general equilibrium models and development of planning and econometric tools, it created an environment to allow the development of a theory of economic policy (TEP) and planning tools. Again, Tinbergen and Frisch are the ones credited with developing a theory of economic policy. Before them, theoretical work on economic policy was “little more than a collection of examples of empirical policy” (Acoccella, 2017, p. 662).

After the Second World War was over, the European countries needed to reconstruct their economies, many times almost from the scratch. From now on, planning in both capitalist and socialist economies would become the standard way to do economic policy (Klein, 1947b) and many economists started to follow suit, leading to the creation of a theory of economic policy. Both Tanzi (2011) and Acoccella et al (2016) recognize that the Northern Europe provided the perfect climate for the emergence of a theory of economic policy.

Acoccella (2017) argued that the emergence of TEP the openness of Scandinavia and the Netherlands to theoretical innovation by Wicksell, Ohlin, Myrdal, among others, and their exchange with Keynes (Louçã (2007) added the geographical proximity with the Soviet Union that allowed them being aware of its planning techniques), the interaction between experts and policymakers through the inter-Scandinavian Marstrand meeting and the meetings of the Dutch Economic Association, and the style of planning, being an indicative one.

Amongst the most important of them, Frisch first mentioned that policy could be optimized through flexible variables in a memorandum to the United Nations (Frisch, 1949). His interest in econometrics and quantitative methods existed with the intention of providing tools for economic policy. He showed this intention already in the 1930s (Frisch, 1934), in which planning would obey economic laws of circulation under a general equilibrium framework (Dupont-Kieffer, 2012). His importance in establish a system of national accounts in Norway, the Ecocirc-System, cannot be denied (Bjerve, 1995; Lie, 2007). He was aware of problems such as the Arrow’s paradox and how the political arena could be a place where existed more conflicts than anything else, but he defended that scientific planning was a way to conciliate societal preferences, allowing politicians and scientific experts to cooperate for the

11

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

national welfare, and thus heavy mathematical modelling was a way to give impartial validation to planning (Frisch, 1971; Long, 1979, p. 149).

In Sweden, Erik Lindhal and moved to implement a welfare state, with help from economic theory. Vellupilai (2013, p. 1331) wrote, with a personal testimony of Gertrude Lindhal, Erik’s wife, that Ernst Wiggforss, Swedish finance minister in 1933, came to Lindhal and Myrdal requesting them to elaborate a theory to justify the underbalancing of the budget, against criticism of liberal oppositionists.

In the Netherlands, Tinbergen saw the opportunity to combine his econometric research with concrete policy application. Thus, when he was appointed to the Dutch Central Planning Board (DCPB), he developed the first ideas that would become his theory of economic policy. After the end of the war, there was a shortage of supplies in the Netherlands, so restoring equilibrium in the economy was the primary objective, through intensive control of the economic machinery in order to return to pre-war levels (Tinbergen, 1947). The DCPB itself had little influence in decisive methods, but it provided a large amount of data and techniques for the policymaking (Hughes Hallet, 1988).

First published in 1952, On the theory of economic policy became the first text in an attempt to give theoretical treatment of economic policy. There, he proposed the fundamental concept that “the choice of instruments cannot be separated from the targets and hence from the form of the indicator” (Tinbergen, 1952, p. 4) and that the number of target variables must be equal to the number of instruments, so that its sum with the number of irrelevant variables is equal to the number of structural relations (p. 27).

Later, Tinbergen would consider his theory of economic policy important to the proposal of development policies, with the intention of both creating an environment to development and active intervention in the economy to facilitate the development, and quantitative techniques would be indispensable, making part of the “scientific planning” (Tinbergen, 1967). And even later in his life, he would maintain that “the purpose of economic research is either (a) to attempt to explain an economic phenomenon or (b) to recommend an economic policy or structure” (Tinbergen, 1991, p. 33), showing that economic theory must be purposeful.

The most important modification to Tinbergen’s TEP came from his fellow countryman , colleague and pupil of Tinbergen. According to Hughes Hallet (1989, p. 198-202), his contributions were the result of combining microeconomic demand theory and identified some problems with Tinbergen’s approach, that it was too rigid, because it did not consider the uncertainty of non- controllable variables and poorly specified models, the misnomer of irrelevant variables that turned out to be relevant and the arbitrariness of the value of some target variables.

Theil proposed a way to turn flexible the policy options for the government and turn the choice of the government a tradeoff that could be maximized. Theil’s efforts gave birth to the quadratic loss function , (Theil, 1966, p. 16), which is familiar to any student of intermediate macroeconomics. He mentioned this function has applications in engineering (p. 19) and now he adapted it to economics. Usually the terms are assigned to the variables and unemployment and the policymaker is then given the choice to use policies to minimize both and maximize the product.

12

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

These are some of the most important traditions in TEP. According to Acoccella (2017), there are others traditions in different countries. In Britain, for example, in spite of being one of the most important centers of interventionist ideas, besides Meade, no British economist made an effort to create a systematic theoretical treatment of economic policy (p. 666). This justifies why Tanzi (2011, p. 193) called TEP the “Nordic European economic theory of fiscal policy”. Although the term “theory of economic policy” could mean different things in different contexts, the term became associated with the Theil-Tinbergen approach.

3.2. Theory and ideology

As Acoccella mentioned, “the weight and the left-wing orientation of the ‘intelligentsia’, as well as of the political parties supporting the governments or of some strong opposition parties and institutions (such as trade unions), together with the widespread idea that public happiness should be served by a visible hand” (Acoccella, 2017, p. 668). Planning was invariably associated with what can be considered “left” and it was developed in a time the divide between Capitalist West and Communist East was most hostile. It should be noted that Tinbergen and Frisch’s effort to establish a scientific planning aimed to be a neutral one, in spite of initial socialistic leanings presented their early years and the association of planning with socialism during the economic calculation debate. In other words, they attempted to give a value-free approach to planning through extensive use of quantitative methods, thus they indirectly wanted to imply that “to intervene is to be scientific”.

The use of quantitative methods was also a way to disperse the ideological fears present in the 1950s. Sir Eric Roll wrote that “for a long time any discussion of the forms, methods, merits, and risks of planned tended to be political and emotional” (Roll, 1968, p. 55), but many writers turned to quantitative methods in order to disperse these subjective matters. Bockmann (2013) argued that both in the (during the McCarthyism period) and Soviet Union (the Stalinist purges), economists saw in quantitative methods a way to “escape” ideology, to not have their respective secret services prying on their research3. In Latin America, there was an effort to show how planning techniques were neutral, but the leftist stigma was still present (Bielschowsky, 2004, p. 387).

Tinbergen himself had concrete examples of this dilemma. During his time in the Dutch Central Planning Office, there was a conflict between those who wanted a Soviet-style economic planning (with yearly plans) and those who wanted policy guidelines (Hughes Hallet, 1988). He had to rephrase “emotionally charged words, such as ‘planning’ and ‘National Welfare Plan’, redrafting them into ‘organized foresight’ and ‘Central Economic Plan’. Tinbergen also put considerable effort into promoting ‘The Third Road’, showing the alternative between no planning at all and Soviet-style planning.” (Jolink, 2009, p. 395).

It should be noted that the theory of economic policy was something different from the planning techniques that emerged and were widely used. Propagation of planning techniques was encouraged by the United Nations as a way to develop Third-world countries (e.g. United Nations, 1963). Sir Erich

3 However, see Weintraub (2017) for a critique of this view. 13

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

Roll wrote that “it is however, by no means clear that the next twenty years will produce so radical a change in basic approach as did the last twenty in comparison with the preceding prewar period.” (Roll, 1968, p. 57). He wrote this in 1968. Economic theory would indeed undergo through a radical change but not in the direction he wanted to.

4. THE RETURN OF FREE-MARKET TO A RELEVANT POSITION

4.1. Fall in the 1930s and reorganization

Up until the Great Depression, the laissez-faire doctrine was commonly held as the dominant approach in economics. We saw that Keynes was one of the most important defenders of the idea that laissez-faire harmed capitalism and held it responsible for the crisis of the 1930s. It should be noted that, while economists are not entirely and unambiguously sure of what caused the Great Depression, if lack or excess of intervention prior it and how the countermeasures might have deepened it, the commonly held view is that the countermeasures influenced by the laissez-faire attitude was the “liquidationist” answer to the Great Depression, that is considered the view that worsened the depression (White, 2008)4.

As mentioned before, the association of the 1929 crisis with the liquidationist view and the fact that the equalization of the Walrasian model of a socialist economy with a capitalist one, during the socialist calculation debate, meant a theoretical defeat for the liberals and non-interventionists. With the promise of a social engineering, which Hayek (1973, p. 5) negatively labelled “rationalistic constructivism”, the neoclassical Keynesianism dominated the policy guidance.

Thus, fearing their diminishing influence, they organized first through the Walter Lippman Colloque, in 1938, and then through the Mont Pèlerin Society (MPS), in 1947 (Burgin, 2012). The MPS was pivotal in organizing the liberal movement, in spite of the disputes between the factions (for example, the German ordoliberals and American neoliberals, which ended up in the prevalence of the latter group and posterior alienation of the former in the MPS), the society was important to provide a forum for liberals on how to influence society for the improvement of liberalism.

4.2. Public choice and political business cycles

Amongst the main critics of interventionism were the public choice theorists. Although public choice has different strands, the term is usually associated with the Virginia School of Political Economy (MacLean, 2015), whose most important representative is James Buchanan – although Besley (2006, p. 29) argued that the term “public choice” is referred to any analysis that combines economics and politics, in some circles (a definition we will use for this paper due to the necessity of encapsulating many views into this section). Public choice emerged after application of the concept of the self-interested rational economic agent to politics itself. As we have seen in the previous section, economists believed that the

4 White argues that economists associated with the liquidationist (like Hayek and Robbins) view are incorrectly blamed, and blames the creation of central banks instead. 14

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

policymaker was an altruistic agent that believed that, through extensive mathematical modelling, he could manipulate instrument variables to achieve policy targets.

In one of its earlier papers, Buchanan (1949, p. 505) concluded that we need an “individualistic” theory of government, in which the government is just the collective will of individuals and thus cannot be held responsible by economic action in the abstract sense. Downs (1957) applied utility concept to show that this is how citizens use the government as proxy to enact policies that benefit them. Riker (1962) showed, through extensive use of game theory, how political coalitions are rationally built to win elections. Buchanan and Tullock (1999 [1962]) provided the foundations for constitutional political economy. And Olson (1965) provided a theoretical treatment of political groups and issues of tragedy of commons.

These works are considered the foundational works in public choice theory because they managed to analyze political problems from an economic point of view and, in varying degrees, they provided an alternative to the pro-interventionist TEP by treating policymakers as any other economic agent. In the end, for them, market failure was not a problem as big as government failure (Keech, Munger, 2015). Thus, during its formative years, public choice could be placed in the heterodoxy of economic theory. Rowley (2008) went to the point of claiming that there was a conspiracy of mainstream economics against public choice authors. Medema (2011, p. 232) claimed that public choice theorists might exaggerate the lack of receptivity of public choice ideas, but the fact they were not part of the mainstream during the 1950s and 1960s is clear. Medema (2011) also focused on the fact that public choice theorists built a creative community to help discuss and propagate ideas. The ultimate recognition of public choice ideas came with the Nobel memorial prize of 1986 being given to James Buchanan.

Similarly to public choice, and many times intersecting with it, the research in political business cycles also showed to be an important criticism to the TEP idea of a benevolent policymaker. First formalized by Nordhaus (1975), it provided an important criticism of how state action happens. Basically, a political business cycle happens when the government increases fiscal/monetary expenditures in election years; these policies increase the popularity of the incumbent government, by transferring income to the electorate, and increasing its chances of being reelected at the cost of inducing future inflation. Then, the government has to enact austerity policies to curb this inflation and, when there is a new election, the cycle begins anew.

Although there are debates about the nature and actual existence of political business cycles (e.g. Dubois, 2016), it provided a conceptual problem for long-term planning: “A final reason for explaining the scarce attention to long-term planning (and then to an ingredient of the core) might be tied to the importance of the Nordhaus political business cycle and the political aspects of policy, at least in some countries, such as the USA, Canada, Japan and, possibly, Germany, in contrast with Scandinavian countries.” (Acoccella, 2017, p. 668-669). If the government freely manipulated the economy in order to achieve reelection, it remained little attention to long-term planning questions, although Acoccella argued that it depends on the political culture of the country, a result that is corroborated by recent political business cycle literature (Franzese, Jusko, 2006).

15

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

4.3. Friedman and rational expectations

Milton Friedman was, probably, the most important economist to challenge the synthetized Keynesianism. Burgin (2012) considered him to have the same influence Keynes had, since they both used similar methods (becoming public intellectuals) in order to propagate their ideologies. One of his first academic articles was a critical review of Tinbergen’s report (Friedman, 1942) and he remained critical of the Klein-Goldberg and structural models. “From Friedman’s point of view, his monetary theory was a little David that succeeded against the Goliath of Keynesian multi-equation system. His results were all the more disturbing to Keynesians who, as mentioned before, were positing structures of greatly increased complexity.” (Epstein, 1987, p. 126). Further, Burgin argued that:

“The publication of “The Methodology of Positive Economics” [Friedman, 1953] was a pivotal moment in the history of free-market advocacy for two reasons. First, Friedman’s emphasis on the necessary descriptive simplification entailed in the act of generating hypotheses reinvigorated the embattled theory of perfect competition. Economists had long struggled against the descriptive inaccuracies of the homo economicus…The defense of simplified hypotheses in [the article] was, implicitly if not overtly, a defense of the mode of perfect competition…Friedman had opened a formidable new front in an argument that many in the prior generation of free-market economists had abandoned as lost.” (p. 161)

Thus, according to Burgin, Friedman’s methodological views proved to be a theoretical base for laissez-faire theory, to contrast with the neoclassical Keynesian’s theoretical base for interventionist on econometrics and the theory of economic policy. His reason for the Great Depression argued that it was the FED’s failure to keep the supply of money in the economy, thus shifting the “blame” of the Great Depression from the markets to State intervention – or lack of (Friedman, Schwartz, 1963). He helped to popularize the label “monetarist”, which was initially related to the control of money supply by the and skepticism towards fiscal policy, but became associate with liberalization and opposition to State intervention.

Friedman worked with theory (especially monetary theory), but his greatest achievement for liberalism was his capacity of being a public intellectual. The theoretical role would belong to Robert Lucas and the proponents of the rational expectations hypothesis.

The rational expectation hypothesis (REH) changed the economic theory again. The apparently simple but mathematically complex definition that economic agents use all the information available, both in the past and present, to make their judgements. Not only this, but, as De Vroey (2016) shows, Lucas had an intention of replacing the Keynesian theory.

The REH paved way to the real-business cycle theory and the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models, that followed calibration instead of estimation. However, while the REH meant an evolution in economic theory, the relationship with economic policy was shaken. For once,

16

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

the REH established the “policy ineffectiveness proposition” (PIP), in which policy intervention would be neutral due to rational expectations (Sargent, Wallace, 1975).

The PIP meant that the agents could predict the consequences of an announced economic policy and adjust their expectations accordingly and thus eliminating the effect of the policy. However, even in spite of the PIP, economic policy has still been practiced. Some authors try to incorporate the REH tenets into their economic policy research, while other have been attempting to formulate alternatives to the REH and DSGEs. Thus, the theory of economic policy was just mere management of some variables, with little mention of active intervention (e.g. Sargent, Wallace, 1976). “This state of affairs had led to a widening of the gap between the production of economic science and the art of economic policy.” (De Vroey, 2016, p. 306).

5. CONCLUSION: ECONOMICS AND ITS POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS CHANGE

The epigraph of this paper quotes the opening line of The Romance of the Three Kingdoms, a highly fictionalized history of the Warring States period in Ancient China, 169-280AD, written in the 14th century (Luo, 2015). It opened with the breakdown of the Han dynasty and ends with its reunification under the Jin dynasty. It recognized a constant process in Chinese history, of cycles of separation and unification of the Chinese state. Though this principle was meant to be broadly understood. In economics, this article attempted to provide an overview of the fact that interventionism was once understood as a standard belief in economics and free-market liberalism was considered a heterodox belief. The situation inverted after the 1970s, when theoretical developments that criticized state action and defended a return to laissez-faire became the norm. In both cases, the change in economic theory was linked to a change in the global economic situation

Interestingly enough, some authors had thoughts about whether there is a cyclical component. W. Arthur Lewis, winner of the Nobel memorial prize of 1979, and John Jewkes, president of the Mont Pèlerin Society from 1962-1964, though writers themselves of treatises on economic planning, wondered if the euphoria of planning would be transitory - whether it was just a fad5 (Jewkes, 1950, p. 3), or part of a cycle wherein the importance given to the powers of the state in economic theory oscillated (Lewis, 1952, p. 21).

Changes in the way economists perceived intervention happened in other periods of time. Thomas Leonard, in his Illiberal Reformers (2016), had a historical account of how progressive American economists, influenced by German thought and eugenics, attempted to create a State planned and managed by science that would induce to a biologically efficient State. Lots of economists and other social scientists (such as Richard T. Ely, John R. Commons, , Edward A. Ross, Oliver Wendell Holmes and even presidents Theodore Roosevelt and Woodrow Wilson) supported a social engineering that would eventually turn the United States in a perfect moral managerial state. The classical liberal thought, which included free-market, was seen as a superstition at best by them and they proclaimed the future would be collectivist. The cost was that undesirable, disenfranchised Whites,

5 In an article from 2016, the writers at The Economist claimed that economists are prone to fads, especially in quantitative methods (The Economist, 2016). 17

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

Blacks, Asians, Eastern Europeans, Native Americans, the disabled and women would have to have their liberties limited or even they would be forcefully kept in the worse parts of society, all in name of efficiency. This still has enduring effects on American society today.

And yet, the views on interventionism in the United States changed; Acoccella wrote that the reasons why a theory of economic policy did not develop in the United States “where the dominant credo was one of scarce public interventions, with the exception of unemployment and anti-inflationary policies” and the scarce literature “lacked systematic treatment of the general ends of public economic action, dealing mainly with more or less technical notions of the policy instruments that can be used to further specific ends” (Acoccella, 2017, p. 666).

The recent financial crisis in 2007-2008 also provided an occasion to discuss economic theory. Due to overall failure in predicting the crisis, many people started to question the fundamentals of mainstream economic theory, with many articles demanding a revision of central tenets, such as general equilibrium and the relationship between theory and evidence (e.g. Colander et al, 2009; Kirman, 2010; Stiglitz, 2011). However, Dobusch and Kappeller (2009) argued that the presence of restrictive norms concerning research and publication will ensue that the situation will not change much, not to mention the bigger importance of networks that keep the current orthodoxy afloat.

Perhaps the very idea of an interventionist-liberal cycle might be coincidental or farfetched, but this article showed how economists can change their minds, due to a series of processes it should be noted that some studies find out that, even in spite of the unbounded free-market stereotype, most economists tend to be “middle of the road”, preferring a mix of intervention and liberalism (Klein, Stern, 2007), and the theory of economic policy has absorbed much of earlier criticism and has evolved (e.g. Acoccella, Di Bartolomeo, Hughes Hallet, 2016). We identified there is an overall change and proposed some basic explanations. While this article used a “broad” approach to history of economic thought, it provides guidelines for more applied work.

18

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

REFERENCES

ACOCCELLA, N. The rise and of economic policy as an autonomous discipline: a critical survey. Journal of Economic Surveys, v. 31, n. 3, p. 661-677, 2017.

____.; DI BARTOLOMEO, G.; HUGHES HALLET, A. Macroeconomic paradigms and economic policy: from the Great Depression to the Great Recession. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2016.

ALBERS, G. On connecting socialism and mathematics: Dirk Struik, Jan Burgers, and Jan Tinbergen. Historia Mathematica, v. 21, p. 280-305, 1994.

BARBIERI, F. História do debate do cálculo socialista. Doctoral thesis. Faculdade de Economia e Administração, Universidade de São Paulo. São Paulo: Universidade de São Paulo, 2004.

BARONE, E. The ministry of production in the collectivist state. 1935 [1908], p. 245-290. In: HAYEK, F. (ed.). Collectivist economic planning. London: Routledge, 1935.

BESLEY, T. Principled agents? The political economy of good governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006.

BIELSCHOWSKY, R. Pensamento econômico brasileiro: O ciclo ideológico do desenvolvimentismo, 5ª ed., Rio de Janeiro: Contraponto, 2004.

BJERVE, P. J. The influence of Ragnar Frisch on macroeconomic planning and policy in Norway. Working paper, Statistics Norway Research Department, 1995.

BOCKMANN, J. Markets in the name of socialism: the left-wing origins of neoliberalism. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2013.

BOUMANS, M. J. How economists model the world into numbers. New York: Routledge, 2005.

BUCHANAN, J. The pure theory of government finance: a suggested approach. Journal of Political Economy, v. 57, n. 6, p. 496-505, 1949.

_____.; TULLOCK, G. The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Indianapolis: , 1999 [1962].

BURGIN, A. The great persuasion: reinventing the free markets since the Depression. Cambridge: Press, 2012.

CIRILO, R. The ‘socialism’ of Léon Walras and his economic thinking. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, v. 39, n. 3, pp. 295-303, 1980.

COLANDER, D.; GOLDBERG, M.; HAAS, A.; JUSELIUS, K.; KIRMAN, A.; LUX, T.; SLOTH, B. The financial crisis and the systemic failure of the economics profession. Critical Review, v. 21, n. 2-3, p. 249-267, 2009.

DEQUECH, D. Some institutions (social norms and conventions) of contemporary mainstream economics, macroeconomics and financial economics. Cambridge Journal of Economics, v. 41, p. 1627-1652, 2017.

19

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

DE VROEY, M. A history of macroeconomics from Keynes to Lucas and beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2016.

DHAENE, G.; BARTEN, A. P. When it all began: the 1936 Tinbergen model revisited. Economic Modelling, v. 6, p. 203-219, 1989.

DOBUSCH, L.; KAPELLER, J. Diskutieren und Zitieren: zur paradigmatischen Konstellation aktueller ökonomischer Theorie. Intervention, v. 6, n. 2, p. 145-152, 2009.

DOWNS, A. An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row, 1957.

DUARTE, P. G. A contribuição da econometria para o debate macroeconômico. In: DUARTE, P. G.; SILBER, S. D.; GUILHOTO, J. J. M. (Orgs.). O Brasil e a ciência econômica em debate: o estado da arte em economia. São Paulo: Saraiva, 2011. v. 2, p. 229-251.

DUBOIS, E. Political business cycles 40 years after Nordhaus. Public Choice, v. 166, n. 1, p. 235-259, 2016.

DUPONT-KIEFFER, A. Ragnar Frisch’s “Circulation planning”: an attempt at modelling general equilibrium. Œconomia, v. 2, n. 3, p. 281-303, 2012.

DURBIN, E. F. M. Problems of Economic Planning: papers on planning and economics. London, Routledge & Paul 1949.

EPSTEIN, R. J. A history of econometrics. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1987

FRANZESE, R. J., Jr.; JUSKO, K. L. Political-economic cycles. In: WEINGAST, B. R.; WITTMAN, D. A. (eds.). The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006.

FRIEDMAN, M. Statistics and its methods. American Economic Review, v. 30, n. 3, p. 657-660, Sept. 1940.

_____. The methodology of positive economics. 1953. In: FRIEDMAN, M. Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, p. 3-43, 1966.

_____.; SCHWARTZ, A. J. A monetary history of the United States: 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.

FRISCH, R. Circulation planning: proposal for a national organization of a commodity and service exchange. Econometrica, v. 2, n. 3, p. 258-336, 1934.

_____. A memorandum on price-wage-tax-subsidy policies as instruments in maintaining optimal employment. U. N. Document, E/CN.1/Sub 2, 1949.

_____. Co-operation between politicians and econometricians on the formalization of economic preferences. 1971. In LONG, F. (ed.) Economic planning studies: collected essays by Ragnar Frisch. Dordretch: Reidel, p. 41-86, 1976.

FOURCADE, M. Economics and societies: discipline and profession in the United States, Britain and France. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2009.

HANSEN, A. H. Economic Policy and Full Employment. New York: MacGraw Hill, 1947.

20

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

HARRIS, S. E. Economic Planning: the plans of fourteen countries with analyses of the plans. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1949.

HAYEK, F. A. The use of knowledge in society, 1945. In: _____. Individualism and economic order. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1980, p. 77-91

_____. Law, legislation and liberty: a new statement of the liberal principles of justice and political economy. London: Routledge, 1973.

HICKS, J. R. Mr. Keynes and the "classics": a suggested interpretation. Econometrica, v. 5, n. 2, p. 147-159, 1937.

HUGHES HALLET, A. J. Econometrics and the theory of economic policy: the Tinbergen-Theil contributions 40 years on. Oxford Economic Papers, v. 41, n. 1, p. 189-214.

JOLINK, A. Jan Tinbergen’s statistical contribution to economic policy. Statistica Neerlandica, v. 63, n. 4, p. 385-399, 2009.

KAHN, R. F. The relation of home investment to unemployment. Economic Journal, v. 41, n. 162, pp. 173-198, 1931.

KEECH, W. R.; MUNGER, M. C. The anatomy of government failure. Public Choice, v. 164, n. 1, p. 1-42, 2015.

KEYNES, J. M. The economic consequences of peace. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Howe, 1920. Available at .

_____. Essays in persuasion. London: Macmillian, 1932. Available at .

_____. The general theory of employment, interest, and money. Adelaide: Ebooks@Adelaide, 2010 [1936].

_____. Professor Tinbergen’s method. The Economic Journal, v. 49, p. 558-568, 1939.

KIRMAN, A. The economic crisis is a crisis for economic theory. CESifo Economic Studies, v. 56, n. 4, p. 498-535, 2010.

KLEIN, L. R. The use of econometric models as a guide to economic policy. Econometrica, v. 15, p. 108-131, 1947.

_____. The Keynesian revolution. 2nd ed. London: Macmillian, 1966 [1949].

KLEIN, D. B.; STERN, C. Is there a free-market economist in the house? The policy views of American Economic Association members. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, v. 66, n. 2, p. 309-334, 2007.

LANGE, O. On the economic theory of socialism: part one. Review of Economic Studies, v. 4, n. 1, pp. 53-71, 1936.

LEONARD, T. C. Illiberal reformers: race, eugenics & American economics in the Progressive Era. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2016.

21

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

LIE, E. The “protestant” view: the Norwegian and Scandinavian approach to national accounting in the postwar period. History of Political Economy, v. 39, n. 4, p. 713-734, 2007.

LONG, F. Ragnar Frisch: econometrics and political economy of planning. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, v. 38, n. 2, p. 141-153.

LOUÇÃ, F. The econometric challenge to Keynes: arguments and contradictions in the early debates about a late issue. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, v. 6, n. 3, p. 404- 438, 1999.

_____. The years of high econometrics: a short history of the generation that reinvented economics. London: Routledge, 2007.

LUO G. Romance of the Three Kingdoms. Translated by C. H. Brewitt-Taylor. N.L.: Amazon Kindle Books, 2015.

MACLEAN, I. The strange history of social choice, and the contribution of the Public Choice Society to its fifth revival. Public Choice, v. 163, p. 153-165, 2015.

MAGNUS, J. R.; MORGAN, M. S. The ET interview: Professor J. Tinbergen. Econometric Theory, v. 3, p. 117-142, 1987.

MEDEMA, S. G. Public choice and deviance: a comment. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, v. 63, n. 1, p. 51-54, 2004.

_____. Public choice and the notion of creative communities. History of Political Economy, v. 43, n. 1, p. 225-246, 2011.

MISES, L. von. Economic calculation in the socialist commonwealth. Translated by S. Adler. Auburn: Mises Institute, 1990 [1920].

MORGAN, M. The history of econometric ideas. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.

_____.; RUTHERFORD, M. American economics: the character of transformation. History of Political Economy, v. 30 (supplement), pp. 1-26, 1998.

NORDHAUS, W. D. The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, v. 42, n. 2, p. 169- 190, 1975.

OLSON, M. The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1965.

ROLL, E. The world after Keynes: an examination of the economic order. London: Pall Mall Press, 1968.

ROWLEY, C. Public choice trailblazers versus the tyranny of the intellectual establishment. In: _____; SCHNEIDER, F. Readings in public choice and constitutional political economy. New York: Springer, p. 47-76, 2008.

RUTHERFORD, M. American institutional economics in the interwar period. In: SAMUELS, W. J.; BIDDLE, J. E.; DAVIS, J. B (Ed.). A companion to the history of economic thought. Malden, Oxford, Melbourne, Berlin: Blackwell Publishing, p. 36-373, 2003.

22

How Economics Became an Interventionist Science (and how it ceased to be) - TD 612(2019)

SARGENT, T. J.; WALLACE, N. “Rational” expectations, the optimal monetary instrument, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy, v. 83, n. 2, p. 241-254, 1975.

_____. Rational expectations and the theory of economic policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, v. 2, p. 169-183, 1976.

STIGLER, George. The politics of political economists. Quarterly Journal of Economics, v. 73, n. 4, p. 522-532, 1959.

STIGLITZ, J. Rethinking macroeconomics: what failed, and how to repair it. Journal of the European Economic Association, v. 9, n. 4, p. 591-645, 2011.

TANZI, V. Governments versus markets: the changing role of the State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011.

THEIL, H. Applied economic forecasting. Amsterdam: North- Holland, 1966.

THE ECONOMIST. Economists are prone to fads, and the latest one is machine learning. November 24th 2016. Available at . Access: March 15th 2018.

TINBERGEN, J. An economic policy for 1936. In: KLAASEN, L. et al. Jan Tinbergen: selected papers. Amsterdam: North Holland, p. 36-84, 1959 [1936].

_____. Statistical testing of business-cycle theories: a method and its application to investment activity. Geneva: League of Nations, 1939.

_____. Central planning in the Netherlands. Review of Economic Studies, v. 15, n. 2, p. 70-77, 1947.

_____. On the theory of economic policy. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1952.

_____. Economic policy: principles and design. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1956.

_____. Planificación del desarrollo. New York: Guadamarra, 1967.

_____. The functioning of economic research. Journal of Economic Issues, v. 25, n. 1, p. 33-38.

UNITED NATIONS. Planning for economic development: report of the Secretary-General transmitting the study of a group of experts. New York, USA: UN, 1963.

VELLUPILAI, K. V. Towards a political economy of the theory of economic policy. Cambridge Journal of Economics, v. 38, p. 1329-1338, 2013.

WEINTRAUB, E. R. McCarthyism and the mathematization of economics. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, v. 39, n. 4, p. 571-597, 2017.

WHITE, L. H. Did Hayek and Robbins deepen the great depression? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, v. 40, n. 4, pp. 751-768, 2008.

23