<<

Asset accounting, fiscal policy and the UK’s oil and gas resources, past and future Giles Atkinson and Kirk Hamilton September 2016 Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy Working Paper No. 280 Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment Working Paper No. 250

The Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy (CCCEP) was established by the University of Leeds and the London School of Economics and Political Science in 2008 to advance public and private action on climate change through innovative, rigorous research. The Centre is funded by the UK Economic and Social Research Council. Its second phase started in 2013 and there are five integrated research themes: 1. Understanding green growth and climate-compatible development 2. Advancing climate finance and investment 3. Evaluating the performance of climate policies 4. Managing climate risks and uncertainties and strengthening climate services 5. Enabling rapid transitions in mitigation and adaptation

More information about the Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy can be found at: http://www.cccep.ac.uk.

The Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment was established by the London School of Economics and Political Science in 2008 to bring together international expertise on economics, finance, geography, the environment, international development and political economy to create a world- leading centre for policy-relevant research and training. The Institute is funded by the Grantham Foundation for the Protection of the Environment and the Global Green Growth Institute. It has nine research programmes: 1. Adaptation and development 2. Carbon trading and finance 3. Ecosystems, resources and the natural environment 4. Energy, technology and trade 5. Future generations and social justice 6. Growth and the . International environmental negotiations 8. Modelling and decision making 9. Private sector adaptation, risk and insurance

More information about the Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment can be found at: http://www.lse.ac.uk/grantham.

This working paper is intended to stimulate discussion within the research community and among users of research, and its content may have been submitted for publication in academic journals. It has been reviewed by at least one internal referee before publication. The views expressed in this paper represent those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the host institutions or funders.

Asset Accounting, Fiscal Policy and the UK’s Oil and Gas Resources, Past and Future

Giles Atkinson1,2 and Kirk Hamilton2 1 Department of Geography and Environment and 2 Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and Environment, London School of Economics and Political Science, Houghton Street, London, WC2E 2AE, UK

Contact: [email protected]

Abstract: The UK has been an exception to the trend of channelling revenues arising from the depletion of subsoil assets into a resource fund. In this paper, we construct an asset account for the UK’s oil and gas resources to evaluate the cost of this exceptionalism and, looking forward, the implications of establishing a fund now. We show that had a decision been made to establish a resource fund in 1975, this fund could now be substantial in size (about GBP 280 billion in 2010). A significant contributor to this result is the historical efficiency of the UK fiscal regime in capturing oil and gas rents, as we demonstrate. A further benefit of the resource fund would have been a reduction in volatility of resource revenues flowing to the Treasury. An ex post cost-benefit analysis of the simulated fund suggests it could have been a sound public investment. However, our simulation of a future resource fund based on (possible) gas and oil revenues shows that it could reach a size similar to the 1975-2010 fund only under optimistic assumptions about prices, revenues and economic reserves.

Acknowledgements: We would like to thank Renaud Coulomb and Emanuele Campiglio for comments on an earlier draft.

1

1. Introduction

The recent evidence that the UK may possess sizable resources of and oil has prompted reflection about whether the UK ‘wasted’ its resource, and whether some form of sovereign wealth fund (SWF) would now be a more effective way to use tax revenues from shale gas and oil exploitation. A meaningful answer to the question of ‘wasted’ assets seems out of reach, not least because of the difficulty of building a plausible counterfactual. But it is worth revisiting the historical data on North Sea petroleum to consider a number of questions concerning the contribution of the sector to the development of the UK economy.

Hamilton and Ley (2011) list 12 countries or jurisdictions where resource funds and/or fiscal rules for resource revenues have been implemented.1 Given that North Sea revenues reached 9.9% of fiscal revenues and 3.7% of GDP in 1984, with revenues exceeding 1% of GDP from 1979 to 1987, it is fair to ask whether the UK was an outlier in not establishing some form of SWF (for a historical analysis of the UK oil and gas industry see, e.g. Kemp, 2011a,b; Harvie, 1994; Stewart, 2013).

Exhaustible resources and the revenues they generate present two broad problems for macroeconomic management: gross production and tax revenues tend to be large and highly volatile, and the stream of revenues is finite, ending when the resource deposit ceases to be economic. Large flows of resource tax revenues lead to the distinct risk that fiscal policy will be pro-cyclical and hence a source of macroeconomic instability. And the finite nature of the resource revenue stream raises important questions about the sustainability of the macroeconomy – will wellbeing fall as the resource is exhausted? The contribution of this paper is to demonstrate how asset accounting can throw light on this debate in a number of ways.

We construct natural resource asset accounts for the UK covering the period 1975 to 2010 in order to examine several key aspects of the North Sea experience (for a general discussion see UN, 2013; Hamilton and Hartwick, 2014, Obst and Vardon, 2014). Building resource asset accounts requires the estimation of resource rents, and these rents provide a useful for the effectiveness of revenue capture from petroleum production through the tax regime (henceforth, in this paper, ‘resource revenues’). This is because the rent is, in effect, the payment owed to the owner of the natural resource, e.g. the government (for a broader discussion of resource taxation, see Keen and MacPherson, 2010). The resource asset accounts also yield a measure of the value of resource depletion (Hamilton, 2014), another useful benchmark for resource revenue generation. Finally, we integrate the resource asset account with national accounts data to calculate a fundamental sustainability indicator, ‘adjusted’ net savings, and related indicators of net wealth creation.

As Ossowski et al. (2008) argue, some combination of a natural resource fund and fiscal rules on the use of resource revenues can reduce pro-cyclical tendencies and provide investments and savings to support future wellbeing in extractive economies. Recent interest has focused in particular on how resource revenues could be channelled into a financial asset such as a

1 Some of these funds combine saving and stability objectives (e.g. Kuwait and ) while other countries have funds for one objective only (e.g. savings in Alaska and Alberta and stability in Papua New Guinea and Venezuela) or separate funds to serve distinct objectives (e.g. Oman).

1 sovereign wealth fund (SWF) (see also, for example: Davis et al. 2003; van der Ploeg, 2014, Hassler et al. 2015; Clark et al. 2013).2

We simulate a simplified version of the Norwegian Government Pension Fund for the UK by assuming that all resource revenues from the North Sea were invested in a global portfolio of financial assets, and that the fund paid out a fixed percentage of assets, 3.9%, to the Treasury from 1975 to 2010.3 The simulation answers four questions. First, how large a sacrifice, in terms of reduced current revenues, would this have entailed? Secondly, in what year would fund payouts have exceeded current resource revenues? Thirdly, how much would the fund have reduced the volatility of resource revenues flowing into the Treasury? Finally, how large would the fund and the payout have been in 2010?

Looking forward, we also simulate a SWF for the UK that begins operation in 2015. The fund accumulates revenues from the declining North Sea reserves and, starting as early as 2025, accumulates (potential) revenues from shale gas and oil as well. Under the most favourable projections for recoverable resources, extraction, prices and rents, by 2040 this fund could grow as large as the fund we simulate for 1975 to 2010. Yet for less favourable projections, this potential fund is smaller, possibly significantly so and underlining further perhaps past opportunities missed.

Our conclusions on the effectiveness of resource taxation in the UK are positive: on average 65% of resource rent and 80% of resource depletion values were captured by taxes and royalties over 1975-2010. The conclusions on the sustainability of the economy are less encouraging – if we deduct the value of resource depletion from published estimates of net national saving for the UK, in most years this measure is less than 4% of GNI and it approaches 0 in some years.

The simulated SWF for 1975 to 2010 shows that sacrifices in terms of foregone current revenues to the Treasury would have been large, 10-20 billion constant 2010 GBP, over the years 1979 to 1987. By 1988, however, payouts from the SWF would have exceeded resource revenues and the value of the fund would have doubled the size of the government balance sheet by 2010. The volatility of payouts from the fund would also have been much lower than the volatility of resource revenues from 1985 to 2010.

It is important to note that our simulation of a SWF is a partial analysis rather than a full counterfactual scenario for government finances in the presence of a SWF. Since there is little economic logic to simultaneously increasing debt and paying resource revenues into a SWF, the implication is that a counterfactual would have to include reductions in public expenditures and/or increases in non-petroleum revenue.4 The numbers are large enough that macroeconomic consequences could be expected. However, our judgment is that a full counterfactual would be arbitrary in many ways.

2 An alternative model for a fund is an earmarked pot with which to finance projects identified ‘now’ as being productive investments (van den Ploeg, 2014). For example, this investment might be in domestic produced, human capital or even natural capital. 3 Our analysis therefore builds on Hawksworth (2008) which calculates that the UK could have had a fund of some GBP 450 billion (an amount greater than the tax revenues collected over the period of that study). (2009) also simulate the establishment of a (hypothetical) past fund by assuming different (but relatively modest) percentages of tax revenues being invested as well as different rates of return. 4 There is an element of endogeneity at work here as well, since the availability of resource revenues may have led government to reduce or restrain taxation of the non-petroleum economy.

2

Rather than constructing a counterfactual for government income and expenditure, we carry out an ex post cost-benefit analysis of introducing a SWF for two different starting points, 1975 and 1990. The costs of the SWF are the petroleum tax revenues paid into it, rather than into general revenues; the benefits are the payouts from the fund to the Treasury. Because the fund can, in principle, provide revenues in perpetuity after the depletion of the resource, the result is that benefits exceed costs by 10% to 100% depending on the start year and the social discount rate. A SWF would have been a sound public investment.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents an account for oil and gas assets in the UK over the period 1975-2010 and derives alternative measures of net saving over this period. This section also reviews resource revenues generated and benchmarks them against total resource rents and the value of resource depletion. Section 3 then models the size of a hypothetical SWF based on historical resource revenues and provides projections to 2040 based upon potential revenues from conventional and non-conventional petroleum resources – these are the “two windfalls” of the title of the paper. Section 4 discusses this costs and benefits of establishing a UK SWF including an ex post CBA. Section 5 concludes.

2. Accounting for UK Oil and Gas

2.1 The UK Petroleum Asset Account

The petroleum asset account constructed here is based on standard resource accounting principles as laid out in the United Nations System of Environmental and Economic Accounts (UN SEEA) (UN 2013). The starting point is an estimate of resource rents, which are measured as the difference between resource revenues and the economic cost of extraction, which includes current extraction costs, depreciation and the opportunity cost of fixed capital.

A complication in asset accounting for the UK is that there are no separate extraction cost estimates available for . We therefore use the oil extraction costs in estimating resource rents, and treat gas as a co-product of oil extraction. Resource revenues in the rent calculation are therefore the sum of revenues from oil and gas extraction. For purposes of measuring unit resource rents, gas is measured in tonnes of oil equivalent so that it can be added to quantities of crude oil.

Table 1: Assumptions and Parameter Choices for Petroleum Asset Accounts

Assumption or parameter Value Resource lifetime Capped at 25 years at current production rates Path of resource rents Fixed at the current year and held constant up to the point of exhaustion Co-production For accounting purposes gas is treated as a co-product of oil extraction Opportunity cost of fixed capital 4.3% (assumed rate of return on assets) Discount rate 3.5%

Resource asset values are calculated as the present value of resource rents up to the point of exhaustion. Physical reserves are measured as the sum of proven and probable resources. We assume a cap on reserves equal to 25 times current production. While oil reserve estimates for

3 the UK exceeded 25 years up to 1980, extrapolating resource rents more than 25 years into the future seems dubious, particularly given the volatility of resource prices. For purposes of the present value calculation, resource rents are fixed at the current year and held constant up to the point of exhaustion. This is how resource asset values are typically estimated, although in some instances governments use specific forecasts of prices, costs and quantities extracted (see, for example, ONS, 2014 and Kahn et al. 2013). The key assumptions and parameters used in estimating petroleum asset values are shown in Table 1.

The rate of return used to establish the opportunity cost of fixed capital is equal to the 10 year moving average of interest rates on government bonds as measured in 2013, while the discount rate is the recommended rate from the UK Green Book for cost-benefit analyses covering periods of 30 years or less (HM Treasury, 2003). For simplicity we assume these rates to be fixed from 1975 to 2010, which may lead to minor differences between our asset estimates and any values published by the UK Office for National Statistics (ONS).

As stipulated in the SEEA, the value of depletion of petroleum is measured as the unit value of depletion times the quantity extracted (where, again, gas is measured in tonnes of oil equivalent). The unit value of depletion is equal to the current resource asset value divided by the current physical stock (capped at 25 years lifetime). Note that this methodology implicitly accounts for resource discoveries if the resource lifetime is less than the cap. As shown in Hamilton and Atkinson (2013), as long as resource rents are assumed to be constant over the resource lifetime, the unit value of depletion declines when there is an increase in the physical stock owing to discoveries. Other things being equal then, a depletion-adjusted measure of Net National Income rises when new resources are discovered. The resulting resource asset account estimates can be found in Annex 1 to this paper.

2.2 The Linkage between Resource Asset Accounting and Policy

Measuring the value of resource depletion is an essential input into policies for sustainable development in extractive economies. The Hartwick Rule (Hartwick 1977) shows that future consumption can be sustained when exhaustible resources are extracted if other investments offset the value of resource depletion. Hamilton and Clemens (1999) show that wellbeing cannot be sustained if ‘genuine’ saving, including the value of resource depletion, is negative. This forward-looking strategy for saving has parallels too with the permanent income hypothesis (PIH) (see, for example, van der Ploeg, 2014).

The practical link between changes in total wealth and sustainability was first explored by Pearce and Atkinson (1993). Subsequent growth theoretic literature, including Hamilton and Clemens (1999), Dasgupta and Mäler (2000) and Asheim and Weitzman (2001), has elaborated the theoretical foundations for this approach to measuring sustainability. The SEEA enshrines these findings in its definition of two extended national accounting aggregates – depletion-adjusted saving and depletion-adjusted national income. Similarly, the World Bank publishes figures on Adjusted Net Saving (ANS) going back to 1970 for over 150 countries in the World Development Indicators – this extended measure of the change in real wealth includes not only resource depletion but also investments in human capital and damages from pollution exposure.

In Figure 1, we combine these indicators with the findings from our resource asset account to comment on asset accumulation and wealth more generally for the UK. Except for the early 1980s, the value of resource depletion is a relatively small share of Gross National Income

4

(GNI). ANS is fairly low but positive, with education expenditure playing a big role in keeping it above zero. The new SEEA statistical standard – which excludes this education expenditure – shows 'depletion-adjusted net saving' to be just above 0 for at least some of the historical period. Notably, this is the case for the early 1980s when the value of resource depletion was at its highest (relative to GNI), in the early 1990s, and more recently at the end of the historical series.

Figure 1: Change in Real Wealth in the UK (% of GNI)

Note: Per capita (wealth) measures as expressed as percentage of per capita GNI.

From 2001-2010 UK population growth was moderate at 0.5% per year on average. Yet relatively low rates of ANS suggest that it is useful also to look at the change in per capita wealth. This measures the extent to which total assets are shared over a changing population. This is reflected in an extra “wealth dilution” term which must be subtracted from the measure of net saving (Hamilton, 2003).5 Figure 1 includes two measures of the change in per capita wealth.

The first is the change in the tangible wealth per capita, where both produced assets and oil and gas resources are taken into account. This estimate goes back to 1987 when UK balance sheets for produced assets commence. The change in this tangible wealth (net of wealth dilution) stays positive until 2008 after which it is negative. The disparity between depletion adjusted saving and this measure is also notable after 2000.

The second measure is the change in tangible assets plus human capital in per capita terms. This corresponds roughly to ANS which, by including education investment, reflects how total assets are changing over time. This estimate begins only in 2001, the earliest year for

5 To be precise, the wealth dilution term is measured as the total wealth per capita times the population growth rate.

5 which ONS data (in Jones and Fender, 2011; Fender and Carver, 2013) on UK human capital are available. This wealth change was negative for most of that decade.6

2.3 Accounting for Government Resource Revenues

The picture about the sustainability of the economy, in the previous section, while mixed is far from encouraging. These highly aggregated insights take us only so far. Relating this asset accounting to the public finances is also important given that a critical pathway for boosting savings from resource depletion originates from appropriating these benefits through the tax regime. This tax regime, established in the Oil Taxation Act of 1975, has evolved substantially over subsequent years. Broadly speaking, these changes have had two objectives: (a) securing a larger take of the value of resource production (particularly when resource prices were high); and latterly, (b) a simplification of the layers of tax imposed on resource producers (HMRC, 2008; Kemp, 2011a,b).7

The initial regime consisted of three different tax streams starting with a ‘Royalty’ amounting to a charge of 12.5% of the gross value of oil and gas produced within a licensed area (less allowable deductions). Two further (field-based) charges applied to the net profits8 of producers: (PRT) and Corporation Tax (CT).9 Two subsequent charges (both established in 1981) were Supplementary Petroleum Duty (SPD) and a Gas Levy (on otherwise tax exempt gas). The SPD was short-lived and abolished after two calendar years while the Gas Levy was phased out after the late 1990s. The Royalty applies to fields licenced before 1982 only and was discontinued altogether by 2002. PRT now does not apply to fields developed after March 1993.

The tax rates for both PRT and CT have also undergone a number of revisions. In the past, PRT rates have been 45% (until 1978), 60% in 1978, 70% from 1979 before reaching a peak of 75% level in 1983. From 1993, this was reduced to 50% and this rate still applies currently for those fields subject to the PRT. While CT for resource producers has tracked the standard corporation tax, from 2002, this was complemented by a further supplementary charge introduced at 10% but increased from the beginning of 2006 to 20% and to 32% in 2011. This was accompanied by a pledge to reduce this rate if oil prices decline below a certain level (Frank and Webber, 2012; Pope and Roantree, 2014).

Figure 2 indicates the various government receipts (henceforth, resource revenues) that this regime has generated from 1975 to 2010. The key messages are twofold. First, there is the relative importance of PRT in the late 1970s and much of the 1980s (and the Royalty and SPD too but to a far lesser extent and temporarily in the case of the latter). Secondly, within the last ten years of the period considered, the relative importance of CT clearly increased substantially. Indeed, the CT becomes the principal instrument used to collect resource

6 To the extent that population change reflects net migration, the impact of this on human capital should be reflected in the stock estimates since they are based on current labour force data. 7 See, HM Treasury (2013) for a discussion of the possible extension of this tax regime to shale gas resources in the UK 8 Defined as the value of production net of allowable capital and operating expenditures. 9 Note that PRT is a being a deductible item in terms of calculating what CT is due. This CT is the same as for any economic sector in the UK but with one key difference. In the oil and gas production sector, much of this CT is ring-fenced; that is, chargeable on profits from resource depletion (rather than other areas of a producer’s operations) (HMRC, 2008).

6 revenues in the oil and gas sector. On average, these resource revenues in total10 contributed 2.5% of total government revenues over the period 1975 to 2010. Clearly this average is skewed by the tax proceeds accruing in the 1980s where these amounted to 5.7% of total revenues on average (and 8.4% on average from 1981 to 1985).

Figure 2: UK Resource Revenues to Exchequer, 1975-2010 (GBP million, 2010)

Source: adapted from data in HMRC (2013)

Figure 3 shows the extent to which these resource revenues have succeeded in capturing resource rents. We compare revenues with depletion values since, according to the theory outlined in Section 3.1 of this paper, this is the portion of total resource rents which must be invested in other assets if sustainability is to be achieved. What is interesting is that the two series track one another reasonably closely. On average, this amount captured through taxation corresponds to 80.6% of depletion values over the period 1975-2010 (which, in turn, corresponds to 65.2% of resource rents over the same period).

This is a striking result. While this tax regime has been critiqued on the grounds of being dominated by short-term macroeconomic policy and creating uncertainty for resource exploration and development (Kemp, 2011a, Nakhle, 2008, Staerck, 2002),11 it has been effective in capturing resource rents. Figure 3 further illustrates this for the case of the SPD widely criticized as a short-term expedient (e.g. Kemp, 2011a) but which according to the figure enabled a greater proportion of depletion value to accrue to HM Government rather than producers during its brief duration from 1981 to 1983.

10 We include here the Gas Levy. The fact that the tax was not production-based has led, for example, Scottish Government (2009) not to include its value under its assessment of oil and gas tax revenues. However, the charge is levied on resources not otherwise subject to tax presenting a case for including it as part of the benefits of depletion appropriated by central government. 11 More broadly, Boadway and Keen (2010) identify a stable and predictable regime as well as the taxation of rents on endowments as the key elements of a theoretically defensible regime. Daniel et al. (2010) provide a thorough overview of both the theory and practice of resource taxation.

7

Figure 3: Resource Revenues in Comparison to Depletion Values (GBP million, 2010)

Of course, what this asset accounting misses is whether these depletion values were optimal (which would require that marginal resource rents rise at the rate of interest – the Hotelling Rule). And while the average performance of the tax regime is important, so is its variability. Over the 1980s and 1990s, resource revenues exceeded depletion values on average: that is, the tax regime over-performed in respect of this criterion. By contrast, from 2000 onwards there was substantial divergence, with tax revenues falling short of depletion values.

3. Simulating a Sovereign Wealth Fund for the UK

3.1 Looking Back on 1975 to 2010

To understand the potential benefits of a SWF for the UK, we simulate a fund established in 1975 and track its size and payout up to 2010. This provides estimates of the sacrifices entailed by the fund (years when resource revenues exceeded fund payouts), the long-run potential payout from 2010 onwards, and the reduction in volatility of revenues into the Treasury when comparing fund payouts to current resource revenues.

The technique we use to simulate a UK SWF is based on the ‘bird-in-hand’ approach employed by the Norwegian Government Pension Fund. The fund operates on the basis of three principles: all petroleum revenues are paid into the fund, revenues are invested in financial assets, and payouts from the fund to the Treasury are at a fixed rate each year. The fixed payout rate we use is based upon aggregate long-run real rates of returns on assets in major economies from 1900 to 2010 (Credit Suisse 2011). We assume that the fund is fully invested in a global portfolio of 60% equities and 40% bonds, which yields a mean real rate of return of 3.9%.

The simulation of the fund is straightforward. The net value of the fund at the end of the preceding period is equal to the gross value minus the payout on the gross value. The gross value of the fund at the end of the current period is therefore equal to current resource revenues, plus the net value of the fund at the end of the preceding period times 1 plus the nominal rate of return on assets in the current period.

8

A complication in the simulation is that only long run averages are reported in Credit Suisse (2011), while the underlying (Dimson-Marsh-Staunton) data on real returns by country by year are proprietary. We are therefore forced to construct a synthetic annual nominal rate of return for the UK SWF as the sum of the long-run aggregate real return on assets, 3.9%, plus the rate of inflation in the UK economy as measured by the GDP deflator. The synthetic nominal returns can differ considerably from actual returns in any given year because the assumed constant real rate of return on assets introduces an element of smoothing in the calculation. Over the long run, however, the value of the smoothed fund should be close to that of the fund based on nominal returns.

Based on this smoothed accounting, the simulated value of the fund totals GBP 284 billion in 2010 (nominal). While this hypothetical fund value amounts to only 4% of total produced assets in the UK, it would represent a rough doubling of the value of assets in the central government balance sheet.

Figure 3: Resource Revenues and Returns from a (Hypothetical) SWF

Figure 3 plots the evolution of resource revenues and the value of the payout from the simulated fund from 1975 to 2010. Two key conclusions follow: the payouts from the SWF are less volatile than annual resource revenues, and payouts exceed resource revenues from 1988 onward (with two minor exceptions). However, the figure also shows that resource revenues were much larger than the payout from the fund from 1979 to 1986, the period following the second oil crisis. While a slow buildup of payouts is a natural property of a ‘bird-in-hand’ fund, this result indicates the considerable short-run sacrifices that government would have had to make in implementing the fund. The compensation for this sacrifice would be a fund that continues to make annual payouts of tens of billions of pounds to the Treasury long after the North Sea petroleum deposits have ceased to be in production. We turn to this question of sacrifices in Section 4, where we carry out an ex post cost-benefit analysis of the simulated fund.

9

The low volatility of fund payouts seen in Figure 3 is to some extent an artefact of the smoothing introduced by our synthetic calculation of nominal returns. In Annex 2 we simulate a UK SWF that invests all of its revenues in US stocks and bonds, building upon historical data on nominal returns on US financial assets (Damodaran, 2014). This fund is compared with a SWF that also invests in US financial assets but uses a synthetic nominal return as constructed for the SWF underlying Figure 3. The fund based on observed nominal returns has a higher value in 2010 and exhibits more volatility than the smoothed fund simulated using synthetic nominal returns. From 1985 to 2010 the standard deviation of year to year changes in flows equals 35% for resource revenues, 13% for the fund simulated using nominal rates of return, and nearly 6% for the fund using synthetic estimates of nominal returns.

The simulation in Annex 2 based upon historical nominal returns shows that the resource fund buffers revenues and thereby reduces the volatility of flows to the Treasury. Yet there is a partially offsetting source of volatility in the form of year to year variation in the nominal returns on investment in the portfolio of the SWF. The Annex also indicates this broad conclusion holds for a fund based on a global portfolio of financial assets, but the data available are limited.

3.2 Looking Forward

The preceding historical simulation of a SWF has intrinsic interest. But our framework has implications for the future as well. OBR (2013) provides forecasts of predicted revenues from future oil and gas production up to around 2040. These data – while contingent on forecasts12 – indicate that the stream of future resource revenues is likely to be declining in real terms. There is an obvious implication here. A decision to start a fund ‘now’ – based on conventional oil and gas resources – will be limited in terms of the size of the returns that it generates. This begs a further question. Given the on-going debate about unconventional gas and oil resources, what might be the revenue implications of this possible windfall?

These unconventional resources refer most notably to natural gas and, to a lesser extent, oil resources trapped in shale beds – formed of sedimentary rocks. These resources can be freed by (or ‘fracking‘) entailing injection of fluids, including water, at high pressure into rocks (Royal Society/ Royal Academy of Engineers, 2012; DECC, 2013a). Significant attention has centred on shale gas production in the US using this technology, its transformative effect on the gas market, as well as the institutional reasons for this boom (see, for example: Rogers, 2011; Wang and Krupnick, 2013). Debate has also focused on the range of negative externalities that this extraction technology could give rise to (see, for example, Krupnick et al. 2013; Royal Society/ Royal Academy of Engineers, 2012; Mason et al. 2015).

Within the UK, two regions have been identified as having considerable potential (EIA, 2013, BGS/ DECC, (2013a, 2013b): (a) the North UK Shale Region: geological basins and troughs across northern and southern ; and, (b) the South UK Shale Region: basins in Southern England and offshore into the English Channel. In what follows, we construct an asset account based on recent tentative estimates of the extent

12 These are estimates of resource revenues (forecast to be raised from the North Sea oil and gas fiscal regime) predicted by the Office for Budgetary Responsibility (OBR). OBR published a range for these values (for high/ low resource prices and high/ low production). The data used here (currently) are the mid-range forecasts that the OBR publishes. The OBR also publishes low and high predictions based on assumptions about (respectively) less steep and steeper price paths.

10 of shale gas and oil in the UK. We do so, however, in the acknowledgement that there is considerable uncertainty about the extent of these resources as well as their technical and economic recoverability. To quote POST (2013, p1), an estimate of “… UK reserves could be anywhere from zero to substantial.”

Table 2 summarises a handful of studies that assess availability. These refer to gas-in-place (GIP) or oil-in-place (OIP), the quantities reckoned to be physically contained in source rock (EIA, 2013). DECC (2010) estimates that shale gas reserves potential could be about 135 mtoe. However, subsequent studies by US EIA (2013)13 and DECC (2013a, 2013b, 2014) have been more optimistic.

The substantial variation across studies partly reflects differences in scope and methodology as well as evolving knowledge about novel geological areas. Notably, the BGS/ DECC studies provide a more detailed assessment of particular basins including an assessment of the extent in place with different probability levels. The US EIA study is arguably somewhat more conservative in some of its assumptions. There is greater consistency, however, between these BGS/ DECC and US EIA estimates if the latter can be interpreted as 90% probability estimates of potential resources.

None of these estimates in Table 2 refer to the ultimate recoverability of resources. US EIA (2013) also assesses geological and technical factors influencing the likelihood of production. This results in estimates for the UK of recoverable shale gas of 728 mtoe and for shale oil of 94 mtoe.14 Assuming, very optimistically, that all of these resources were economically recoverable over the longer-term, this would have the effect of doubling current UK reserves of oil and gas.

Table 2: Estimates of Potential Shale Resources (mtoe)

Publication Area of assessment Shale Gas Shale Oil Total DECC Whole of UK 135 135 (2010) EIA (2013) Whole of UK 17,444 7,366 24,810 Midland Valley, 1,235 (p90) 436 (p90) 1671 (p90) Scotland 2,008 (p50) 818 (p50) 2,826 (p50) 3,365 (p10) 1,528 (p10) 4,893 (p90) BGS/ DECC Bowland, N. England 20,550 (p10) 20,550 (p90) (2013a,b, 33,225 (p50) 33,225 (p50) 2014) 57,025 (p90) 57,025 (p10) Weald Basin, S. 293 (p90) 293 (p90) England 591 (p50) 591 (p50) 1,143 (p10) 1,143 (p10) Notes: p(90) refers to 90% probability of estimated resources being in place; p(50) refers to 50% probability of estimated resources being in place; p(10) refers 10% probability of estimated resources being in place;

To construct a preliminary asset account for shale gas and oil resources, we use as our starting point the data for resources-in-place from BGS/ DECC (2013a,b, 2014). Regarding recoverability, POST (2013) relates the US experience that reserves have tended to

13 This is an increase on an earlier initial study described in US EIA (2011). 14 BGS/ DECC (2013a,b, 2014), however, baulks at estimating recovery factors such as this on the basis of current uncertainty.

11 correspond to 8% to 20% of this measure of resource extent. This seems a generous assumption given the findings of US EIA (2013) which stresses the likely geological complexity of the UK compared to the US experience. Hence, we assume – in broad line with EIA (2013) – recoverability of 4% (but also test for sensitivity to more and less conservative assumptions). It is important to note this further (implicitly) assumes technically recoverability equates to economic recoverability (e.g. proven plus possible reserves). Moreover, we are unable here to consider the environmental and regulatory hurdles that will also determine actual recoverability (KPMG, 2011) and, therefore, the value of these resources as economic assets.

For accounting purposes, further assumptions are needed on a range of parameters. This includes resource prices, the timing and magnitude of depletion as well as the proportion of the value of this production appropriated by Government through a future fiscal regime. Table A3.1 in Annex 3 provides details of these assumed values and lower and upper bounds assumed to test sensitivity. We note here though significant uncertainties do exist regarding, for example, development and production costs in the UK and Europe generally (see Rogers, 2011; Stevens, 2013 although some estimates of possible costs are presented in IEA, 2012, 2013).

Table 3 illustrates some initial assessments of the implied magnitudes of a simulated fund for our base-case. What is clear is that this fund could match our estimate for conventional oil and gas over 1975-2010 only if relatively high levels of both resource availability and recovery rates can be assumed. Yet the suggestion in the BGS/ DECC (2013, 2014a,b) studies as well as US EIA (2013) is that resource availability is far more likely to correspond to the medium or perhaps even the lower bound of the estimates that we use. For this lower bound amount, a recovery rate of about 4% could produce a fund roughly equivalent in size to that achieved by investing resource revenues from conventional oil and gas over the same period. A further Table in Annex 3 looks at the sensitivity of these findings to alternative assumptions about other important parameters.

Table 3: Hypothetical values of a SWF for UK Shale Resources (2010, GBP millions)

Estimated Resources Assumed recovery rate 4 per cent 2 per cent 6 per cent Low 62,679 31,339 94,018 Medium 100,286 50,143 150,429 High 175,500 87,850 263,250 Notes: See Table A3.1 in Annex 3 for details of assumed values used to estimate these magnitudes

Finally, Figure 4 places this in the context of our earlier analysis in Section 3.1 of revenues and (hypothetical) fund returns. The series of unbroken lines repeat those earlier findings (i.e. Figure 3) whereas the series of broken line continue this story from 2011 to 2040. Resource revenues from conventional oil and gas (blue line) are forecast to decline over this period, from GBP 5 to 6 billion annually over the period 2011-2020 to around GBP 2 billion annually from 2031-2040). If a fund for conventional oil and gas were established from 2015, then only by the end of the period would its potential returns exceed the forecast revenues.

12

Figure 4: Resource Revenues and Returns to 2040

Source: authors’ calculations

Of course, all such assessments of future resource values are contingent on oil prices. Annex Table A1.1 shows the effect of the large oil price drop in 1986 on resource asset values. The 2014/2015 fall in oil prices is of a similar magnitude. The current debate surrounding the externalities that could result from exploration and exploitation of shale gas (Royal Society/ Royal Academy of Engineering, 2012, Mason et al. 2015) is also relevant here, since this could reduce the expected social value of shale-based sub-soil assets.15

This point notwithstanding, if shale oil and gas revenues were included in such a fund, then depending on the size of the resources (low, medium or high corresponding to Table 3) clearly this will boost fund payouts significantly (the higher broken black line in Figure 4). Exactly how much will depend on the timing of significant shale resource production. The (higher) broken red lines illustrate the missed opportunity of not starting a fund using resource revenues in 1975. While conventional oil and gas add a further one-third to this fund by 2040 (about GBP 90 billion, GBP 2010), shale resources add between 22% and 62% (with a best guess of 35%) with a corresponding increase in (hypothetical) returns by 2040.

4. Discussion: Cost and Benefits of Establishing a SWF

Given the current prevalence of SWFs in a growing number of resource abundant countries, it is worth asking why the UK chose not to establish a fund. Kemp (2011a,b) provides a thorough review of the relevant official historical documents (including British Cabinet minutes and papers) providing formal records of this decision, crucially in the late 1970s. His account indicates a wide ranging debate about: the appropriate scale of a fund (e.g. would it be a repository for all resource revenues or just some smaller proportion); the expenditure it could facilitate (i.e. discrete investment projects or reducing external debt burdens) and

15 However, Mason et al. (2015) also cite beneficial externalities on, for example, (national) and displacement of the use of for energy production.

13 whether this hypothecation of tax revenues would misallocate resources by possibly divorcing these spending decisions from normal fiscal processes.

Importantly, Kemp identifies the apparent absence in explicit debate – up to the political decision in 1979 not to establish a fund – of intergenerational equity, as a guiding principle for managing this UK resource windfall. Such discussion came more to the fore, however, when in the early- to mid-1980s concerns resurfaced about the use of resource revenues (perhaps in part as a result of the by-then apparent magnitudes of resource revenues). In particular, a series of contributions by the (BoE 1980, 1982 and, later, 1986) explicitly recognises that these revenues were generated by a ‘wasting asset’ and as such “… would require investment of sufficient of the revenues to main the real value of the capital.” (BoE, 1982, p56).16

Common to those later papers was discussion of principles and, broadly speaking, an investment strategy rather than a more detailed plan based on revisiting the idea of establishing a fund. Moreover, in the 1970s, Kemp (2011a) makes clear that was discussed was a very particular type of fund, construed as an investment account (using the typology in van der Ploeg, 2014, discussed earlier) with which to fund identified ‘projects’ in the same fiscal year as resource revenues were paid in. So what was debated then was not a SWF in the sense commonly understood now (or, for that matter, as would have been observable in examples from Alaska and Alberta in the late 1970s).

Stewart (2013) further cites the difficult economic context, particularly in the early 1980s, as a practical obstacle to a positive decision to establish a fund.17 Kemp (2011a) notes a significant element of the economic strategy of the in-coming Conservative administration in 1979 was to use resource revenues to support its macroeconomic policy and reduce public borrowing. HM Government Budgets from 1979 reduced both basic and higher rates of income tax, while the tax rate on corporations was considerably reduced from 1984. Resource tax rates meanwhile rose, with the PRT rate levied on oil and gas was increasing in 1979, 1980 and 1982. As a result, resource revenues increased from 3.5% of central government tax receipts in 1979 to peak at 10.1% in 1984.

The fiscal consequences of instead investing these resource revenues in a SWF in the early 1980s presumably would have been large. To illustrate this, Figure 5 focuses on the first decade of oil production. Both government consumption and total expenditure grew strongly from 1977 to 1985. There was a flattening of non-resource revenue from 1975 to 1979, and it grew more slowly than total and consumption expenditure afterwards. Because money is fungible there is no unambiguous way to determine how resource revenues affected the main fiscal aggregates historically. One message, however, from the figure is that it appears possible that resources revenues contributed significantly to filling the gap between (non- resource) revenue and expenditure.18

16 Odling-Smee and Riley (1985) examines this same issue from the perspective of the UK Treasury and the role of resource revenues in improving public finances. 17 There was some debate about whether increases in oil and gas production was itself responsible for some of these problems through, for example, appreciation in the exchange rate and decline of the manufacturing sector (see, for example, Atkinson et al. 1982). Bean (1987), however, concludes that while some impact cannot be ruled out, a more significant factor appears to have been macroeconomic policy during this period. 18 Of course, some portion of what officially comprises government consumption may actually have an investment component, particularly expenditure on education. Data published in ONS (2014) indicate that from 1979 to 1985 education expenditures increased by 0.3% in real terms over this 6 year period. This is

14

Figure 5: Non-resource Tax Revenues and Government Expenditure from 1975 to 1985

Source: ONS (2014)

To explore the likely sacrifice from the establishment of a sovereign wealth fund in 1975, we choose not to simulate a counterfactual path for the fiscal revenues and expenditures that could result from. This would be essentially arbitrary. The alternative we examine is to carry out an ex post cost-benefit analysis of the SWF as a public investment. Resource revenues transferred to the fund become costs from the Treasury viewpoint, while fund payouts to the Treasury are benefits. For simplicity we assume that the petroleum resource is depleted by 2010. Costs of investing in the SWF cease at this point. The fund, however, is assumed to continue paying out an amount equal to its 2010 value (the real return on the portfolio) in perpetuity. Table 4 shows the present value of costs and benefits of investing in the SWF, normalized per capita, for different time horizons and discount rate assumptions.

To isolate the effects of the oil price bubble and other economic circumstances in the early 1980s, we simulate costs and benefits for two assumptions about the year that investment in the fund commenced, 1975 and 1990. Starting in 1975 yields a larger present value of benefits from the fund, but it also yields a high present value of costs because these costs (payments into the fund) are front-end loaded. This front-end loading is much diminished for the fund simulated to commence in 1990.

The first discount rate assumed, fixed 3.5%, is equal to the Green Book 2003 social discount rate for projects where costs and benefits span 30 years or less. The second discounting scenario uses a discount rate of 3.5% that declines beyond 30 years. This is the Green Book 2003 social discount rate assumption for assessing policies affecting the long term19 – which is precisely what a SWF is designed to do.

considerably lower than the average annual increase (1.8%) for 1975-2010 (see also Crawford et al. 2009). By contrast, non-education government consumption increased by 3.4% over 1979-1985. 19 The schedule of the declining discount rate is 3.5% for the first 30 years, 3.0% for the next 45, 2.5% for the next 50, 2.0% for the next 75, 1.5% for the next 100, and 1.0% beyond this point.

15

Table 4. Costs and Benefits of Establishing a SWF, 2010 GBP / capita

Fund established 1975 Fund established 1990 Total resource Total resource revenue SWF returns revenue SWF returns (cost) (benefit) (cost) (benefit) Fixed 3.5% discount rate

Present value 2,897 3,182 1,251 1,394 Levelized costs and benefits 145 159 88 98 Ratio of benefits to costs 1.10 1.11

Declining 3.5% discount rate

Present value 3,000 5,068 1,251 2,510 Levelized costs and benefits 143 240 88 176 Ratio of benefits to costs 1.69 2.00 Source: Authors’ calculation. The discount rates are derived from Green Book 2003. Levelized costs and benefits are calculated over 1975-2010 or 1990-2010 as appropriate.

As shown in Table 4, the present value of benefits from the SWF exceeds costs by 10% to 69% for the fund starting in 1975; for the fund starting in 1990 the corresponding figures are 11% and 100%. In terms of levelized net annual benefits, these vary from GBP 14 to 10 per capita for the fixed discount rate, and GBP 97 to 88 for the declining discount rate – in each case the 1990 scenario yields the lower net benefit figures.

The fixed discount rate results are of course sensitive to the choice of discount rate, with a discount rate of 3.92% (the assumed constant real rate of return of the SWF) yielding 0 net benefits for either start year. This is an artifact of the synthetic nominal SWF return that we simulate.

This ex post analysis suggests that if a SWF had been established per Green Book 2003 standards, the net benefits per capita would be positive and moderately large for the assumption of declining discount rates. This assumes, of course, 20/20 hindsight and requires the use of a discounting standard that did not exist in 1975 or 1990.

5. Conclusions

We have simulated a potential fund based on investing resource revenues. Specifically, had the UK established such a fund along the lines of the Norwegian example, starting in 1975, its value would amount to about GBP 284 billion in 2010. We show that this would have provided a number of further benefits. First, there would be much lower volatility of payouts from the fund compared with the volatility of resource revenues; this would have consequences for fiscal stability. Second, owing to the early 1980’s bubble in oil prices, the fund would have fairly rapidly produced annual income greater than annual resource

16 revenues.20 Lastly, the UK government would today enjoy a rough doubling of the public sector balance sheet, and the balance sheet would be more diversified.

Such benefits are not without sacrifice of course. Resource revenues would flow into the SWF, with only the returns on the fund being paid into general government revenues. On the presumption that it makes little sense to pay into a SWF and simultaneously increase public debt,21 then in the absence of more borrowing, non-oil fiscal revenues and so public expenditures would have to adjust to preserve the gross operating balance of central government after the SWF is established. While we have not sought to evaluate an arbitrary counterfactual to the historical government policy, we do show that from a cost-benefit perspective, the net benefits per capita would be positive and reasonably large.

Of course, this cost-benefit case relies on a number of assumptions including SWF returns being enjoyed in perpetuity. This potential for sustained payouts is clearly a virtue. Indeed, from this standpoint, the UK decision in 1979 (and implicitly subsequently) against establishment might be viewed as a failure of a basic (but early) test of government commitment to sustainability. Having said that, the need for a formal fund has been questioned more recently by Hughes (2014) in large, diverse economies where resource rents are a relatively small percentage of activity; e.g. the UK over the past 40 years or so. Reinvesting these rents is important, he continues, but the degree of reinvestment can be assessed by using an indicator such as depletion-adjusted saving. Our finding, however, is that depletion-adjusted saving has been relatively low in the UK since 1975, pointing to insufficient investment of resource revenues.

Had it established a fund in 1975 as we have simulated here, the UK would have been in the experimental vanguard. What is perhaps surprising is that the policy debate about establishing a fund appears not to have been seriously revisited until recently. The current debate appears to hinge on the use of revenues from shale-based depletion only. 22,23 Our analysis of shale oil and gas shows that a fund of similar size is only likely to be realized for relatively optimistic assessments of shale gas and oil resource availability and high recovery rates. While more conservative assumptions could result in a fund that is still considerable in magnitude, these findings emphasise the size of the missed opportunity in the past. And paradoxically, while we show that – in the past – resource revenues have tracked depletion values reasonably closely, there is more recent evidence of divergence between these series.

Doubts about the size of future resource revenues do not negate the case for a resource fund. Resource prices are volatile and large increases have been experienced in the early 1970s and 80s, as well as the mid-2000s. Having a fund in place would position the UK, and any country with similar or larger resources, to benefit from any such windfall. And, as we have shown, comprehensive resource asset accounts can be a complementary tool to support the establishment of a fund, assess the effectiveness of resource taxation, and track progress toward sustainability.

20 This bubble, of course, could not have been foreseen by decision-makers in 1975. 21 This assumes that rates of return on international investments are not significantly higher than domestic borrowing costs. 22 See, for example: http://www.bbc.com/news/uk-england-29968603 (accessed 04/08/2015). 23 But see Hughes (2014) for a discussion in the context of .

17

References

Asheim, G.B. and Weitzman, M.L. (2001) “Does NNP Growth Indicate Welfare Improvement”, Economics Letters, 73: 233-239.

Atkinson, F.J. Brooks, S.J. and Hall, S.G.F. (1982) “The Economic Effects of North Sea Oil”, National Institute Economic Review, 104: 38-44.

Bank of England (1980) “The North Sea and the Economic: Some Longer- Term Perspectives and Implications”, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Dec. (1980): 449- 454.

Bank of England (1982) “North Sea Oil and Gas – Costs and Benefits”, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, March (1982): 56-73.

Bank of England (1986) “North Sea Oil and Gas”, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Dec. (1986): 510-518.

Bean, C. (1987) “The Impact of North Sea Oil”, in Dornbusch, R. and Layard, R. (eds.) The Performance of the British Economy, Clarendon Press, Oxford.

BGS (British Geological Survey)/ DECC (Department of Energy and Climate Change) (2013a) The Carboniferous Bowland Shale Gas Study: Geology and Resource Estimation, DECC, London.

BGS (British Geological Survey)/ DECC (Department of Energy and Climate Change) (2013b) The Jurassic of the Weald Basin: Geology and Shale Oil and Shale Gas Resource Estimation, DECC, London.

BGS (British Geological Survey)/ DECC (Department of Energy and Climate Change) (2014) The Carboniferous Shale of the Midland Valley of Scotland: Geology and Resource Estimation, DECC, London.

Boadway, R. and Keen, D.P. (2010) “Theoretical Perspectives on Resource Tax Design”, in Daniel, P. Keen, M. and McPherson, C. (eds.) The Taxation of Petroleum and Minerals: Principles, Problems and Practice, Routledge, London.

Clark, G.L. Dixon, A.D. and Monk, A.H.B. (2013) Sovereign Wealth Funds: Legitimacy, Governance and Global Power, Princeton University Press, New Jersey.

Crawford, R. Emmerson, C. and Tetlow, G. (2012) A Survey of UK Public Spending, IFS Briefing Note BN43, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London.

Credit Suisse (2011) Global Investment Returns Yearbook 2011, Credit Suisse Research Institute, Zurich.

Damodoran, A. (2014) http://www.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/pc/datasets/histretSP.xls, accessed Dec. 12, 2014.

18

Dasgupta, P. and Mäler, K.-G. (2000) “Net National Produce, Wealth and Social Welfare”, Environment and Development Economics, 5(1): 69-93.

DECC (Department of Energy and Climate Change) (2013a) About Shale Gas and Hydraulic Fracturing (Fracking), DECC, London.

DECC (Department of Energy and Climate Change) (2013b) Resources vs. Reserves: What Do Estimates of Shale Gas Mean?, DECC, London.

DECC (Department of Energy and Climate Change) (2011) The Unconventional Hydrocarbon Resources of Britain’s Onshore Basins - Shale Gas, DECC, London.

Devereux, M.P. and Morris, C. (1983) North Sea Oil Taxation: The Development of the North Sea Tax System, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London.

Dimson, E. Marsh, P.R. and Staunton, M. (2002) Triumph of the Optimists: 101 Years of Global Investment Returns, Princeton University Press, New York.

Fender, V. and Carver, J. (2013) “Human Capital Estimates, 2013”, Office for National Statistics, London.

Frank, C. and Webber, R. (2012) “UK: Recent Developments in the Taxation of Oil and Gas Activities in the UK”, International Tax Review, July 9th 2012.

Hamilton, K. (2014) “Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental and Economic Accounting”, GRI Working Paper 154, Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment, London School of Economics, London.

Hamilton, K. and Atkinson, G. (2013) “Resource Discoveries, Learning, and National Income Accounting”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 6505, World Bank, Washington DC.

Hamilton, K. and Hartwick, J.M. (2014) “Wealth and Sustainability”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 30(1): 170-187.

Hamilton, K. and Ley, E. (2013) “Sustainable Fiscal Policy for Mineral Based Economies”, in Amadou, S. Rabah, A. and Gylfason, B. (eds.) Beyond the Curse: Policies to Harness the Power of Natural Resources, International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.

Hartwick, J.M. (1977) “Intergenerational Equity and the Investment of Rents from Exhaustible Resources”, American Economic Review, 67: 972-74.

Harvie, C. (1994) Fool’s Gold: The Story of North Sea Oil, Penguin, London.

Hassler, J. Krusell, P. Shifa, A. Spiro, D. (2015) “Sovereign Wealth Funds and Spending Constraints in Resource Rich Developing Countries – The Case of Uganda”, Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University.

Hawksworth, P. (2008) Dude, Where’s My Oil Money Gone, PriceWaterhouseCoopers, London.

19

HMRC (Her Majesty’s Revenue and Customs) (2013) Statistics of Government Revenues from UK Oil and Gas Production, HMRC, London.

HMRC (Her Majesty’s Revenue and Customs) (2008) A Guide to UK and UK Continental Shelf: Oil and Gas Taxation, HMRC, London.

HM Treasury (2013) Harnessing the Potential of the UK’s Natural Resources: A Fiscal Regime for Shale Gas, Open Consultation, HM Treasury, London.

Hughes, G. (2014) “The Energy Sector in Scotland’s Future”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 30(2): 374-391.

Humphreys, M. and Sandbu, M.E. (2007) “The Political Economy of Natural Resource Funds”, in Humphreys, M. Sachs, J.D. and Stiglitz, J.E. (eds.) Escaping the Resource Curse, Columbia University Press, New York.

IEA (International Energy Agency) (2013) Resources to Reserves 2013, OECD/ IEA, Paris.

IEA (International Energy Agency) (2012) Golden Rules for a Golden Age of Gas – World Energy Outlook Special Report on Unconventional Gas, OECD/ IEA, Paris.

IFS (Institute of Fiscal Studies (2012) A Survey of the UK Tax System, Institute of Fiscal Studies, London.

Jones, R. and Fender, V. (2011) “Human Capital Estimates, 2010”, Office for National Statistics, London.

Khan, J. Greene, P. and Wei Hoo, K. (2013) Monetary Valuation of UK Continental Shelf Oil & Gas Reserves, Office for National Statistics, London.

Kemp, A. (2011a) The Official History of North Sea Oil and Gas: Volume I – The Growing Dominance of the State, (Government Official History Series), Routledge, London.

Kemp, A. (2011b) The Official History of North Sea Oil and Gas: Volume II – Moderating the State's Role (Government Official History Series), Routledge, London.

KPMG (2011) Shale Gas – A Global Perspective, KPMG Global , KPMG International,

Krupnick, A.J. (2013) “Managing the Risks of Shale Gas: Key Findings and Further Research”, Resources for the Future, Washington DC.

Krupnick, A.J. Gordon, H. and Olmstead, S. (2013) Pathways to Dialogue: What the Experts Say about the Environmental Risks of Shale Gas Development, RFF Report, Resources for the Future, Washington DC.

Mason, C.F. Muehlenbachs, L.A. and Olmstead, S.M. (2015) “The Economics of Shale Gas Development”, RFF Discussion Paper 14-42 (Revised version), Resources for the Future, Washington DC.

20

Nakhle, C. (2010) “Petroleum Fiscal Regimes: Evolution and Challenges”, in Daniel, P. Keen, M. and McPherson, C. (eds.) The Taxation of Petroleum and Minerals: Principles, Problems and Practice, Routledge, London.

Nakhle, C. (2008) Petroleum Taxation, Routledge, Abingdon.

OBR (Office for Budgetary Responsibility) (2014) Fiscal Sustainability Report, OBR, London.

Obst, C. and Vardon, M. (2014) “Recording Environmental Assets in the National Accounts”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 30(1): 126-144.

Odling-Smee, J. and Riley, C. (1985) “Approaches to the PSBR”, National Institute Economic Review, August 1985.

ONS (Office for National Statistics) (2014) UK Environmental Accounts 2014, ONS, London.

ONS (Office for National Statistics) (2013) UK National Accounts (The Blue Book), ONS, London.

Ossowski, R. Villafuerte, M. Medas, P. and Thomas, T. (2008) The Role of Fiscal Institutions in Managing the Oil Revenue Boom, International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.

Pearce, D.W. and Atkinson, G. (1993) “Capital Theory and the Measurement of Sustainable Development: An Indicator of ‘Weak’ Sustainability”, Ecological Economics, 8(2): 103-108.

Pope, T. and Roantree, B. (2014) A Survey of the UK Tax System, IFS Briefing Note BN09, IFS, London.

PwC (Price Waterhouse Cooper) (2012) The Total Tax Contribution of the UK Oil & Gas Industry, Report Prepared for Oil and Gas UK, PwC, London.

Rogers, H. (2011) “Shale Gas – The Unfolding Story”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 27(1): 117-143.

Royal Society/ Royal Academy of Engineering (2012) Shale Gas Extraction in the UK: A Review of Hydraulic Fracturing, Royal Society/ Royal Academy of Engineering, London.

Scottish Government (2009) An Oil Fund for Scotland: Taking Forward Our National Conversation, The Scottish Government, Edinburgh.

Staerck, G. (2002) The Development of North Sea Oil and Gas, ICBH Expert Witness Seminar, Institute of Contemporary British History, University of London, London.

Stevens, P. (2013) “Shale Gas in the United Kingdom”, Chatham House, London.

Stewart, G. (2013) Bang! A History of Britain in the 1980s, Atlantic Books, London.

21

UN (United Nations) (2013) System of Environmental-Economic Accounts: Central Framework, United Nations, New York.

US EIA (United States Energy Information Administration) (2013) Technically Recoverable Shale Oil and Shale Gas Resources: An Assessment of 137 Shale Formations in 41 Countries Outside the United States, US Department of Energy, Washington DC.

US EIA (United States Energy Information Administration) (2011)

Van der Ploeg, R. (2014) “Guidelines for Exploiting Natural Resource Wealth”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 30(1): 145-169.

Wang, Z. and Krupnick, A.J. (2013) “A Retrospective Review of Shale Gas Development in the United States: What Led to the Boom?”, RFF Discussion Paper 13-12, Resources for the Future, Washington DC.

22

Annex 1

Table A1.1: Monetary Asset Account for UK Oil and Gas, 1975-2010 (2010, million GBP unless otherwise indicated)

Asset Production Resource Depletion value (% value value rent of resource rent) 1975 0 1,540 0 0 1976 0 4,252 0 0 1977 74,029 10,476 4,340 2,961 (68.2%) 1978 80,766 12,539 4,735 3,231 (68.2%) 1979 384,820 31,541 22,559 15,393 (68.2%) 1980 336,844 29,477 19,747 13,474 (68.2%) 1981 366,939 32,923 22,078 15,289 (69.3%) 1982 393,723 38,692 26,766 19,686 (73.5%) 1983 394,298 42,845 30,113 23,194 (77.0%) 1984 410,378 49,858 36,308 29,313 (80.7%) 1985 342,530 47,055 32,122 26,348 (82.0%) 1986 85,913 23,335 8,590 7,159 (83.3%) 1987 95,437 23,846 9,542 7,953 (83.3%) 1988 36,736 17,333 3,673 3,061 (83.3%) 1989 33,479 16,811 3,140 2,575 (82.0%) 1990 40,480 18,109 3,796 3,114 (82.0%) 1991 16,341 16,363 1,446 1,167 (80.7%) 1992 6,021 15,848 505 401 (79.5%) 1993 17,171 17,614 1,519 1,227 (80.7%) 1994 31,732 19,466 3,173 2,644 (83.3%) 1995 41,431 20,454 4,447 3,766 (84.7%) 1996 72,129 24,240 8,380 7,213 (86.1%) 1997 54,871 21,780 5,890 4,988 (84.7%) 1998 12,053 17,142 1,400 1,205 (86.1%) 1999 34,100 20,320 4,793 4,262 (88.9%) 2000 108,503 30,318 15,251 13,563 (88.9%) 2001 99,294 28,400 13,956 12,412 (88.9%) 2002 93,276 27,413 13,111 11,660 (88.9%) 2003 82,240 25,296 11,559 10,280 (88.9%) 2004 95,237 25,562 12,095 10,582 (87.5%) 2005 147,638 30,736 17,152 14,764 (86.1%) 2006 172,820 34,029 20,077 17,282 (86.1%) 2007 145,187 31,304 16,867 14,519 (86.1%) 2008 224,469 39,534 24,093 20,406 (84.7%) 2009 136,137 30,070 14,612 12,376 (84.7%) 2010 181,022 33,504 18,099 15,085 (83.3%)

23

Annex 2

In this annex we simulate a SWF for the UK that invests only in US financial assets, yielding results that are in some respects more realistic than those calculated in the main body of the paper. The analysis builds upon historical data on nominal returns on US financial assets going back to 1928 (reported in Damodaran 2014), as well as historical inflation data from the US Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The simulations of the US asset fund employ two alternative assumptions. The first assumption is that returns on the resource fund are calculated at historical nominal rates for the US. Under the second assumption, a synthetic nominal return is calculated as the sum of the inflation rate and the long run real rate of return on US financial assets (this is the approach used in the main body of the paper). UK resource revenues are converted to US dollars at annual average exchange rates.

The basic variables for the simulation are gross fund value 퐴퐺(푡), net fund value 퐴푁(푡), long-run real rate of return on financial assets 푟푟 (constant), nominal rate of return 푟푛(푡), annual inflation 푖(푡) and resource revenues 푅(푡). For fund payout 푟푟 ∗ 퐴퐺(푡 − 1) the basic accounting is as follows:

퐴푁(푡 − 1) = 퐴퐺(푡 − 1) ∗ (1 − 푟푟)

퐴퐺(푡) = 푅(푡) + 퐴푁(푡 − 1) ∗ (1 + 푟푛(푡))

Given an initial endowment of the fund 퐴퐺(0), these two equations permit simulation of the growth of the fund and the payouts from the fund as resource revenues are captured. In the ‘unsmoothed’ simulation nominal returns 푟푛(푡) are measured at historical values; in the ‘smoothed’ simulation nominal returns are calculated as 푟푛(푡) = 푖(푡) + 푟푟. According to data from Damadoran (2014), a fund invested 60% in the S&P 500 and 40% in 10 year bonds would have a long-run (1928-2013) real rate of return 푟푟 of 4.6%.

Figure A2.1 UK SWF Invested in US Financial Assets, Smoothed and Unsmoothed, $mn (nominal), 1975-2010

Source: authors’ calculations

24

Figure A2.1 plots resource revenues and payouts from the unsmoothed and smoothed funds in nominal dollars from 1975 to 2010. As expected, the curves for resource revenues and the smoothed fund bear a family resemblance to the equivalent curves in Figure 3, with the key difference being nominal dollars vs. constant 2010 GBP. By 2010 the unsmoothed fund using historical nominal returns is nearly 50% larger than the smoothed fund (reflecting high returns on financial assets in the US during the 1980s and 1990s), and its payouts are much more volatile.

Table A2.1: Standard Deviation of Year on Year Changes in Revenues and Fund Payouts

US1 UK2 World3 1985-2010 1985-2010 1997-2010 Resource revenues 35.2% 36.5% 35.8% Unsmoothed payouts 13.1% 17.3% 16.4% Smoothed payouts 5.8% 5.1% 10.3% Source: authors’ calculations Notes – Based on data on returns in: 1 Damadoran (2014); 2 Barclays; (2013); 3 Dimson et al. (2002)

By measuring year-on-year changes in revenues and the two measures of fund returns, we calculate the volatility of these changes as seen in Table A2.1. The first column of the table shows that even unsmoothed payouts, based on historical nominal returns on financial assets, reduce the volatility of flows into the Treasury considerably compared to the alternative of simply paying the proceeds of resource taxation into general revenues.

By way of comparison, the second column looks at the volatility of a fund based on the return on UK equities over the same period. The final column measures the volatility of a global portfolio over 1997-2010 (based on data on global returns in Dimson et al. 2002). The rankings of the different measures of the volatility of revenues and fund payouts are the same across the three columns, while the UK and World portfolios exhibit higher levels of volatility compared to the US.

25

Annex 3

Table A3.1 below describes the data used to calculate the size of a fund based on shale (gas and oil) resources. The initial parameter values refer to a broad measure of prospective shale oil and gas (Section 4). These ‘resources-in-place’ might be “low”, “medium” or “high” in extent. This, in turn, is based approximately on the totals implied by BGS/ DECC (2013a,b, 2014) in its assessments across Scotland (Midland Valley), North England (Bowland) and South England (Weald Basin) (see Table 2). Immediately below in Table A3.1 is an assumption about what percentage of these (low, medium or high levels of) resources in place are actually recoverable. For example, a recovery rate of 4% on the medium estimate of ‘resources-in-place’ implies ‘reserves’ of about 1,440 mtoe; a recovery rate of 6% on the high estimate of resources in place implies reserves of about 3,780 mtoe, and so on.

The remaining values in the Table reflect choices about parameters needed to transform this assumed estimate of physical reserves into a monetary flow of depleted resources and the accumulation of a potential fund. Specifically: (a) the unit values for tonne of oil equivalent resource is based roughly on OBR (2014); (b) we assume that production is zero until a given date (e.g. production begins in 2020, 2025 or 2030) and is constant thereafter (until the resource is exhausted); and, (c) in terms of accumulation of a fund, we further assume that resource revenues accrue from the outset of production with an arbitrary cut-off, for purposes of illustration, of 2040.

Table A3.1: Assumptions and Parameter Choices for SWF Based on (Future) Revenues from Shale Resources

Base-case Sensitivity Total resources in place (mtoe) Low 22,500 Medium 36,000 High 63,000 Percentage of resources recoverable 2,%, 4%, 6% Start of production: years from 2010 15 10 20 Depletion path/ lifetimes 35 25 45 Price: GBP per toe (GBP, 2010) 500 400 600 Total rent: as % of production value 50% 35% 65% Resource revenues: as % of total rent 65% 50% 80%

Table A3.2 describes the value of a hypothetical SWF that could be built, by 2040, from depleting these assumed shale resources. The initial three rows of results indicate the size of the fund given: (a) three distinct potential sizes of ‘resources-in-place’; (b) three distinct probabilities of these resources being recovered; plus (c) a range of additional (base-case) assumptions. The following four rows indicates the sensitivity of findings – for low and medium resources-in-place only – to a different assumption about when production begins: i.e. a shorter or longer time horizon for resource revenues to accumulate in a fund by 2040 (and where all other parameter values remain the same). The final four rows assume production begins in 2025 – again, for low and medium resources-in-place – but otherwise look at relatively ‘optimistic’ and ‘pessimistic’ scenarios. In the former, the oil price is high as is the proportion of rent (to production value) and in addition the capture of resource revenues is high too. In the latter, all of these parameters are assumed to take low values. (See Table A3.1 for details.)

26

Table A3.2: Sensitivity of a Hypothetical SWF in 2040 to Alternative Assumptions (million GBP, 2010)

Estimated Assumed recovery rate Other assumptions Resources 4 per cent 2 per cent 6 per cent Low 62,679 31,339 94,018 See base-case assumptions in Medium 100,286 50,143 150,429 Table 3 High 175,500 87,850 263,250

Low 83,571 41,786 125,357 Production begins in 2020 + Medium 133,714 66,857 200,571 rest of base-case assumptions Low 41,786 20,893 62,679 Production begins in 2030 + Medium 66,857 33,429 100,286 rest of base-case assumptions

Low 120,343 60,171 180,514 Price/ rent/ resource revenues Medium 201,080 100,540 301,619 high + rest of base-case Low 27,000 13,500 40,500 Price/ rent/ resource revenues Medium 43,200 21,600 64,800 low + rest of base case

Recall that our fund for 1975-2010 was GBP 284,106 million (GBP, 2010) by 2010. The above Table indicates that a shale-based fund only approaches this magnitude in the presence of a high amount of resources-in-place and a 6% recovery of those resources (i.e. GBP 263,250 million, GBP 2010) or either earlier production and/ or optimistic assumptions about other parameter values. The possible fund sizes for more conservative estimates remains significant in many cases, although not so with more pessimistic (but still plausible) assumptions. Linking this back to our discussion of Figure 4, Table A3.3 illustrates the magnitude, and implied pay-out, in 2040 of two hypothetical SWFs; one beginning in 1975 and the other beginning in 2015 (based on e.g. medium levels of resources-in-place and an assumed 4% recovery rate).

Table A.3.3: Summary of Size and Payment from Hypothetical SWF in 2040 (million GBP, 2010)

Size of Implied fund hypothetic payout al fund

Total 477,679 18,725 Contribution from: Conventional resource revenues: 1975-2010 284,106 11,137 Conventional resource revenues: 2011-2040 93,287 3,657 1975 Fund 1975 Shale resource revenues: 2015-2040 100,286 3,931

Total 168,910 6,621

Contribution from: 2015 2015

Fund Conventional resource revenues: 2015-2040 68,624 2,690 Shale resource revenues: 2015-2040 100,286 3,931

27