Stadiums and Scheduling: Measuring Deadweight Losses in Professional Sports Leagues, 1920-1970

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Stadiums and Scheduling: Measuring Deadweight Losses in Professional Sports Leagues, 1920-1970 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 1441-5429 DISCUSSION PAPER 07/15 Stadiums and Scheduling: Measuring Deadweight Losses in Professional Sports Leagues, 1920-1970 Lionel Frosta, Luc Borrowmanb and Abdel K. Halabic Abstract: In studies of professional sports leagues it has not been possible to quantify losses of economic welfare (deadweight losses) because of the absence of a counterfactual. Before 1970, Australian Football’s major league, the Melbourne-based Victorian Football League (VFL) set standard admission prices for all games and scheduled matches to distribute revenue evenly between clubs. Almost all of the League’s teams were based in one city, with all but one playing home (or regular season) games at small stadiums with limited facilities, while the city’s largest and best equipped stadium lay vacant every second weekend. By estimating demand for matches between the five highest drawing clubs over a 50-year period, we specify the size of revenue losses that resulted from different schedules and venues. The results show significant losses in League revenue and attendances, but these were not sufficient to threaten the survival of a distance-protected cartel. Fixed pricing created welfare gains for supporters of the larger clubs and welfare losses for supporters of the smaller clubs, and was not conducive to an even competition. Keywords: Sports, football, cartels, stadiums, scheduling, pricing JEL Classification Numbers: D42, L1, L830, N97 a Department of Economics, Monash Business School, Monash University; [email protected] b School of Business and Economics, Monash University Malaysia; [email protected] c Faculty of Business, Federation University Australia Gippsland Campus; [email protected] © 2015 Lionel Frost, Luc Borrowman and Abdel K. Halabi All rights reserved. No part of this paper may be reproduced in any form, or stored in a retrieval system, without the prior written permission of the author monash.edu/ business-economics ABN 12 377 614 012 CRICOS Provider No. 00008C 1 INTRODUCTION Sports leagues operate as cartels, the behavior of which, as Vamplew (2007) observes, depends on the drawing up and enforcement of rules that reflect the values of the rule makers. Leagues generate increased demand through fixed schedules of home-and-away matches, tables that show the rank order of teams, and rules that restrict club profits and the mobility of players to prevent strong clubs from dominating the competition (Neale 1964). However, league decisions about the venues and times at which matches are played, ticket prices and the admission of new teams may result in incomplete markets that fail to provide the product to all consumers whose willingness to pay is higher than the market price. Cartels are inherently unstable, because setting prices above marginal cost provides an incentive for individual firms to ‘defect’, through price shaving to increase demand (Stigler 1964). Stigler’s (1958) ‘survivor principle’ suggests that a cartel is an optimum market structure if cost and efficiency advantages allow it to maintain or expand market share in an industry over time. Because cartel survival depends on the development of effective mechanisms to monitor and enforce agreements and distribute profits to members, duration is the simplest and most common measure of cartel success (Levenstein and Suslow 2006). Until the 1950s, and in some cases the 1960s, all sports leagues supplied products that were largely non-tradable. Apart from limited newsreel and television coverage, markets did not exist for potential consumers who could not watch a sports event in person. Leagues operated in regional markets that were protected from import competition, and while this distance protection fostered cultures of intense local fan loyalty, it also tended to entrench conservative cartel behavior that restricted the size of markets and the total surpluses they generated. While distance protection was conducive to the survival of cartels, it also encouraged reduced output levels as consumers dropped out of markets, creating deadweight losses. 2 Szymanski and Zimbalist (2005) draw a distinction between the evolution of American baseball’s major league as a profit-oriented organization that drove competing leagues out of business, and that of soccer, which retained a broad federation of competitive clubs. Soccer clubs primarily sought to maximize the utility derived from winning matches, and were willing to accept league restrictions on the profits they could make. British football leagues set minimum admission charges, which prevented clubs from reducing prices to increase attendances at less attractive matches (Vamplew 1988; Tabner 1992). Until floodlights were approved for use in the English and Scottish leagues in 1956, midweek matches were played in the afternoon, when only fans who were able to take time off work could attend (Pierce 2006). Although baseball and American football team owners sought to maximize profits, their leagues opposed the relocation or establishment of franchises in western and southern cities (White 1996; MacCambridge 2004). In the first half of twentieth century, baseball excluded black players (and a potential black fan base), resisted opportunities to play matches at night, and responded slowly to opportunities to negotiate broadcast agreements for radio and television (Tygiel 2000, 2008). Intuitively, economists would regard such practices as likely to generate suboptimal outcomes. Estimation of the size of these economic inefficiencies requires a comparison of levels of revenue and utility in a cartelized industry with those that would have prevailed in competitive markets. However, such empirical work is constrained by the absence of a counterfactual that would allow specification of true levels of demand and the total surplus that would have been generated had markets been more competitive (Levenstein and Suslow 2006). Discouraged spectators leave no data. Once sports products became tradable and leagues expanded the size of their markets they moved to new production possibilities 3 frontiers.1 As a result it is not appropriate to use revenue from a given time period to quantify earlier inefficient levels of production. It is possible to construct a counterfactual for Australian Football’s major league, the Victorian Football League (VFL). Australian Football is played at an elite level in only one country and developed idiosyncratic rules and practices in splendid isolation. In terms of the rise of professional sport worldwide, Australian Football is an outlier in the general sense of the word. However, this does not mean that its experience should necessarily be discarded from broader consideration of the significance of deadweight losses in distance-protected sports leagues. For most of the period from 1920-1970, the VFL had 12 clubs, 11 of them based in Melbourne, but only one played home (or regular season) games at the Melbourne Cricket Ground (MCG), a large, centrally-located stadium at which the quality of spectator amenities was much greater than that of the smaller stadiums of other teams. The MCG was a latent asset that lay vacant every second weekend until a second club began a ground-sharing arrangement there in 1965. The situation parallels that of London, where seven teams that have played at least 20 seasons in the Premier League or its equivalent are based, but none use Wembley Stadium for League matches. VFL grounds were used for cricket for six months of each year and the League played matches only on Saturday afternoons because State government legislation prohibited play on Sundays. One VFL ground had floodlights, but these were not used for official League matches. No more than one match was played at any venue on the same day. Before 1970, the League scheduled 18 rounds, which in a 12- 1 Pete Rozelle’s strategy as NFL commissioner from 1960-1989 to expand the League beyond its traditional regional boundaries, embrace television as a source of revenue, and equalise the playing strength of member teams, is the pre-eminent example of the successful transformation of a sport (MacCambridge 2004; Oriard 2007). 4 team competition meant that each team played four others only once during a season. The schedule was set randomly, to give every team the same opportunity to attract large crowds. Similar scheduling issues were, and are, faced by America’s National Football League as the length of the season does not allow each team at least one home field advantage in all of its games against other teams. In terms of structure, the VFL occupied a position between the closed cartels of North American leagues and the more organic promotion-and-relegation system of European soccer, which allows teams to join and move up and down the divisions of leagues. The VFL was not a profit-maximizing organization, and its clubs were owned by members, for whom membership was an item of consumption that yielded utility through winning matches. The VFL operated with a fixed number of member clubs, as did North American leagues, and clubs could only join the League when it chose to admit more teams. Poorly performing teams did not face the threat of relegation. Unlike North American teams, VFL clubs did not enjoy territorial monopolies, but drew strong support from the districts in which they had originated.2 Most club grounds lay within a one-hour walk of each other and all were accessible by trains and trams. As in English soccer, teams did not travel long distances in search of profitable
Recommended publications
  • Wartime Price Control and the Problem of Inflation
    WARTIME PRICE CONTROL AND THE PROBLEM OF INFLATION J. M. CLARK* I. Inflation and the Normal Function of Price Everyone opposes "inflation"-or nearly everyone. And everyone agrees that war brings on inflation if it is allowed to run its natural course unresisted. But there is no real agreement as to just what "inflation" is. On the whole it seems best to consider that what we are talking about is harmful price increases of a widespread or general sort, and then go on to examine the things that do harm, and the kinds of harm they do; and forget this ill-defined and controversial term. So far as the term is used in this article, it will mean simply general price increases of harmful magnitude. In ordinary times, it is customary to say, price is the agency which brings supply and demand into equality with one another, allocates productive resources between different products, determines how much of each shall be produced and limits de- mand to the amount that is available. This is a shorthand form of statement, and in some respects a bit misleading. The chief misleading implication is that production responds only to price; and, if supply is short of demand, production will not increase except as price rises. It is true that in such a situation price will usually rise, and production will increase; but this leaves out the most essential part of the process: namely, an increase in the volume of buying orders. In a large-scale manufacturing industry, this alone will ordinarily result in increased output.
    [Show full text]
  • Current Affairs February 2019
    VISION IAS www.visionias.in CURRENT AFFAIRS FEBRUARY 2019 Copyright © by Vision IAS All rights are reserved. No part of this document may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without prior permission of Vision IAS. 1 www.visionias.in ©Vision IAS Table of Contents 1. POLITY AND GOVERNANCE ____________ 4 5.5. Landscape-Level Approach to Address 1.1. Falling Productivity of Rajya Sabha _______ 4 Human-Elephant Conflicts ________________ 50 1.2. National Security Act __________________ 5 5.6. Cheetah Reintroduction _______________ 51 1.3. Section 124-A of The Indian Penal Code ___ 6 5.7. Indus Dolphin _______________________ 52 1.4. Judges and Post Retirement Positions ____ 7 5.8. The New Delhi Declaration on Asian Rhinos 2. INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS ___________ 9 2019 __________________________________ 52 2.1. India-Saudi Arabia Relations ____________ 9 5.9. Low Carbon Strategy for Renewable Energy 2.2. Chabahar Port ______________________ 10 Integration _____________________________ 53 2.3. Geneva Convention 1949 ______________ 11 5.10. Rainwater Harvesting in Metropolitan 2.4. ICJ on Decolonization of Mauritius ______ 13 Cities _________________________________ 54 2.5. Intermediate-Range Nuclear Forces Treaty 14 5.11. Pradhan Mantri Ji-Van (Jaiv Indhan- 3. ECONOMY _________________________ 16 Vatavaran Anukool Fasal Awashesh Nivaran) 3.1. Pradhan Mantri Kisan Samman Nidhi (PM- Yojana ________________________________ 55 KISAN) ________________________________ 16 5.12. Eviction Order of Forest Dwellers ______ 56 3.2. Policy Bias Against Rainfed Agriculture ___ 18 5.13. Environmental Rule of Law ___________ 57 3.3.
    [Show full text]
  • IB Economics HL Study Guide
    S T U D Y G UID E HL www.ib.academy IB Academy Economics Study Guide Available on learn.ib.academy Author: Joule Painter Contributing Authors: William van Leeuwenkamp, Lotte Muller, Carlijn Straathof Design Typesetting Special thanks: Andjela Triˇckovi´c This work may be shared digitally and in printed form, but it may not be changed and then redistributed in any form. Copyright © 2018, IB Academy Version: EcoHL.1.2.181211 This work is published under the Creative Commons BY-NC-ND 4.0 International License. To view a copy of this license, visit creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0 This work may not used for commercial purposes other than by IB Academy, or parties directly licenced by IB Academy. If you acquired this guide by paying for it, or if you have received this guide as part of a paid service or product, directly or indirectly, we kindly ask that you contact us immediately. Laan van Puntenburg 2a ib.academy 3511ER, Utrecht [email protected] The Netherlands +31 (0) 30 4300 430 TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction 5 1. Microeconomics 7 – Demand and supply – Externalities – Government intervention – The theory of the firm – Market structures – Price discrimination 2. Macroeconomics 51 – Overall economic activity – Aggregate demand and aggregate supply – Macroeconomic objectives – Government Intervention 3. International Economics 77 – Trade – Exchange rates – The balance of payments – Terms of trade 4. Development Economics 93 – Economic development – Measuring development – Contributions and barriers to development – Evaluation of development policies 5. Definitions 105 – Microeconomics – Macroeconomics – International Economics – Development Economics 6. Abbreviations 125 7. Essay guide 129 – Time Management – Understanding the question – Essay writing style – Worked example 3 TABLE OF CONTENTS 4 INTRODUCTION The foundations of economics Before we start this course, we must first look at the foundations of economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Price Ceilings and Price Floors (Supports) Price Ceiling Price Floor
    Price Ceilings and Price Floors (Supports) Price Ceiling Price Floor Market Equilibrium P = __$2.50__ Q = ___12___ also the allocatively efficient quantity because at Q = 12, MSB=MSC Price Ceiling Ceiling Price = $ 2.00 Qd = __14___ Qs = __10____ Shortage = ___4___ = allocative inefficiency: at the quantity of 10, MSB > MSC, so there is an UNDERallocation of resources Price Floor Floor Price = $ 3.00 Qd = ___10___ Qs = ___14___ Shortage = ____4___ = allocative inefficiency: at the quantity of 14 MSB < MSC, so there is an OVERallocation of resources Quick Quiz – Government Set Prices 1. In the above market, economists would call a government-set minimum price of $50 a: A. price ceiling. B. price floor. C. equilibrium price. D. fair price. 2. In the above market, economists would call a government-set maximum price of $40 a: A. price ceiling. B. price floor. C. equilibrium price. D. fair price. 3. If government set a minimum price of $50 in the above market, a: A. shortage of 21 units would occur. B. shortage of 125 units would occur. C. surplus of 21 units would occur. D. surplus of 125 units would occur. 4. If government set a maximum price of $50 in the above market: A. a shortage of 21 units would arise. B. a surplus of 21 units would arise. C. a surplus of 40 units would arise. D. it would create neither a shortage nor a surplus. 5. Refer to the above diagram. A government-set price floor is best illustrated by: A. price A. B. price B. C. price C. D.
    [Show full text]
  • AS Economics: Microeconomics Ability to Pay Where Taxes Should
    AS Economics: Microeconomics Key Term Glossary Ability to pay Where taxes should be set according to how well a person can afford to pay Ad valorem tax An indirect tax based on a percentage of the sales price of a good or service Adam Smith One of the founding fathers of modern economics. His most famous work was the Wealth of Nations (1776) - a study of the progress of nations where people act according to their own self-interest - which improves the public good. Smith's discussion of the advantages of division of labour remains a potent idea Adverse selection Where the expected value of a transaction is known more accurately by the buyer or the seller due to an asymmetry of information; e.g. health insurance Air passenger duty APD is a charge on air travel from UK airports. The level of APD depends on the country to which an airline passenger is flying. Alcohol duties Excise duties on alcohol are a form of indirect tax and are chargeable on beer, wine and spirits according to their volume and/or alcoholic content Alienation A sociological term to describe the estrangement many workers feel from their work, which may reduce their motivation and productivity. It is sometimes argued that alienation is a result of the division of labour because workers are not involved with the satisfaction of producing a finished product, and do not feel part of a team. Allocative efficiency Allocative efficiency occurs when the value that consumers place on a good or service (reflected in the price they are willing and able to pay) equals the cost of the resources used up in production (technical definition: price eQuals marginal cost).
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Department of Economics Issn 1441-5429 Discussion Paper 42/10 Labour Market Regulation and Professional Sport: the Case Of
    1 Department of Economics Issn 1441-5429 Discussion paper 42/10 Labour market regulation and professional sport: The case of the Victorian Football League’s Coulter Law, 1930-1970 Lionel Frost and Peter Schuwalow1 Abstract In most professional team sports, salary caps – first used in the mid-1980s – stabilise the financial position of teams and promote balanced competitions. Teams that do not comply with labour market regulations face heavy penalties and there is a debate about whether such labour markets should operate like competitive markets in general – with wages directing players to the teams that value their contributions most. Analysis of earlier restrictions on the mobility of players and the movement of wages may raise new questions about the effects of non- compliance. The Coulter Law was a set of Victorian Football League (VFL) recruiting and payment rules that operated from 1930 to 1970. The conventional view – that most VFL clubs breached the maximum player wage rules to maximise the utility derived from winning games – is supported only by anecdotal evidence. A new data set reveals that the Coulter Law did restrict earnings in the VFL, except for a small number of elite players. Clubs allowed players to take up more lucrative jobs in other leagues and their subsequent on-field performance reflected the level of talent of replacement players. 1 Department of Economics, Monash University © 2010 Lionel Frost and Peter Schuwalow All rights reserved. No part of this paper may be reproduced in any form, or stored in a retrieval system, without the prior written permission of the author.
    [Show full text]
  • Dictionary-Of-Economics-2.Pdf
    Dictionary of Economics A & C Black ț London First published in Great Britain in 2003 Reprinted 2006 A & C Black Publishers Ltd 38 Soho Square, London W1D 3HB © P. H. Collin 2003 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced in any form or by any means without the permission of the publishers A CIP record for this book is available from the British Library eISBN-13: 978-1-4081-0221-3 Text Production and Proofreading Heather Bateman, Katy McAdam A & C Black uses paper produced with elemental chlorine-free pulp, harvested from managed sustainable forests. Text typeset by A & C Black Printed in Italy by Legoprint Preface Economics is the basis of our daily lives, even if we do not always realise it. Whether it is an explanation of how firms work, or people vote, or customers buy, or governments subsidise, economists have examined evidence and produced theories which can be checked against practice. This book aims to cover the main aspects of the study of economics which students will need to learn when studying for examinations at various levels. The book will also be useful for the general reader who comes across these terms in the financial pages of newspapers as well as in specialist magazines. The dictionary gives succinct explanations of the 3,000 most frequently found terms. It also covers the many abbreviations which are often used in writing on economic subjects. Entries are also given for prominent economists, from Jeremy Bentham to John Rawls, with short biographies and references to their theoretical works.
    [Show full text]
  • AP Microeconomics Vocabulary 2014
    AP Microeconomics Vocabulary 2014 This is a list of every microeconomic term that must be known for the exam. 1. Microeconomics - The branch of economics that studies the economy of consumers or households or individual firms. 2. Macroeconomics - The branch of economics that studies the overall working of a national economy. 3. Scarcity - Scarcity is the fundamental economic problem of having seemingly unlimited human needs and wants, in a world of limited resources. It states that society has insufficient productive resources to fulfil all human wants and needs 4. Economic Efficiency - The use of resources so as to maximize the production of goods and services. 5. Economic Equity - Equity is the concept or idea of fairness. 6. Opportunity Cost - The cost of an opportunity forgone (and the loss of the benefits that could be received from that opportunity). 7. Productivity - The ratio of the quantity and quality of units produced to the labor per unit of time. 8. Inflation - A general and progressive increase in prices. 9. Philips Curve - A historical inverse relationship between the rate of unemployment and the rate of inflation in an economy. Stated simply, the lower the unemployment in an economy, the higher the rate of inflation. 10. Market Power - The ability of a firm to alter the market price of a good or service. In perfectly competitive markets, market participants have no market power. A firm with market power can raise prices without losing its customers to competitors. 11. Externality - A cost or benefit, not transmitted through prices, incurred by a party who did not agree to the action causing the cost or benefit.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 6 Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
    Mankiw: Priciples od Economics Chapter 6 Supply, Demand, and Government Policies Review Questions Using supply-demand diagrams, show the difference between a non-binding price ceiling and a binding price ceiling in the wheat market. ANSWER: The diagrams should look like panels (a) and (b) of Figure 6-1 in the text. Who benefits from a binding price ceiling? Who is hurt by a binding price ceiling? ANSWER: The buyers of the good or service subject to a price ceiling benefit from the ceiling, if they are still able to purchase the product. Sellers of a good or service subject to a price ceiling are hurt by the ceiling, as are the workers who produce the product, and those buyers unable to purchase the product because of the shortage caused by the price ceiling. In the long run, even successful buyers of the product may be hurt by the price ceiling because of deterioration in the quality of the product, as often occurs under rent control. Using the graph shown, analyze the effect a $300 price ceiling would have on the market for ten-speed bicycles. Would this be a binding price ceiling? Why would policymakers choose to impose a price ceiling? ANSWER: For this example, a $300 price ceiling would cause a shortage of 4,000 bicycles. Since the equilibrium price in the market is $500, this would be a binding price ceiling. More than one reason may exist for policymakers to impose a price ceiling in a market. Often this is done in an attempt to increase equity.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand and Supply Analysis: Introduction
    READING 13 Demand and Supply Analysis: Introduction by Richard V. Eastin, PhD, and Gary L. Arbogast, CFA Richard V. Eastin, PhD, is at the University of Southern California (USA). Gary L. Arbogast, CFA (USA). LEARNING OUTCOMES Mastery The candidate should be able to: a. distinguish among types of markets; b. explain the principles of demand and supply; c. describe causes of shifts in and movements along demand and supply curves; d. describe the process of aggregating demand and supply curves; e. describe the concept of equilibrium (partial and general), and mechanisms by which markets achieve equilibrium; f. distinguish between stable and unstable equilibria, including price bubbles, and identify instances of such equilibria; g. calculate and interpret individual and aggregate demand, and inverse demand and supply functions, and interpret individual and aggregate demand and supply curves; h. calculate and interpret the amount of excess demand or excess supply associated with a non-equilibrium price; i. describe types of auctions and calculate the winning price(s) of an auction; j. calculate and interpret consumer surplus, producer surplus, and total surplus; k. describe how government regulation and intervention affect demand and supply; l. forecast the effect of the introduction and the removal of a market interference (e.g., a price floor or ceiling) on price and quantity; m. calculate and interpret price, income, and cross- price elasticities of demand and describe factors that affect each measure. © 2011 CFA Institute. All rights reserved. 2 Reading 13 ■ Demand and Supply Analysis: Introduction 1 INTRODUCTION In a general sense, economics is the study of production, distribution, and con- sumption and can be divided into two broad areas of study: macroeconomics and microeconomics.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 6: Supply, Demand, and Government Policies Principles of Economics, 8Th Edition N
    Chapter 6: Supply, Demand, and Government Policies Principles of Economics, 8th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1 1. Introduction: a. This is an interesting chapter with important insights. b. Most of the examples of government interference in markets in this book--as well as other microeconomics books--reduce social welfare. i. They are often motivated by the desire to benefit a group with a narrow focus at the expense of a potentially much larger group with a more dispersed focus. c. Economists have two roles: i. Scientists and ii. Policy makers. d. This chapter offers our first look at policy. 2. Controls on Prices a. Buyers always want a lower price, while sellers want a higher price. b. Price ceiling is a legal maximum on the price at which a good can be sold. P. 112. i. Rent controls. c. Price floor is a legal minimum on the price at which a good can be sold. P. 112. i. Agricultural price supports ii. Minimum wages. d. How Price Ceilings Affect Market Outcomes i. Figure 1: A Market with a Price Ceiling. P. 113 ii. While there can be non-binding price ceilings, we are interested in the situations in which they are binding. iii. The outcome of a binding price ceiling is usually inefficient and unfair. (1) Some mechanism for rationing will naturally develop. (2) One method is the sellers’ personal biases. (3) Only the people who get it benefit. (4) A general result: When the government imposes a binding price ceiling on a competitive market, a shortage of the good arises and sellers must ration the scarce goods among the large number of potential buyers.
    [Show full text]
  • An Experimental Investigation of Hard and Soft Price Ceilings in Emissions Permit Markets
    An Experimental Investigation of Hard and Soft Price Ceilings in Emissions Permit Markets David F. Perkis Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University [email protected] Timothy N. Cason Department of Economics, Krannert School of Management, Purdue University [email protected] Wallace E. Tyner Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University [email protected] May 2014 Abstract Tradable emissions permits have been implemented to control pollution levels in various markets and represent a major component of legislative efforts to control greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Because permits are supplied for a fixed level of pollution, allowing the market for permits to determine the price, price control mechanisms may be needed to protect firms from price spikes caused by fluctuations in the demand for permits. We test permit markets in an experimental laboratory setting to determine the effectiveness of several price control mechanisms, with special attention on the soft price ceiling. We focus on a static setting similar to some of the earliest experimental work focused on price ceilings. Results indicate that both permit supply adjustments and price ceilings (hard ceilings) effectively limit elevated prices in this setting. By contrast, reserve auctions to implement soft ceilings do not consistently control prices, especially when a minimum reserve permit price is applied. Furthermore, the grandfathering of permits allows permit sellers to realize significant welfare gains at the expense of buyers under a soft ceiling policy. Our results thus highlight several advantages of hard ceilings for controlling short term price increases. Keywords : greenhouse gases ; hard price ceiling ; laboratory economic experiments; pollution controls ; price controls ; reserve auction ; soft price ceiling ; tradable emissions permit market (1) Introduction Emissions permit markets have been established for many pollutants to control environmental degradation.
    [Show full text]