Estimation of Distortion Risk Measures

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Estimation of Distortion Risk Measures Int. Statistical Inst.: Proc. 58th World Statistical Congress, 2011, Dublin (Session CPS046) p.5035 Estimation of Distortion Risk Measures Hideatsu Tsukahara Department of Economics, Seijo University, Tokyo e-mail address: [email protected] The concept of coherent risk measure was introduced in Artzner et al. (1999). They listed some properties, called axioms of `coherence', that any good risk measure should possess, and studied the (non-)coherence of widely-used risk measure such as Value-at- Risk (VaR) and expected shortfall (also known as tail conditional expectation or tail VaR). Kusuoka (2001) introduced two additional axioms called law invariance and comonotonic additivity, and proved that the class of coherent risk measures satisfying these two axioms coincides with the class of distortion risk measures with convex distortions. To be more speci¯c, let X be a random variable representing a loss of some ¯nancial position, and let F (x) := P(X · x) be the distribution function (df) of X. We denote ¡1 its quantile function by F (u) := inffx 2 R: FX (x) ¸ ug; 0 < u < 1. A distortion risk measure is then of the following form Z Z ¡1 ½D(X) := F (u) dD(u) = x dD ± F (x); (1) [0;1] R where D is a distortion function, which is simply a df D on [0; 1]; i.e., a right-continuous, increasing function on [0; 1] satisfying D(0) = 0 and D(1) = 1. For ½D(X) to be coherent, D must be convex, which we assume throughout this paper. The celebrated VaR can be written of the form (1), but with non-convex D; this implies that the VaR is not coherent. Also note that di®erent authors use di®erent names spectral risk measure or weighted V@R for a distortion risk measure. The most well-known example of coherent risk measure is£ the above-mentioned¤ ex- ES ¡1 ¡ ¡ pected shortfall. Taking distortion of the form D® (u) = ® u (1 ®) +, 0 < ® < 1 yields the expected shortfall as a distortion risk measure: Z 1 1 ¡1 ES®(X) := F (u) du: ® 1¡® The following one-parameter families of distortion yields several classes of coherent risk measures: ² PH ¡ ¡ θ Proportional hazards (PH) distortion: Dθ (u) = 1 (1 u) , ² PO ¡ ¡ Proportional odds (PO) distortion: Dθ (u) = θu=[1 (1 θ)u] ² GA ¡1 Gaussian distortion: Dθ (u) = ©(© (u) + log θ) To implement the risk management/regulatory procedure using risk measures, it is necessary to statistically estimate their values based on data. For a distortion risk measure, its form (1) suggests a natural estimator which is a simple form of an L-statistic. The main theme of this paper is to derive the asymptotic statistical properties of simple estimators of those risk measures based on strictly stationary sequences, and to compare some distortion risk measures and VaR. 1 Int. Statistical Inst.: Proc. 58th World Statistical Congress, 2011, Dublin (Session CPS046) p.5036 Let (Xn)n2N be a strictly stationary process with a stationary distribution F , and denote by Fn the empirical df based on the sample X1;:::;Xn. A natural estimator of ½(X) is given by Z 1 Xn b F¡1 ½n = n (u) dD(u) = cniXn:i; (2) 0 i=1 where cni := D(i=n) ¡ D((i ¡ 1)=n) and Xn:1 · Xn:2 · ¢ ¢ ¢ · Xn:n are the order statistics based on the sample X1;:::;Xn. In what follows, instead of restricting ourselves to the particular form (2) of L-statistic, we consider a general L-statistic of the following form: 1 Xn T = c h(X ); (3) n n ni n:i i=1 where cni's are constants. De¯ne for 0 · u · 1, Z Xn u Jn(u) := cni1((i¡1)=n; i=n](u) + cn11f0g(u); ªn(u) := Jn(v) dv i=1 1=2 Then we have Z Z 1 F¡1 F¡1 Tn = h( n (u))Jn(u) du = h( n (u)) dªn(u): 0 [0;1] Let g := h ± F ¡1, and de¯ne the centering constants Z Z 1 ¹n := g(u)Jn(u) du = g(u) dªn(u): 0 [0;1] Consistency is a basic desirable property of statistical estimators. The following result was proved in van Zwet (1980) for the i.i.d. case, but his proof remains to be valid for the ergodic case. Proposition 1 Suppose that X1;X2;::: forms an ergodic stationary sequence. Let 1 · p q p · 1, 1=p + 1=q = 1, and assume that Jn 2 L (0; 1) for n = 1; 2;:::, and g 2 L (0; 1). If either · 1 j jp 1 (i) 1 < p and supn E( Jn ) < , or (ii) p = 1 and fJn; n = 1; 2;:::g is uniformly integrable, then we have Tn ¡ ¹n ! 0; a.s.. R R 2 t t Further, if there exists aR function J Lp such that limn!1 0 Jn(s) ds = 0 J(s) ds for 2 ! every t (0; 1), then Tn [0;1] J(s) dg(s), a.s. By this result, in particular, our estimator ½bn in (2) of distortion risk measure proves to possess strong consistency under the very general conditions stated above. For the asymptotic normality, we basically draw upon Shorack and Wellner (1986), Chapter 19, for the form of assumptions and the line of argument. First we set out the following assumption on (Xn). 2 Int. Statistical Inst.: Proc. 58th World Statistical Congress, 2011, Dublin (Session CPS046) p.5037 F j (A.1) (Xn)n2N is strongly mixing: Setting i := σ(Xi;:::;Xj), the strong mixing coe±- cient n o j \ ¡ j 2 F k 2 F 1 ¸ ®(n) := sup P (A B) P (A)P (B) : A 1 ;B k+n; k 1 converges to 0 in such a way that p ®(n) = O(n¡θ¡´) for some θ ¸ 1 + 2; ´ > 0 Note that strong mixing assumption is the weakest requirement among various mixing concepts. Next we assume the bounded growth of g and Jn, and smoothness of Jn. (A.2) h is a function of bounded variation: h = h1 ¡ h2, where h1 and h2 are increasing, left-continuous, and satisfy ¡1 jhi(F (u))j · H(u); for all 0 < u < 1; ¡ ¡ where H(u) := Mu d1 (1 ¡ u) d2 . R ± ¡1 For g = h F , let dg be theR integral with respect to the Lebesgue-Stieltjes signed measure associated with g, and djgj be the integral with respect to the total variation measure associated with g. (A.3) There exists a function J which is jgj-a.e. continuous such that Jn converges to J locally uniformly jgj-a.e. ¡b ¡b (A.4) For B(u) := Mu 1 (1 ¡ u) 2 , jJn(u)j · B(u), jJ(u)j · B(u) for all 0 < u < 1 with b1 _ b2 < 1. We note that under (A.2) and (A.4), Z 1 [u(1 ¡ u)]rB(u) djgj(u) < 1 (4) 0 when r > (b1 + d1) _ (b2 + d2) (see Shorack and Wellner (1986), Lemma 19.1.1). Before we state and prove the asymptotic normality of the estimator (2), let us note that it is possible to reduce the argument to the uniform case, as in the i.i.d. case. Namely, there exists a strictly stationary sequence (»n)n2N with the same mixing rate as (Xn) such ¡1 that Xn = F (»n) and »n » U(0; 1) (on a possibly extended probability space; see Lemma 4.2 in Dehling and Philipp (2002)). Let Gn be the empirical df based on »1;:::;»n. Then Z L £ ¤ Tn ¡ ¹n = = g(u) d ªn(Gn(u)) ¡ ªn(u) : (5) [0;1] L Here X = Y means that the random variables X and Y have the same distribution. Let Ck(u; v) := P(»1 · u; »k · v) and put X1 X1 σ(u; v) := u ^ v ¡ uv + [Ck(u; v) ¡ uv] + [Ck(v; u) ¡ uv]: (6) k=2 k=2 When (»n) satis¯es the same mixing rate as in (A.1), it follows from the covariance inequal- ity (see Dehling and Philipp (2002), Lemma 3.9) that the two series on the right-handp side of (6) are absolutely convergent. We de¯ne the empirical process Un(u) := n(Gn(u) ¡ u) as usual. 3 Int. Statistical Inst.: Proc. 58th World Statistical Congress, 2011, Dublin (Session CPS046) p.5038 Theorem 2 Let (Xn)n2N be a strictly stationary sequence satifying (A.1){(A.4) with 2b + 1 1 b + d + i < ; i = 1; 2 (7) i i 2θ 2 Then we have p L 2 n(Tn ¡ ¹n) ¡! N(0; σ ); where Z Z 1 1 σ2 := σ(u; v)J(u)J(v) dg(u)dg(v) < 1 (8) 0 0 Returning to the problem of estimating distortion risk measures, we should set cni = n[D(i=n) ¡ D((i ¡ 1)=n)] and h(x) = x. Then in most cases, the limit of Jn will be d, so applying Theorem 2 we have the following corollary. Corollary 3 Assume (A.1), (A.2) with h(x) = x, (A.3) with J = d, and (A.4). Then, for the estimator ½bn of (2), we have p L 2 n(½bn ¡ ½(X)) ¡! N(0; σ ); where Z Z 1 1 σ2 = σ(u; v)d(u)d(v) dF ¡1(u)dF ¡1(v): 0 0 When we try to construct approximate con¯dence intervals for risk measures, we need to estimate the asymptotic variance (8). Let Z Yn := J(F (x)) dh(x); n 2 Z: [Xn;1) It is then easy to see that σ2 is written as the double-sided in¯nite sum of autocovariance γ(n) of the stationary sequence (Yn).
Recommended publications
  • Var and Other Risk Measures
    What is Risk? Risk Measures Methods of estimating risk measures Bibliography VaR and other Risk Measures Francisco Ramírez Calixto International Actuarial Association November 27th, 2018 Francisco Ramírez Calixto VaR and other Risk Measures What is Risk? Risk Measures Methods of estimating risk measures Bibliography Outline 1 What is Risk? 2 Risk Measures 3 Methods of estimating risk measures Francisco Ramírez Calixto VaR and other Risk Measures What is Risk? Risk Measures Methods of estimating risk measures Bibliography What is Risk? Risk 6= size of loss or size of a cost Risk lies in the unexpected losses. Francisco Ramírez Calixto VaR and other Risk Measures What is Risk? Risk Measures Methods of estimating risk measures Bibliography Types of Financial Risk In Basel III, there are three major broad risk categories: Credit Risk: Francisco Ramírez Calixto VaR and other Risk Measures What is Risk? Risk Measures Methods of estimating risk measures Bibliography Types of Financial Risk Operational Risk: Francisco Ramírez Calixto VaR and other Risk Measures What is Risk? Risk Measures Methods of estimating risk measures Bibliography Types of Financial Risk Market risk: Each one of these risks must be measured in order to allocate economic capital as a buer so that if a catastrophic event happens, the bank won't go bankrupt. Francisco Ramírez Calixto VaR and other Risk Measures What is Risk? Risk Measures Methods of estimating risk measures Bibliography Risk Measures Def. A risk measure is used to determine the amount of an asset or assets (traditionally currency) to be kept in reserve in order to cover for unexpected losses.
    [Show full text]
  • Minimizing Spectral Risk Measures Applied to Markov Decision Processes 3
    MINIMIZING SPECTRAL RISK MEASURES APPLIED TO MARKOV DECISION PROCESSES NICOLE BAUERLE¨ AND ALEXANDER GLAUNER Abstract. We study the minimization of a spectral risk measure of the total discounted cost generated by a Markov Decision Process (MDP) over a finite or infinite planning horizon. The MDP is assumed to have Borel state and action spaces and the cost function may be unbounded above. The optimization problem is split into two minimization problems using an infimum representation for spectral risk measures. We show that the inner minimization problem can be solved as an ordinary MDP on an extended state space and give sufficient conditions under which an optimal policy exists. Regarding the infinite dimensional outer minimization problem, we prove the existence of a solution and derive an algorithm for its numerical approximation. Our results include the findings in B¨auerle and Ott (2011) in the special case that the risk measure is Expected Shortfall. As an application, we present a dynamic extension of the classical static optimal reinsurance problem, where an insurance company minimizes its cost of capital. Key words: Risk-Sensitive Markov Decision Process; Spectral Risk Measure; Dy- namic Reinsurance AMS subject classifications: 90C40, 91G70, 91G05 1. Introduction In the last decade, there have been various proposals to replace the expectation in the opti- mization of Markov Decision Processes (MDPs) by risk measures. The idea behind it is to take the risk-sensitivity of the decision maker into account. Using simply the expectation models a risk-neutral decision maker whose optimal policy sometimes can be very risky, for an example see e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • Robust Spectral Risk Optimization When Information on Risk Spectrum Is Incomplete
    Robust Spectral Risk Optimization When Information on Risk Spectrum Is Incomplete Wei Wangy Huifu Xuz June 25, 2020 Abstract Spectral risk measure (SRM) is a weighted average of value at risk (VaR) where the weighting function (also known as risk spectrum or distortion function) characterizes decision maker's risk attitude. In this paper, we consider the case where the decision maker's risk spectrum is ambiguous and introduce a robust SRM model based on the worst risk spectrum from a ball of risk spectra centred at a nominal risk spectrum. When the ball consists of step-like risk spectra, we show that the robust SRM can be computed by solving a linear programming problem. For general case, we propose a step-like approximation scheme and derive an error bound for the approximation. As an application, we apply the proposed robust SRM to one-stage stochastic optimization with objective of minimizing the robust SRM and propose an alternating iterative algorithm for solving the resulting minimax optimization problem. Moreover, to examine stability of the robust spectral risk optimization model with respect to perturbation of observed data from the underlying exogenous uncertainty in data- driven environments, we investigate statistical robustness of the model and derive sufficient conditions for the required stability. Keywords: robust spectral risk measure, robust spectral risk optimization, step-like ap- proximation, alternating iterative algorithm, statistical robustness 1 Introduction Spectral risk measure (SRM) is a weighted average of value at risk (VaR) where the weighting function captures an investor's risk preference. The weighting function is formally called risk spectrum as it determines the nature of SRM.
    [Show full text]
  • A Framework for Dynamic Hedging Under Convex Risk Measures
    A Framework for Dynamic Hedging under Convex Risk Measures Antoine Toussaint∗ Ronnie Sircary November 2008; revised August 2009 Abstract We consider the problem of minimizing the risk of a financial position (hedging) in an incomplete market. It is well-known that the industry standard for risk measure, the Value- at-Risk, does not take into account the natural idea that risk should be minimized through diversification. This observation led to the recent theory of coherent and convex risk measures. But, as a theory on bounded financial positions, it is not ideally suited for the problem of hedging because simple strategies such as buy-hold strategies may not be bounded. Therefore, we propose as an alternative to use convex risk measures defined as functionals on L2 (or by simple extension Lp, p > 1). This framework is more suitable for optimal hedging with L2 valued financial markets. A dual representation is given for this minimum risk or market adjusted risk when the risk measure is real-valued. In the general case, we introduce constrained hedging and prove that the market adjusted risk is still a L2 convex risk measure and the existence of the optimal hedge. We illustrate the practical advantage in the shortfall risk measure by showing how minimizing risk in this framework can lead to a HJB equation and we give an example of computation in a stochastic volatility model with the shortfall risk measure 1 Introduction We are interested in the problem of hedging in an incomplete market: an investor decides to buy a contract with a non-replicable payoff X at time T but has the opportunity to invest in a financial market to cover his risk.
    [Show full text]
  • Divergence-Based Risk Measures: a Discussion on Sensitivities and Extensions
    entropy Article Divergence-Based Risk Measures: A Discussion on Sensitivities and Extensions Meng Xu 1 and José M. Angulo 2,* 1 School of Economics, Sichuan University, Chengdu 610065, China 2 Department of Statistics and Operations Research, University of Granada, 18071 Granada, Spain * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +34-958-240492 Received: 13 June 2019; Accepted: 24 June 2019; Published: 27 June 2019 Abstract: This paper introduces a new family of the convex divergence-based risk measure by specifying (h, f)-divergence, corresponding with the dual representation. First, the sensitivity characteristics of the modified divergence risk measure with respect to profit and loss (P&L) and the reference probability in the penalty term are discussed, in view of the certainty equivalent and robust statistics. Secondly, a similar sensitivity property of (h, f)-divergence risk measure with respect to P&L is shown, and boundedness by the analytic risk measure is proved. Numerical studies designed for Rényi- and Tsallis-divergence risk measure are provided. This new family integrates a wide spectrum of divergence risk measures and relates to divergence preferences. Keywords: convex risk measure; preference; sensitivity analysis; ambiguity; f-divergence 1. Introduction In the last two decades, there has been a substantial development of a well-founded risk measure theory, particularly propelled since the axiomatic approach introduced by [1] in relation to the concept of coherency. While, to a large extent, the theory has been fundamentally inspired and motivated with financial risk assessment objectives in perspective, many other areas of application are currently or potentially benefited by the formal mathematical construction of the discipline.
    [Show full text]
  • G-Expectations with Application to Risk Measures
    g-Expectations with application to risk measures Sonja C. Offwood Programme in Advanced Mathematics of Finance, University of the Witwatersrand, Johannesburg. 5 August 2012 Abstract Peng introduced a typical filtration consistent nonlinear expectation, called a g-expectation in [40]. It satisfies all properties of the classical mathematical ex- pectation besides the linearity. Peng's conditional g-expectation is a solution to a backward stochastic differential equation (BSDE) within the classical framework of It^o'scalculus, with terminal condition given at some fixed time T . In addition, this g-expectation is uniquely specified by a real function g satisfying certain properties. Many properties of the g-expectation, which will be presented, follow from the spec- ification of this function. Martingales, super- and submartingales have been defined in the nonlinear setting of g-expectations. Consequently, a nonlinear Doob-Meyer decomposition theorem was proved. Applications of g-expectations in the mathematical financial world have also been of great interest. g-Expectations have been applied to the pricing of contin- gent claims in the financial market, as well as to risk measures. Risk measures were introduced to quantify the riskiness of any financial position. They also give an indi- cation as to which positions carry an acceptable amount of risk and which positions do not. Coherent risk measures and convex risk measures will be examined. These risk measures were extended into a nonlinear setting using the g-expectation. In many cases due to intermediate cashflows, we want to work with a multi-period, dy- namic risk measure. Conditional g-expectations were then used to extend dynamic risk measures into the nonlinear setting.
    [Show full text]
  • Loss-Based Risk Measures Rama Cont, Romain Deguest, Xuedong He
    Loss-Based Risk Measures Rama Cont, Romain Deguest, Xuedong He To cite this version: Rama Cont, Romain Deguest, Xuedong He. Loss-Based Risk Measures. 2011. hal-00629929 HAL Id: hal-00629929 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-00629929 Submitted on 7 Oct 2011 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Loss-based risk measures Rama CONT1,3, Romain DEGUEST 2 and Xue Dong HE3 1) Laboratoire de Probabilit´es et Mod`eles Al´eatoires CNRS- Universit´ePierre et Marie Curie, France. 2) EDHEC Risk Institute, Nice (France). 3) IEOR Dept, Columbia University, New York. 2011 Abstract Starting from the requirement that risk measures of financial portfolios should be based on their losses, not their gains, we define the notion of loss-based risk measure and study the properties of this class of risk measures. We charac- terize loss-based risk measures by a representation theorem and give examples of such risk measures. We then discuss the statistical robustness of estimators of loss-based risk measures: we provide a general criterion for qualitative ro- bustness of risk estimators and compare this criterion with sensitivity analysis of estimators based on influence functions.
    [Show full text]
  • A Discussion on Recent Risk Measures with Application to Credit Risk: Calculating Risk Contributions and Identifying Risk Concentrations
    risks Article A Discussion on Recent Risk Measures with Application to Credit Risk: Calculating Risk Contributions and Identifying Risk Concentrations Matthias Fischer 1,*, Thorsten Moser 2 and Marius Pfeuffer 1 1 Lehrstuhl für Statistik und Ökonometrie, Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg, Lange Gasse 20, 90403 Nürnberg, Germany; [email protected] 2 Risikocontrolling Kapitalanlagen, R+V Lebensverischerung AG, Raiffeisenplatz 1, 65189 Wiesbaden, Germany; [email protected] * Correspondence: matthias.fi[email protected] Received: 11 October 2018; Accepted: 30 November 2018; Published: 7 December 2018 Abstract: In both financial theory and practice, Value-at-risk (VaR) has become the predominant risk measure in the last two decades. Nevertheless, there is a lively and controverse on-going discussion about possible alternatives. Against this background, our first objective is to provide a current overview of related competitors with the focus on credit risk management which includes definition, references, striking properties and classification. The second part is dedicated to the measurement of risk concentrations of credit portfolios. Typically, credit portfolio models are used to calculate the overall risk (measure) of a portfolio. Subsequently, Euler’s allocation scheme is applied to break the portfolio risk down to single counterparties (or different subportfolios) in order to identify risk concentrations. We first carry together the Euler formulae for the risk measures under consideration. In two cases (Median Shortfall and Range-VaR), explicit formulae are presented for the first time. Afterwards, we present a comprehensive study for a benchmark portfolio according to Duellmann and Masschelein (2007) and nine different risk measures in conjunction with the Euler allocation. It is empirically shown that—in principle—all risk measures are capable of identifying both sectoral and single-name concentration.
    [Show full text]
  • A Framework for Time-Consistent, Risk-Averse Model Predictive Control: Theory and Algorithms
    A Framework for Time-Consistent, Risk-Averse Model Predictive Control: Theory and Algorithms Yin-Lam Chow, Marco Pavone Abstract— In this paper we present a framework for risk- planner conservatism and the risk of infeasibility (clearly this averse model predictive control (MPC) of linear systems af- can not be achieved with a worst-case approach). Second, fected by multiplicative uncertainty. Our key innovation is risk-aversion allows the control designer to increase policy to consider time-consistent, dynamic risk metrics as objective functions to be minimized. This framework is axiomatically robustness by limiting confidence in the model. Third, risk- justified in terms of time-consistency of risk preferences, is aversion serves to prevent rare undesirable events. Finally, in amenable to dynamic optimization, and is unifying in the sense a reinforcement learning framework when the world model that it captures a full range of risk assessments from risk- is not accurately known, a risk-averse agent can cautiously neutral to worst case. Within this framework, we propose and balance exploration versus exploitation for fast convergence analyze an online risk-averse MPC algorithm that is provably stabilizing. Furthermore, by exploiting the dual representation and to avoid “bad” states that could potentially lead to a of time-consistent, dynamic risk metrics, we cast the computa- catastrophic failure [9], [10]. tion of the MPC control law as a convex optimization problem Inclusion of risk-aversion in MPC is difficult for two main amenable to implementation on embedded systems. Simulation reasons. First, it appears to be difficult to model risk in results are presented and discussed.
    [Show full text]
  • Determination of Risk Pricing Measures from Market Prices of Risk
    Determination of risk pricing measures from market prices of risk Henryk Gzyl and Silvia Mayoral ∗ IESA, Caracas, Venezuela and UNAV, Pamplona, Espa˜na. Abstract A new insurance provider or a regulatory agency may be interested in determining a risk measure consistent with observed market prices of a collection of risks. Using a relationship between distorted coherent risk measures and spectral risk measures, we provide a method for reconstruct- ing distortion functions from the observed prices of risk. The technique is based on an appropriate application of the method of maximum entropy in the mean, which builds upon the classical method of maximum entropy. Key words. Distortion function, Spectral measures, Risk Aversion Func- tion, Maximum entropy in the mean, Inverse problems. ∗The research of this author was partially funded by Welzia Management, SGIIC SA, RD Sistemas SA , Comunidad Autnoma de Madrid Grant s-0505/tic/000230, and MEyC Grant BEC2000-1388-C04-03. 1 1 Introduction The problem of pricing actuarial risk has received a great deal of attention in recent years, generating a large amount of theoretical and practical work. A good account of the traditional and modern pricing methods appears in the book by Kaas, Goovaerts, Dhaene and Denuit (Kaas et al. (2005)). Among pricing measures the class of distorted risk measures is popular and appealing. For fur- ther details and the general philosophy of distorted risk measures the interested reader may consult Wang (1996), Wang, Young and Panjer (1997), and Wang and Young (1998), where, building on Quiggin (1982), Yaari (1987), and Schmeidler (1989), an axiomatic characterization and many applications to insurance can be found.
    [Show full text]
  • Part 2 Axiomatic Theory of Monetary Risk Measures
    Short Course Theory and Practice of Risk Measurement Part 2 Axiomatic Theory of Monetary Risk Measures Ruodu Wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo, Canada Email: [email protected] Ruodu Wang Peking University 2016 Part 2 Monetary risk measures Acceptance sets and duality Coherent risk measures Convex risk measures Dual representation theorems Ruodu Wang Peking University 2016 Axiomatic Theory of Risk Measures In this part of the lectures, we study some properties of a \desirable" risk measure. Of course, desirability is very subjective. We stand mainly from a regulator's point of view to determine capital requirement for random losses. Such properties are often called axioms in the literature. The main interest of study is What characterizes the risk measures satisfying certain axioms? We assume X = L1 unless otherwise specified. We allow random variables to take negative values - i.e. profits Recall that we use (Ω; F; P) for an atomless probability space. Ruodu Wang Peking University 2016 Monetary Risk Measures Two basic properties [CI] cash-invariance: ρ(X + c) = ρ(X ) + c, c 2 R; [M] monotonicity: ρ(X ) ≤ ρ(Y ) if X ≤ Y . These two properties are widely accepted. Here, risk-free interest rate is assumed to be 0 (or we can interpret everything as discounted). Recall that we treat a.s. equal random variables identical. Ruodu Wang Peking University 2016 Monetary Risk Measures The property [CI]: By adding or subtracting a deterministic quantity c to a position leading to the loss X the capital requirement is altered by exactly that amount of c. Loss X with ρ(X ) > 0: Adding the amount of capital ρ(X ) to the position leads to the adjusted loss X~ = X − ρ(X ), which is ρ(X~) = ρ(X − ρ(X )) = 0; so that the position X~ is acceptable without further injection of capital.
    [Show full text]
  • Risk Averse Stochastic Programming: Time Consistency and Optimal Stopping
    Risk averse stochastic programming: time consistency and optimal stopping Alois Pichler Fakult¨atf¨urMathematik Technische Universit¨atChemnitz D–09111 Chemnitz, Germany Rui Peng Liu and Alexander Shapiro∗ School of Industrial and Systems Engineering Georgia Institute of Technology Atlanta, GA 30332-0205 June 13, 2019 Abstract This paper addresses time consistency of risk averse optimal stopping in stochastic optimization. It is demonstrated that time consistent optimal stopping entails a specific structure of the functionals describing the transition between consecutive stages. The stopping risk measures capture this structural behavior and they allow natural dynamic equations for risk averse decision making over time. Consequently, associated optimal policies satisfy Bellman’s principle of optimality, which characterizes optimal policies for optimization by stating that a decision maker should not reconsider previous decisions retrospectively. We also discuss numerical approaches to solving such problems. Keywords: Stochastic programming, coherent risk measures, time consistency, dynamic equations, optimal stopping time, Snell envelope. arXiv:1808.10807v3 [math.OC] 12 Jun 2019 1 Introduction Optimal Stopping (OS) is a classical topic of research in statistics and operations research going back to the pioneering work of Wald(1947, 1949) on sequential analysis. For a thorough ∗Research of this author was partly supported by NSF grant 1633196, and DARPA EQUiPS program grant SNL 014150709. discussion of theoretical foundations of OS we can refer to Shiryaev(1978), for example. The classical formulation of OS assumes availability of the probability distribution of the considered data process. Of course in real life applications the ‘true distribution’ is never known exactly and in itself can be viewed as uncertain.
    [Show full text]