European Integration, 195O–2Oo3 Superstate Or New Market Economy?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

European Integration, 195O–2Oo3 Superstate Or New Market Economy? European Integration, 195o–2oo3 Superstate or New Market Economy? JOHN GILLINGHAM University of Missouri, St. Louis published by the press syndicate of the university of cambridge The Pitt Building, Trumpington Street, Cambridge, United Kingdom cambridge university press The Edinburgh Building, Cambridge cb2 2ru, uk 40 West 20th Street, New York, ny 10011-4211, usa 477 Williamstown Road, Port Melbourne, vic 3207, Australia Ruiz de Alarcón 13, 28014 Madrid, Spain Dock House, The Waterfront, Cape Town 8001, South Africa http://www.cambridge.org © John Gillingham 2003 This book is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements, no reproduction of any part may take place without the written permission of Cambridge University Press. First published 2003 Printed in the United States of America Typeface Sabon 10/12 pt. System ams-tex [fh] A catalog record for this book is available from the British Library. Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication data available isbn 0 521 81317 4 hardback isbn 0 521 01262 7 paperback Contents Preface page xi List of Abbreviations xix I A German Solution to Europe’s Problems? The Early History of the European Communities, 195o–1965 Introduction to Part I A New Global Setting 3 Chapter 1 The Liberal Project for an Integrated Europe 6 The Legacy of Friedrich von Hayek 6 The Classical Liberal Solution to the German Problem 11 Chapter 2 The Rise and Decline of Monnetism 16 Monnet and the Condition of Postwar Europe 18 Monnet and the Origins of European Institutions 22 Chapter 3 More or Less Liberal Europe: The Institutional Origins of Integration 34 From Pax Americana to Pax Universalia 37 Miracles Can Sometimes Happen: Erhard’s Reforms 41 All Hands on Board: The Re-launching 43 Chapter 4 All or Nothing? The Founding of the EEC and the End of an Era, 1958–1966 53 Walter Hallstein’s Commission 55 Independence, Interdependence, or Dependence? President Kennedy and Europe 66 Empty Chairs and Hallstein’s End 68 Conclusion to Part I Needed: A New Integration Scenario 73 II From Embedded Liberalism to Liberalism, A Step Forward: European Integration and Regime Change in the 197os Introduction to Part II A New European Situation 81 Chapter 5 From Realms of Theory to a Sphere of Action: Integration Revived 84 Taking Stock in a Whirlwind: Rethinking Integration 85 vii viii Contents Regime Change 97 Dollar Dethronement and Collapse of the Bretton Woods System 100 Chapter 6 Better than Muddling Through: The World Market, the European Community, and the Member-States in the 1970s 105 The New Protectionism 106 Neomercantilism and Corporatism in France, Germany, Italy, and Great Britain 110 A Most Imperfect Union: Structure and Policy Process at the EC 120 Toward a Less Imperfect Union: European Law, the European Council, Monetary Convergence, and the Recovery of International Trade 130 Margaret Thatcher: Founding Mother of the New Europe 136 Conclusion to Part II Needed: A New Integration Theory 144 III Seeking the New Horizon: Integration from the Single European Act to the Maastricht Treaty Introduction to Part III A New Realm of Possibility 149 Chapter 7 Forces of Change and Resistance in 1980s Europe 152 The United States and Globalization: Challenges to Europe 152 Monsieur Jacques Delors Meets Europe 157 Chapter 8 Mrs. Thatcher, Europe, and the Reform of Britain 164 Mrs. Thatcher and Europe 166 Mrs. Thatcher and the Reform of Britain 168 Chapter 9 The Crisis of the Welfare State and the Challenge of Modernization in 1980s Europe 180 New Zealand Experiments 182 Denmark Conserves 184 Sweden’s Beacon Goes Out 188 France Regroups 194 Germany Rests 200 Italy Resurrects Itself 201 Spain Modernizes 208 Reforming the Welfare State 221 Chapter 10 Maastricht Ho! (by Air, Land, or SEA?): The Parameters of Change 228 The SEA and the Maastricht Treaty: Negotiating Frameworks 231 Big Business and the Commission: High-Tech Neocorporatism in Action 237 Competition Policy and the Single Market 249 Chapter 11 Stumbling toward Superstate: The Delorean Agenda 259 The Delors Packet and Regional Policy 262 Contents ix The Social Charter, Imagined Space, and Policy Networking in Brussels 263 The European Monetary Union Examined 269 Political Maastricht 278 Ambitions and Realities: Delors II and Ratification 284 German Unification and the Crisis of 1992 289 Conclusion to Part III Needed: A New Integration Direction 294 IV A False Dawn? Challenge and Misdirection in 199os Europe Introduction to Part IV A New Global Framework 303 Chapter 12 Almost a Road to Nowhere: The EU in Trouble 313 Summits and Scandals 317 Prodi, Nice, and the Breakdown of Governance 329 Plans, Projects, and the Convention on the Future of Europe 340 Chapter 13 No Open-and-Shut Cases: Member-States and the European Community in the 1990s 357 A Finnish Festival 359 The Failing Italian Miracle 366 A Different Dutchman? 374 Chirac to Chirac: France on Hold 382 United Germany: Well-Meaning but Unwise 390 Britain: No Beef Here 399 Chapter 14 Shrinking Enlargement: Betrayal of Pledge or Opportunity in Disguise? 410 EU Enlargement Policy 413 The Accession Countries: The Front-Runners 420 Estonia: New Zealand of the Baltic 422 Hungary: Right Way or Rightist Way? 427 The Polish Question: As Always, Unanswered 431 Chapter 15 The New Market Economy and Europe’s Future 446 The New and the Old in the European Economy 451 The 3G Telecom Debacle 454 Not Yet a Single Financial Market 461 The European Union: An International Market-Conforming Regulatory Agency? 473 Conclusion to Part IV Needed: A New European Union? 480 Envoi 487 Notes 503 Bibliography 547 Index 563 1 The Liberal Project for an Integrated Europe There was a liberal project for an integrated Europe, even one avant la lettre. Its author was the Austrian economist Friedrich A. Hayek.1 He ranks alongside Jean Monnet and many others as one of the founding fathers of the new era. Hayek’s work inspired both Ludwig Erhard, who turned West Germany into the engine and model of European economic growth, and Margaret Thatcher, the moving force behind the Single European Act, which restarted the integration process in the late 1980s, as well as many others who have followed their footsteps. Hayek discovered the logic underlying the integration process. It is as relevant now as ever. Hayek postulated that the competition principle, if allowed to operate, sets in motion a mutually reinforcing reciprocal process in which the market and self- government together reduce interstate conflict and promote economic growth. It is not only Hayek’s devotees and admirers who hold that integration can pro- ceed on the basis of such “negative integration.” The argument has been restated and confirmed by many specialists and practitioners, some of whose work will be discussed in these pages. The result may, however, simply reflect the diffuse and pervasive nature of Hayek’s influence. Not just economists but also political scientists, sociologists, and legal and constitutional scholars are all slowly be- coming at least partly Hayekian, just as by the third quarter of the past century even President Nixon, as he famously announced, was a Keynesian. the legacy of friedrich von hayek Friedrich von Hayek was born at the turn of the century and lived long enough to witness the fall of communism. His active career, begun after World War I, ended with the onset of senility in the mid-1980s. Hayek impressed people when still in his 20s as being serious beyond his years and, at 80, as being remark- ably spry and alert. The sixty intermediate, grayish years of middle age were the most productive period of his life. Hayek was tall and slightly stooped, reserved, somewhat courtly, unmistakably donnish, and spoke English as a second lan- guage with accents that varied according to the time and place of his residence. The placid and unremarkable demeanor masked a personal life not always con- sistent with the image. Such matters are trifling by comparison to Hayek’s ideas. Hayek never held public office but operated instead on (or close to) the intel- lectual plane. A great economist and social scientist, he was also a brilliant 6 Liberal Project for an Integrated Europe 7 promoter of think tanks dedicated both to reviving the tradition of classical lib- eralism internationally and providing guidance to policy makers who shared his views. Hayek’s influence has been both pervasive and enduring – not merely as a technical economist but as a political visionary with a deep understanding of the historical process. His gifts as a publicist and intellectual entrepreneur should not be overlooked in any assessment of his importance in the history of integration. The Mont Pèlerin Society, which he co-founded in 1947, has served as a cen- tral point of diffusion not only for his own views but also for those of related schools influenced by them, such as monetarism, public choice theory, and the new institutional economics.2 In addition, Hayek and other eminent members of the association have founded colonies of classical liberal intellectuals in the United States, throughout Europe, and, above all, in Great Britain. The Insti- tute of Economic Affairs, despite its bland name, became a hotbed of policy formulation for the government of Margaret Thatcher, who – as has since been nearly forgotten – set in motion a new wave of liberal reform into the Euro- pean Community in the early 1980s. The competition directorate (DG IV), the most influential branch of the eventually labyrinthine Commission bureaucracy, became its locus. Hayek also imprinted the thinking of the Freiburg School of so-called ORDO-liberals who devised the famous Soziale Marktwirtschaft (so- cial market economy) associated with Ludwig Erhard and the German economic miracle of the 1950s.
Recommended publications
  • Removing Obstacles on the Path to Economic Freedom1
    Removing Obstacles on the Path to Economic Freedom1 John B. Taylor Mont Pelerin Society Fort Worth, Texas May 22, 2019 My remarks on removing obstacles on the path to economic freedom touch on themes raised at Mont Pelerin Society meetings for many years. But here I emphasize that the obstacles often change their form over time and pop up in surprising ways. I see two basic kinds of obstacles. First are obstacles based on claims that the principle ideas of economic freedom are wrong or do not work. The principle ideas of economic freedom include the rule of law, predictable policies, reliance on markets, attention to incentives, and limitations on government.2 This first kind of obstacle largely promotes the opposite of these principles, arguing that the rule of law should be replaced by arbitrary government actions, that policy predictability is no virtue, that market prices can be replaced by central decrees, that incentives matter little, and that government does not need to be restrained. Many were making such claims at the time that the Mont Pelerin Society was founded in 1947. Communist governments were taking hold. Socialism was creeping up everywhere. “The common objective of those who met at Mont Pelerin was undoubtedly to halt and reverse current political, social, and economic trends toward socialism,” as R. M. Hartwell described the first meeting in his history of the Mont Pelerin Society.3 Despite many successes, these claims have returned today in renewed calls for socialism and criticism of free market capitalism as a way to improved standards of living.
    [Show full text]
  • The Mont Pelerin Society
    A SPECIAL MEETING THE MONT PELERIN SOCIETY JANUARY 15–17, 2020 FROM THE PAST TO THE FUTURE: IDEAS AND ACTIONS FOR A FREE SOCIETY CHAPTER THIRTY-FOUR MAKING THE CASE FOR LIBERTY RUSSELL ROBERTS HOOVER INSTITUTION • STANFORD UNIVERSITY 1 1 MAKING THE CASE FOR LIBERTY Prepared for the January 2020 Mont Pelerin Society Meeting Hoover Institution, Stanford University Russ Roberts John and Jean De Nault Research Fellow Hoover Institution Stanford University [email protected] 1 2 According to many economists and pundits, we are living under the dominion of Milton Friedman’s free market, neoliberal worldview. Such is the claim of the recent book, The Economists’ Hour by Binyamin Applebaum. He blames the policy prescriptions of free- market economists for slower growth, inequality, and declining life expectancy. The most important figure in this seemingly disastrous intellectual revolution? “Milton Friedman, an elfin libertarian…Friedman offered an appealingly simple answer for the nation’s problems: Government should get out of the way.” A similar judgment is delivered in a recent article in the Boston Review by Suresh Naidu, Dani Rodrik, and Gabriel Zucman: Leading economists such as Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman were among the founders of the Mont Pelerin Society, the influential group of intellectuals whose advocacy of markets and hostility to government intervention proved highly effective in reshaping the policy landscape after 1980. Deregulation, financialization, dismantling of the welfare state, deinstitutionalization of labor markets, reduction in corporate and progressive taxation, and the pursuit of hyper-globalization—the culprits behind rising inequalities—all seem to be rooted in conventional economic doctrines.
    [Show full text]
  • The Mont Pelerin Society: a MANDATE RENEWED
    1 The Mont Pelerin Society: A MANDATE RENEWED By Deepak Lal Ladies and Gentlemen, Welcome to this special meeting of the MPS. In this address I would like to explain why it has been called at such short notice and how I hope it provides a renewal of the mandate our founders set for the society.1 After being anointed with the Presidency of this august body in Tokyo (in early September), my wife and I went on to a lecture tour in China. We were in Shanghai on a tour of the magnificent Suzhou industrial estate outside Shanghai, with MPS member Steven Cheung. On the afternoon of the 15th September Steve received a call on his Blackberry that Lehman Brothers had gone into bankruptcy. Steve opined that this marked the end of American capitalism. I thought this somewhat hyperbolic. But, on getting back to London at the end of September, as I was tending my roses, my neighbor, a Thatcherite heart surgeon, said over the hedge that, given the recent events in the capital markets, did I still stand by the views I had expressed in my last book on "Reviving the Invisible Hand".2 I replied that even a severe trade cycle downturn would not undermine the well tested classical liberal principles I had espoused. Though, Gordon Brown might be in trouble having repeatedly congratulated himself for having abolished boom and bust. Two subsequent events shattered this complacency. I had been following a political betting site called Betfair on which some youngsters at the Tokyo MPS meeting were placing bets on a McCain victory.
    [Show full text]
  • Speaking of Liberty
    Speaking of Liberty Llewellyn H. Rockwell, Jr. Patrons The Mises Institute dedicates this volume to all of its generous donors, and in particular wishes to thank these Patrons: Anthony Deden, Christopher P. Condon, Hugh E. Ledbetter, Mr. and Mrs. William W. Massey, Jr., Roger Milliken, Mr. and Mrs. R. Nelson Nash, Stephenson Family Foundation, Mr. and Mrs. Willard Fischer / Fisher Printing, Inc., Douglas E. French, Don Printz, M.D., Frederick L. Maier, James Bailey / James Bailey Foundation, Mr. and Mrs. J.R. Bost, James W. Frevert, Jule R. Herbert, Jr., Julie Lauer-Leonardi, Mr. and Mrs. William Lowndes, III, William S. Morris, III / Morris Communications Corp., Donald Mosby Rembert, top dog™, James M. Rodney, Mr. and Mrs. Joseph P. Schirrick in memory of Jeannette Zummo, Mr. and Mrs. Michael Shaw, Joe Vierra, Robert H. Walker / Walker Die Casting Company ^ Andreas Acavalos, Robert B. Allan, Anonymous, Richard Bleiberg, Dr. V.S. Boddicker, John Hamilton Bolstad, Ronald Bridges, Paul H. Casey, Mr. and Mrs. John C. Cooke, Kerry E. Cutter, Carl A. Davis / Davis-Lynch, Inc., Mr. and Mrs. Charles F. de Ganahl, Eric Englund, Dr. Larry J. Eshelman, Charles Groff, Charley Hardman, Horace H. Harned, Frank W. Heemstra, Jeremy Horpedahl, Dr. and Mrs. Robert D. Hurt, Martin Jungbluth, W. Thomas Kelly, Lucille Lane, Joe R. Lee, John M. Leger, Dr. Floy Lilley, Arnold Lisio, M.D., Arthur L. Loeb, Björn Lundahl, Samuel Medrano, M.D., in honor of Lupe C. Medrano, Joseph Edward Paul Melville, Robert Mish, Brantley I. Newsom, James O’Neill, Mr. and Mrs. Ronald L. Peterson, Robert M.
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • James M. Buchanan Jr. [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Niclas Berggren Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 292-299
    James M. Buchanan Jr. [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Niclas Berggren Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 292-299 Abstract James M. Buchanan Jr. is among the 71 individuals who were awarded the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel between 1969 and 2012. This ideological profile is part of the project called “The Ideological Migration of the Economics Laureates,” which fills the September 2013 issue of Econ Journal Watch. Keywords Classical liberalism, economists, Nobel Prize in economics, ideology, ideological migration, intellectual biography. JEL classification A11, A13, B2, B3 Link to this document http://econjwatch.org/file_download/718/BuchananIPEL.pdf ECON JOURNAL WATCH James M. Buchanan Jr. by Niclas Berggren6 James M. Buchanan (1919–2013) was born in rural Tennessee under rather simple circumstances: “It was a very poor life,” he says (Buchanan 2009, 91). Still, he ended up, in 1986, as a recipient of the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel. The Prize was awarded “for his development of the contractual and constitutional bases for the theory of economic and political decision-making.” Buchanan earned his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Chicago in 1948 and was thereafter a professor at the University of Tennessee, Florida State University, the University of Virginia, UCLA, Virginia Polytechnic Institute, and George Mason University. In spite of his academic accomplishments, Buchanan felt himself to be apart from an established elite—academic, intellectual or political—and he even regarded that elite with suspicion. The attitude can be connected to Buchanan’s ideological convictions and how these changed over the course of his lifetime.
    [Show full text]
  • Rivista Di Scienze Storiche E Sociali Rivista Scientifica Semestrale Fondata Nell’Anno 2015
    Rivista di scienze storiche e sociali Rivista scientifica semestrale fondata nell’anno 2015 www.StoriaLibera.it [email protected] Anno VII (2021), n. 13 ISSN 2421-0269 Direttore Beniamino Di Martino Capo Redattore Rosa Castellano [email protected] Redazione + Maria Rosaria Abagnale Cesarano Michele Arpaia Antonio Caragliu Giovanni Chierchia Bernardo Ferrero Rosa Saviano Lucia Sorrentino Antonino Trunfio Accanto ai redattori, la Redazione si avvale della collaborazione di altri otto coadiutori. Altre informazioni sono sul sito web della rivista. StoriaLibera anno VII (2021), n. 13 Direzione presso Beniamino Di Martino via Motta Carità, 43 80050 Santa Maria la Carità (Napoli) [email protected] Editore Monolateral PO Box 940451 Plano, Texas (USA) 75094 https://monolateral.com Gli elaborati pubblicati su «StoriaLibera» sono sottoposti a controllo di qualità secondo la procedura della peer review in doppio cieco. I contenuti degli articoli sono di esclusiva responsabilità degli autori. Gli autori cedono i propri contributi alla rivista gratuitamente. Anche ogni altro tipo di collaborazione alla rivista è offerta a titolo totalmente volontario e gratuito. I fascicoli della rivista vengono preparati con cadenza semestrale e vengono diffusi on line a gennaio (numero invernale) e a luglio (numero estivo). La data di uscita di ciascun numero è riportata nell’ultima pagina del fascicolo. I testi contenuti nei fascicoli della rivista sono protetti da copyright. La riproduzione, anche parziale, deve essere svolta citando con precisione
    [Show full text]
  • H-Diplo Roundtable, Vol
    2018 H-Diplo Roundtable Editors: Diane Labrosse and Daniel Steinmetz- @HDiplo Jenkins Roundtable and Web Production Editor: George Fujii Roundtable Review Volume XIX, No. 38 (2018) Introduction by Daniel Steinmetz-Jenkins Rev. B (formatting corrections) 1 June 2018 Melinda Cooper. Family Values: Between Neoliberalism and the New Social Conservatism. Cambridge: MIT Press for Zone Books, 2017. ISBN: 9781935408840 (hardcover, $29.95). URL: http://www.tiny.cc/Roundtable-XIX-38 Contents Introduction by Daniel Steinmetz-Jenkins, Yale University ................................................................2 Review by Kristen Loveland, Southern District of New York ..............................................................5 Review by Andrea Muehlebach, University of Toronto ..................................................................... 10 Review by Gabriel N. Rosenberg, Duke University .............................................................................. 15 Review by Charlotte Walker-Said, John Jay College- City University New York ....................... 19 Author’s Response by Melinda Cooper, the University of Sydney ................................................ 25 © 2018 The Authors. Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 United States License. H-Diplo Roundtable Review, Vol. XIX, No. 38 (2018) Introduction by Daniel Steinmetz-Jenkins, Yale University t is often forgotten that in the early days of the Cold War, vital center/consensus liberals were opposed not simply to Communism but also to doom and
    [Show full text]
  • Markets, Firms and Property Rights a Celebration of the Research of Ronald Coase
    Markets, Firms and Property Rights A Celebration of the Research of Ronald Coase Friday, December 4, and Saturday, December 5, 2009 University of Chicago Law School Auditorium This Conference brings together a group of scholars to honor the life and research of Ronald Coase. 2009 marks the 50th anniversary of the publication of Coase’s seminal paper on the Federal Communications Commission. 2010 marks the 50th anniversary of the publication of his paper on “The Problem of Social Cost,” and his 100th birthday. The presentations on this occasion cover specific topics on which Coase’s work has exerted profound influence, including such areas as telecommunications policy, airline regulation and development, environmental economics, economic development, organization of the firm, and general discussions of the questions of transactions costs and social rationality to which he has contributed so much. With Special Thanks The Conference is being organized by Richard A. Epstein of the University of Chicago, Thomas Hazlett of George Mason University, and Roger Noll and Greg Rosston of Stanford University. These papers shall be published in special issues of the Journal of Law and Economics and the Journal of Legal Studies. The public is invited. For additional information, please visit http://iep.gmu.edu/CoaseConference.php. Sponsors John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics at the University of Chicago Law School Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Information Economy Project at George Mason University Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation Milton Friedman Institute for Research in Economics George J. Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State China Center for Economic Research Lynde and Harry Bradley Foundation Participants Gary Becker Zhimin Liao Omri Ben-Shahar Gary Libecap Lee Benham Thomas Merrill Xiaofang Chen Roger Noll Lennon H.T.
    [Show full text]
  • Milton Friedman and Neoliberal Vanguardism
    DOI: 10.1111/1467-8675.12322 ORIGINAL ARTICLE Burying Mont Pèlerin: Milton Friedman and neoliberal vanguardism Victor L. Shammas Department of Sociology and Human Geography, University of Oslo, Oslo, Norway Correspondence Victor L. Shammas, Department of Sociology and Human Geography, PO Box 1096, Blindern, 0317 Oslo, Norway. Email: [email protected] Funding information This research was supported by the Norwegian Research Council (Grant Number 259888). 1 INTRODUCTION “As you know, I have for years been concerned about the fact that the Mont Pèlerin Society has become a large social gathering rather than the kind of intense intellectual community it once was,” Milton Friedman wrote in 1987 to his friend and comrade-in-arms, Arthur Seldon, founder of the Institute for Economic Affairs, a British pro-market think tank. By the second half of the 1980s, the neoliberal trans-Atlantic alliance between Reagan and Thatcher was on a firm footing. The views and proposals of the Mont Pèlerin Society, once marginal and ridiculed in a world domineered by Keynesianism, were now in alignment with the prevailing spirit of the age (Burgin, 2012, pp. 206–207). This moment of unexpected success seemed to afford Friedman, one of the Society's founding members and leading luminaries, the opportunity to muse on past trials: “In 1972, I was in favor of having a big twenty-fifth anniversary celebration and closing the Society down,” Friedman wrote, “in the view that it would be better for a new society to emerge which would have fresh vigor and would be staffed by a new group of people.” Serving as the Society's president between 1970 and 1972, Friedman had come to the belief that the Mont Pèlerin Society had been sapped of its original vigor and resolve.
    [Show full text]
  • The Mont Pelerin Society
    A SPECIAL MEETING THE MONT PELERIN SOCIETY JANUARY 15–17, 2020 FROM THE PAST TO THE FUTURE: IDEAS AND ACTIONS FOR A FREE SOCIETY CHAPTER FIVE MILTON FRIEDMAN: THE EARLY YEARS JENNIFER BURNS HOOVER INSTITUTION • STANFORD UNIVERSITY 11 DRAFT Copyright 2020 Jennifer L. Burns Do not copy, cite, or circulate without author’s permission Milton Friedman: The Early Years1 In April 1947 Milton Friedman embarked upon a “junket to Switzerland ... to save liberalism,” as his colleague George Stigler jokingly put it.2 The two men were among a small group of intellectuals invited to attend the inaugural meeting of the Mont Pelerin Society. Now considered one of the founding institutions of global conservatism in the 20th century, the Mont Pelerin Society was the brainchild of Austrian economist F.A. Hayek. Once a widely respected scholar, Hayek’s stock had fallen as economists turned to Keynesian and mathematical approaches in the aftermath of the Great Depression. Hayek was now famous not for his economic analysis, but for his 1944 crie de coeur against state planning, The Road to Serfdom, penned in London as German bombs rained from the sky. But now Hayek wanted to move from writing books to starting institutions that could shape the political climate. Hayek recognized that liberalism – the creed of limited government and open markets in which he deeply believed – had lost political purchase. In an era of social democracy, not to mention communism and fascism, the 19th century ideals of republican government seemed bound for extinction. Were it to survive, liberalism needed to be re-thought, top to bottom.
    [Show full text]
  • Neoliberalism, Capital Accumulation, and Austerity in Academia, the Term
    Neoliberalism, Capital Accumulation, and Austerity Mehdi S. Shariati, Ph.D. Professor, Economics, Sociology and Geography Kansas City Kansas City Community College Abstract Recent crisis in global capitalism has once again brought to the fore major structural contradictions and the consequences of these contradictions are reflected in the massive dislocation of the economy, growing number of (the) poor, concentration of wealth in the hands of a few around the globe, indebtedness, rampant speculation and an unprecedented concentration of financial capital at the expense of productive sector of the economy. The austerity program by which the global working class must endure has generated much social protests including "occupy Wall Street," but with very little discussion of an alternative to the current global system. In academia, the term descriptive of finance capital’s policy prescription is “neoliberalism.” Yet the term not only has created confusion since in the North American context, liberals and neoliberals have always been viewed as left leaning people and not the free marketers and market fundamentalists. Neoliberalism often refers to a set of economic policies designed for intense and accelerated capital accumulation. Rarely the discussion of the process of intense capital accumulation includes a restructuring of society and social institutions as a precondition for the successful implementation of the policies. This paper is an attempt to add to the discussion by pointing out the indispensability of the practice of social imperialism in the process of reproducing the hegemonic structure and effective implementation of the policy. Reaction to the evolving socio-economic and political events has been one of the greatest preoccupation in the social and political sciences as a habit and of necessity.
    [Show full text]