For the Love of Contract

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

For the Love of Contract Tulsa Law Review Volume 51 Issue 2 Spring 2016 For the Love of Contract Zvi H. Triger Haim Striks School of Law Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.utulsa.edu/tlr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Zvi H. Triger, For the Love of Contract, 51 Tulsa L. Rev. 407 (2016). Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.utulsa.edu/tlr/vol51/iss2/16 This Book Review is brought to you for free and open access by TU Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Tulsa Law Review by an authorized editor of TU Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Triger: For the Love of Contract 3/13/1611:15 PM FOR THE LOVE OF CONTRACT * Zvi H. Triger MARTHA M. ERTMAN, LOVE’S PROMISES: HOW FORMAL AND INFORMAL CONTRACTS SHAPE ALL KINDS OF FAMILIES (BEACON PRESS 2015). PP. 280. HARDCOVER $ 26.95. I. INTRODUCTION Martha Ertman’s new book, Love’s Promises: How Formal and Informal Contracts Shape All Kinds of Families, explores the role of contracts within the family.1 It shows that contracts shape today’s families and argues that family law should acknowledge that and recognize such contracts. This review essay addresses the dramatic paradigm shifts that have been occurring in contract law and family law in the last decades as a response to technological developments and to people’s resourcefulness, which enable them to reimagine the family and create new forms of families. It presents and analyzes those shifts within their historical and socio-legal contexts. Part II of this essay presents the book’s terminology, and its main arguments. Dis- tinguishing between plan A and plan B families, and between contracts and deals, Ertman urges readers—whether members of plan B families, lawyers, judges, policymakers or others—to reimagine family law and redesign it so that it better protects families and their members. Part III discusses Ertman’s use of contracts within families against the backdrop of classical contract theory and its aversion to all things domestic. It explores the notion that housework has been considered, in Western thought, as a gift, and that love and contracts have been construed as mutually exclusive. Part IV argues that Ertman’s book should encourage us to think of Families’ Laws instead of Family Law, because there is no such thing as a single family model. The law should acknowledge the diversity of family models instead of tailoring itself to a single “Reasonable Family” model, as it has been doing since its early days. * Associate Professor of Law, The Haim Striks School of Law, The College of Management, Rishon Le Zion, Israel. I am grateful to Linda McClain for her insightful comments and suggestions. 1. MARTHA M. ERTMAN, LOVE’S PROMISES: HOW FORMAL AND INFORMAL CONTRACTS SHAPE ALL KINDS OF FAMILIES (2015). 407 Published by TU Law Digital Commons, 2015 1 Tulsa Law Review, Vol. 51 [2015], Iss. 2, Art. 16 TRIGER_3.13.16 (DO NOT DELETE) 3/13/16 11:15 PM 408 TULSA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 51:407 Part V discusses the book’s methodology, and in particular its use of memoir and more traditional academic scholarship, and assesses its unique contribution. II. RECOGNIZING PLAN B FAMILIES: THE BOOK’S MAIN THEMES AND ARGUMENTS Love’s Promises focuses on what Ertman calls “Plan B families,”2 by contrast to “Plan A families,” that is the more traditional (and common) family, comprised of a mother and a father who are married to each other, and children that are genetically related to both of them. The term “Plan B families,” Ertman writes, “covers a wide variety of uncommon families, from repro tech [assisted reproductive technology] and adoption to cohabita- tion.”3 Under this umbrella she includes same-sex couples (whether married or not), single parents, and families with more than two parents (like Ertman’s own family). The new language that this book suggests—Plan A/Plan B—is designed to help us think about uncommon families as exceptions to the gen- eral rule instead of unnatural or inferior. “Plan A” is what’s common: more than nine out of ten kids are raised by their genetic parents, marriage is the most common family form, and most people are straight. But “common” is not the same as better. When someone veers toward the road less traveled, I call it “Plan B.”4 Another key distinction this book utilizes is the one between contracts, which are agreements that courts enforce, and deals, which are agreements that are binding, but are legally unenforceable.5 Deals are what social relations are based upon on an everyday basis, but they are “just too small or vague to bring before a judge when they are breached[,]”6 and people do not expect to sue or be sued over breaches related to deals. “I pay the bills and you do the grocery shopping”7 is an example of an everyday deal between partners, roommates, or spouses. But we also make deals with friends (we share class notes if one of us is sick and cannot make it to class), and see them as binding, although not legally. That means if my classmate refuses to share her contracts notes with me from the class I had missed because I was lying sick in bed that day, despite our pact to cover for each other when we cannot come to class, I will not sue her (unless I am completely devoid of any social skills), but will consider myself exempt from sharing my own notes if she ever has to miss class. This is how deals work—the enforcement mechanism is social, not legal. Social norms such as mutuality and trust, rather than the law, make deals meaningful and binding. 2. Id. at xiv. 3. Id. 4. Id. 5. Id. at xii-xiii. 6. ERTMAN, supra note 1, at xiii. 7. Id. https://digitalcommons.law.utulsa.edu/tlr/vol51/iss2/16 2 Triger: For the Love of Contract TRIGER_3.13.16 (DO NOT DELETE) 3/13/16 11:15 PM 2016] FOR THE LOVE OF CONTRACT 409 The main argument of the book is that families of all types are shaped by both con- tracts and deals, that contracts help create and maintain families, and that they are espe- cially important for Plan B families.8 As Ertman writes, “[c]ontracts and deals allowed me to become one of three parents—all gay—raising a beloved boy named Walter.”9 Moreover, contracts, if properly thought out and drafted, can also help in the unfor- tunate situations of break ups, and assist the parties in avoiding damaging and acrimonious legal disputes. Ertman calls those clauses for rainy days “jerk insurance” clauses.10 They are known also as “Ulysses contracts” among behavioral economists.11 As Ertman ex- plains, “a Ulysses contract strikes a deal between your present self and your future self, binding your future self not to do something stupid or self-destructive.”12 Similarly, a “jerk insurance” clause, such as an inconvenient and costly choice of law clause in the contract, makes it so cumbersome to litigate conflicts that the parties will be likely to choose a more collaborative way to resolve any issues that arise between them.13 This leads to the other important theme explored in the book: the connection between contracts and love, which will be discussed in Part II of this essay. Ertman’s argument joins a long strand of feminist scholarship of contract law that has rejected the classical view of contracts and love as mutually exclusive.14 As I mentioned above, Ertman shows how contracts can secure love and be the product of love (the “jerk insurance” clause being one of the means to remind the fighting parties of the love that leads them to sign the contract and make the deals in the first place).15 There are two aspects of the family that are explored in the book, and it is organized around them: Part I (chapters 2-5) explores Plan B parenthood, and Part II (chapters 6-9) discusses Plan B partnership. Both parts show how diverse families are (in Ertman’s own words, “love comes in different packages”),16 and therefore how important it is to release family law from its fixation on one model, namely the marital heterosexual model, or the Plan A model. Family law is increasingly recognizing that,17 but it has much more to offer in terms of accommodating and promoting Plan B families. The book’s goal is, among other things, to unleash law’s full potential in this regard. Plan B parenthood is achieved either by technological (reproductive technologies) or legal (adoption) means. Both ways are alternatives to the sexual relations between hus- band and wife, which create Plan A parenthood. Plan B parenthood is varied: from heter- osexual couples who cannot conceive, to LGBT and single women who need gamete do- nations, and gay men who also need gestational surrogacy in order to become fathers. All these forms require contracts: between the intended parents (if they are more than one); 8. Id. at xi-xii. 9. Id. at xv. 10. Id. at 167. 11. ERTMAN, supra note 1, at 167. 12. Id. See also IAN AYRES, CARROTS AND STICKS 15 (2010). 13. ERTMAN, supra note 1, at 167. 14. See infra Part II. 15. ERTMAN, supra note 1, at 167. 16. Id. at 109. 17. Id. Published by TU Law Digital Commons, 2015 3 Tulsa Law Review, Vol. 51 [2015], Iss. 2, Art. 16 TRIGER_3.13.16 (DO NOT DELETE) 3/13/16 11:15 PM 410 TULSA LAW REVIEW [Vol.
Recommended publications
  • Training Contracts, Employee Turnover, and the Returns from Firm-Sponsored General Training
    DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 10835 Training Contracts, Employee Turnover, and the Returns from Firm-Sponsored General Training Mitchell Hoffman Stephen V. Burks JUNE 2017 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 10835 Training Contracts, Employee Turnover, and the Returns from Firm-Sponsored General Training Mitchell Hoffman University of Toronto and NBER Stephen V. Burks University of Minnesota, Morris and IZA JUNE 2017 Any opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but IZA takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The IZA Institute of Labor Economics is an independent economic research institute that conducts research in labor economics and offers evidence-based policy advice on labor market issues. Supported by the Deutsche Post Foundation, IZA runs the world’s largest network of economists, whose research aims to provide answers to the global labor market challenges of our time. Our key objective is to build bridges between academic research, policymakers and society. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author. IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Schaumburg-Lippe-Straße 5–9 Phone: +49-228-3894-0 53113 Bonn, Germany Email: [email protected] www.iza.org IZA DP No. 10835 JUNE 2017 ABSTRACT Training Contracts, Employee Turnover, and the Returns from Firm-Sponsored General Training* Firms may be reluctant to provide general training if workers can quit and use their gained skills elsewhere.
    [Show full text]
  • Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law
    Columbia Law School Scholarship Archive Faculty Scholarship Faculty Publications 2003 Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law Alan Schwartz Robert E. Scott Columbia Law School, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.columbia.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Contracts Commons Recommended Citation Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law, 113 YALE L. J. 541 (2003). Available at: https://scholarship.law.columbia.edu/faculty_scholarship/339 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Publications at Scholarship Archive. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Scholarship Archive. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Article Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law Alan Schwartz* and Robert E. Scottt* CONTENTS I. IN TROD U CTION ................................................................................. 543 II. JUSTIFYING AN EFFICIENCY THEORY OF CONTRACT ........................ 550 A . W hat Firms M axim ize .................................................................. 550 B. Why the State Should Help Firms ................................................ 555 III. THE ENFORCEMENT FUNCTION ........................................................ 556 A. Enforcement Often Is Unnecessary.............................................. 557 B. EncouragingRelation-Specific Investment .................................. 559 C.
    [Show full text]
  • The Federal Trade Commission and Online Consumer Contracts
    SMITH – FINAL THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION AND ONLINE CONSUMER CONTRACTS Hilary Smith Consumer contracts have long posed a challenge for traditional contract enforcement regimes. With the rise in quick online transactions involving clickwrap and browsewrap contracts, these challenges only become more pressing. This Note identifies the problems inherent in the current system and explores proposals and past attempts to improve online consumer contract interpretation and enforcement. Ultimately, this Note identifies the Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) as an appropriate and effective agency to provide the much-needed change to online consumer contract enforcement. Based upon its authority under Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act to regulate unfair business practices, the broad discretion that Congress has afforded the FTC, and its successful incursion into the related field of online privacy law, the FTC is uniquely situated to promulgate a new online consumer contracting regime. This Note illustrates the basis and precedent for such a step and explores the form and effects of FTC involvement in online consumer contracts. I. Introduction ............................................................... 513 II. Background on End User License Agreements and Consumer Contracts .................................................. 514 A. Impact of Online Contracting on Consumer Contracts ............................................................. 514 B. Problems with Online Consumer Contracts ....... 517 J.D. Candidate 2017, Columbia Law School; B.A. 2014, Columbia University. Many thanks to Professor Robert Scott for his guidance throughout the research and writing process. Additional thanks to the staff and editors of the Columbia Business Law Review for their assistance in preparing this Note for publication. SMITH – FINAL No. 2:512] THE FTC AND ONLINE CONSUMER CONTRACTS 513 III.
    [Show full text]
  • 4000 Contract Law: General Theories
    4000 CONTRACT LAW: GENERAL THEORIES Richard Craswell Professor of Law, Stanford Law School © Copyright 1999 Richard Craswell Abstract When contracts are incomplete, the law must rely on default rules to resolve any issues that have not been explicitly addressed by the parties. Some default rules (called ‘majoritarian’ or ‘market-mimicking’) are designed to be left in place by most parties, and thus are chosen to reflect an efficient allocation of rights and duties. Others (called ‘information-forcing’ or ‘penalty’ default rules) are designed not to be left in place, but rather to encourage the parties themselves to explicitly provide some other resolution; these rules thus aim to encourage an efficient contracting process. This chapter describes the issues raised by such rules, including their application to heterogeneous markets and to separating and pooling equilibria; it also briefly discusses some non- economic theories of default rules. Finally, this chapter also discusses economic and non-economic theories about the general question of why contracts should be enforced at all. JEL classification: K12 Keywords: Contracts, Incomplete Contracts, Default Rules 1. Introduction This chapter describes research bearing on the general aspects of contract law. Most research in law and economics does not explicitly address these general aspects, but instead proceeds directly to analyze particular rules of contract law, such as the remedies for breach. That body of research is described below in Chapters 4100 through 4800. There is, however, some scholarship on the general nature of contract law’s ‘default rules’, or the rules that define the parties’ obligations in the absence of any explicit agreement to the contrary.
    [Show full text]
  • Module 4: Moral Hazard - Linear Contracts
    Module 4: Moral Hazard - Linear Contracts Information Economics (Ec 515) George Georgiadis · A principal employs an agent. ◦ Timing: ◦ 1. The principal o↵ers a linear contract of the form w (q)=↵ + βq. – ↵ is the salary, β is the bonus rate. 2. The agent chooses whether the accept or reject the contract. – If the agent accepts it, then goto t =3. – If the agent rejects it, then he receives his outside option U, the principal receives profit 0, and the game ends. 3. The agent chooses action / e↵ort a A [0, ]. 2 ⌘ 1 4. Output q = a + " is realized, where " (0,σ2) ⇠N 5. The principal pays the agent, and the parties’ payo↵s are realized. The principal is risk neutral. His profit function is ◦ E [q w (q)] − The agent is risk averse. His utility function is ◦ r(w(q) c(a)) U (w, a)=E e− − − ⇥ ⇤ with a2 c (a)=c 2 Rationality assumptions: ◦ 1. Upon observing the contract w ( ), the agent chooses his action to maximize his · expected utility. 1 2. The principal, anticipating (1), chooses the contract w ( ) to maximize his expected · profit. First Best Benchmark: Suppose the principal could choose the action a. ◦ – We call this benchmark the first best or the efficient outcome. – Equivalent to say that the agent’s action is verifiable or contractible. Principal solves: ◦ max E [a + ✏ w (q)] a,w(q) − r(w(q) c(a)) s.t. E e− − U Individual Rationality (IR) − ≥ ⇥ ⇤ Solution approach: ◦ rx rEx[x] – Jensen’s inequality = Ex [ e− ] e− ) − – Because the principal chooses the action, optimal wage must be independent of q; i.e., w (q)=↵ – Because a higher w (q) decreases the principal’s profit and increases the agent’s payo↵, (IR) must bind.
    [Show full text]
  • Incomplete Contracts and the Theory of Contract Design
    Case Western Reserve Law Review Volume 56 Issue 1 Article 9 2005 Incomplete Contracts and the Theory of Contract Design Robert E. Scott George G. Triantis Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/caselrev Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Robert E. Scott and George G. Triantis, Incomplete Contracts and the Theory of Contract Design, 56 Case W. Rsrv. L. Rev. 187 (2005) Available at: https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/caselrev/vol56/iss1/9 This Symposium is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Journals at Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Case Western Reserve Law Review by an authorized administrator of Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. INCOMPLETE CONTRACTS AND THE THEORY OF CONTRACT DESIGN t Robert E. Scott George G. Triantist We are delighted to accept this invitation to write a short essay on the economic theory of incomplete contracts and to illuminate its cur- rent and potential impact on the legal analysis of contracts and con- tract law. Economic contract theory has made significant inroads in legal scholarship over the past fifteen years, and this is a good time to take stock of its strengths and weaknesses. Several recent publications in the Yale Law Journalhave offered evaluations of the contributions of contract theory.' In this essay, we offer our opinion as to its future path in legal scholarship.2 In particular, we suggest that economic contract theory should incorporate a more textured understanding of the process for judicial enforcement of contracts.
    [Show full text]
  • “Turning the Social Contract Inside Out: Neoliberal Governance and Human Capital in Two
    “Turning the Social Contract Inside Out: Neoliberal Governance and Human Capital in Two Days, One Night” Robert E. Watkins, PhD Associate Professor of Political Science and Cultural Studies Columbia College Chicago For Presentation at the Annual Meeting of The Western Political Science Association San Diego, California March 24-27, 2016 Please do not cite without permission of the author (rwatkins[at]colum.edu) Introduction In place of the social contractarian promise—that the political aggregate (or an authorized precipitate of it) will secure the individual against life-threatening danger from without and within—individual homo economicus may now be legitimately sacrificed to macroeconomic imperatives. Instead of being secured or protected, the responsibilized citizen tolerates insecurity, deprivation, and extreme exposure to maintain the competitive positioning, growth, or credit rating of the nation as firm. Wendy Brown, Undoing the Demos Film critic and scholar Girish Shambu finds an increased willingness to critique capitalism in mainstream media and culture (2015). Films dealing the 2008 financial and housing crisis like The Big Short (2015), 99 Homes (2015), and Money Monster (2016) approach neoliberalism through the lens of headline narratives about money, credit, and houses as they try to bring into focus a large and complex system, particularly in the American context. Approaching the neoliberal economy from a different perspective than these other recent releases, the 2014 film from the Dardenne brothers Two Days, One Night (2014) tells an altogether smaller and symptomatic, but no less significant story that focuses on the fate of one woman’s job in one particular company over the course of one weekend.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Analysis of Contract Law After Three Decades: Success Or Failure? Eric A
    University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Coase-Sandor Working Paper Series in Law and Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics Economics 2002 Economic Analysis of Contract Law after Three Decades: Success or Failure? Eric A. Posner Follow this and additional works at: https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/law_and_economics Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Eric Posner, "Economic Analysis of Contract Law after Three Decades: Success or Failure?" (John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics Working Paper No. 146, 2002). This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics at Chicago Unbound. It has been accepted for inclusion in Coase-Sandor Working Paper Series in Law and Economics by an authorized administrator of Chicago Unbound. For more information, please contact [email protected]. CHICAGO JOHN M. OLIN LAW & ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER NO. 146 (2D SERIES) Economic Analysis of Contract Law after Three Decades: Success or Failure? Eric A. Posner THE LAW SCHOOL THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO This paper can be downloaded without charge at: The Chicago Working Paper Series Index: http://www.law.uchicago.edu/Lawecon/index.html The Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=304977 Economic Analysis of Contract Law After Three Decades: Success or Failure? Eric A. Posner1 Abstract: Law and economics has failed to produce plausible descriptive theories of contract doctrines. This paper documents these failures and suggests that they are due to a methodological problem involving the concept of transaction costs. If transaction costs refer to writing or information costs, then rational individuals would agree to complex contracts that are not in fact observed, and contract law would, for the most part, have no other function than that of specifically enforcing contracts.
    [Show full text]
  • World Bank Document
    Public Disclosure Authorized 2 -.: Public Disclosure Authorized ?,...,,.LC! :I. :;;.;;her:, ar.8 Joseph E. Stic1i.t~ Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized WAGE RIGIDITY, IMPLICIT CONTRACTS, AVD ECONOMIC EFFICIEKCY: ARE MARKET WGES TOO FLEXIBLE?* David M. Kewbery Develophent Research Department The World Bank and Joseph E. Stiglitz Department of Economics Princeton University August 1982 Revised June 1983 . &Preliminary and Confidential: Not for quotation or attribution wtthout prior ~leciilci~l~eir~u LIZ dutnars. ;'ie;js exp;~,,cld d:~:i;c;e of Th,e ~arhcr-,J~Z 33 not necessarily reflect those oathe World aank or Princeton University. lie - are indebted to Richard Arnott,$ostas Azariadis, Sandy Grossman, Oliver hut * and Arthur Hosios. a m WAGE RIGIDITY, IbIPLICIT CONTRACTS, AND ECONOYIC EFFICIENCY: ARE MARKET WAGES TOO FLEXIBLE? Abstract The analysis of implicit contracts between risk-averse workers and risk-neutral firms must recognize that (i) the contract is implicit, not explicit, (ii) it may only be conditioned on observable variables, and (iii) . there are limits to contract complexity. If contracts are perfectly flexible than neither the constraint of enforceability nor observability result in unemp:oyment. However, even with perfect enforceability and flexibility, linitations on con2racc flexibility may generate unemployment. Finally, even \ with flexible enforceable contracts anti no unemployment the market equilibrium is inefficient. We construct some simple general equilibrium models and explore the consequences of restrictions, on the set of feasible contracts, at the same time comment!ag on the present state of implicit contract theory. The implicit contract theory of wages argues that workers are -re risk averse than firms, and that firms will therefore find it less costly to hire labour if they provide some degree of income insurance against fluctuations in demand which would otherwise lead to fluctuations in the demand price of labour.
    [Show full text]
  • Topics in Microeconomics ECON 5210 ( Part II $ Contract Theory )
    Topics in Microeconomics ECON 5210 ( Part II - Contract Theory ) Tapas Kundu & Tore Nilssen University of Oslo Spring Semester 2009 Kundu & Nilssen (UiO) Contract Theory Spring Semester 2009 1 / 28 Private information on I on what the agent does (hidden actions) I on who the agent is (hidden information) Information and sequence of actions I Adverse Selection models : F Screening - The un-informed party (UP), who is imperfectly informed about the informed party (IP), moves …rst F Signaling - Same informational situation as before, but IP moves …rst I Moral Hazard models : UP, who is imperfectly informed about IP’s action, moves …rst Introduction Introduction Strategic interaction between privately informed agents I Inadequacy of general equilibrium set up Kundu & Nilssen (UiO) Contract Theory Spring Semester 2009 2 / 28 Information and sequence of actions I Adverse Selection models : F Screening - The un-informed party (UP), who is imperfectly informed about the informed party (IP), moves …rst F Signaling - Same informational situation as before, but IP moves …rst I Moral Hazard models : UP, who is imperfectly informed about IP’s action, moves …rst Introduction Introduction Strategic interaction between privately informed agents I Inadequacy of general equilibrium set up Private information on I on what the agent does (hidden actions) I on who the agent is (hidden information) Kundu & Nilssen (UiO) Contract Theory Spring Semester 2009 2 / 28 Introduction Introduction Strategic interaction between privately informed agents I Inadequacy
    [Show full text]
  • Lectures in Contract Theory1
    Lectures in Contract Theory1 Steve Tadelis and Ilya Segal2 UC Berkeley and Stanford University Preliminary and Incomplete December 2005 1These notes were prepared for a second year graduate course in Contract theory at Stanford University (Econ 282/291) and UC Berkeley (Econ 206). They are preliminary and incomplete. Thanks also to Debbie Johnston for typing the first version and to Scott Hemphill for excellent research assistance. 2Copyright c 1998-2005 by Steven Tadelis and Ilya Segal. All rights reserved. No part of these° notes may be reproduced in any form by any electronuic or mechanical means without writen permission from the author. Contents IIntroduction 5 0.1Tradewithsmallnumbersofagents............... 6 0.2 Incentives ............................. 7 0.3BoundedRationality....................... 8 0.4Contracts,Mechanisms,Institutions............... 8 II Hidden Information 10 1 The Principal-Agent Model 12 1.1Setup................................ 12 1.1.1 Preferences........................ 12 1.1.2 Contracting........................ 13 1.2Single-CrossingandtheMonotonicityofChoice........ 13 1.3TheFullInformationBenchmark................ 16 1.4TheRevelationPrinciple..................... 18 1.5SolutionwithTwoTypes..................... 20 1.5.1 ManyDiscreteTypes................... 24 1.6SolutionwithaContinuumofTypes.............. 25 1.6.1 TheRelaxedProblem................... 28 1.6.2 Whattodoifmonotonicitybinds(technical)...... 31 1.7ApplicationsoftheModel.................... 32 1.7.1 SecondDegreePriceDiscrimination..........
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Incentive Contract with Endogenous Monitoring Technology
    Theoretical Economics 15 (2020), 1135–1173 1555-7561/20201135 Optimal incentive contract with endogenous monitoring technology Anqi Li Department of Economics, Washington University in St. Louis Ming Yang Fuqua School of Business, Duke University Recent technology advances have enabled firms to flexibly process and analyze sophisticated employee performance data at a reduced and yet significant cost. We develop a theory of optimal incentive contracting where the monitoring tech- nology that governs the above procedure is part of the designer’s strategic plan- ning. In otherwise standard principal–agent models with moral hazard, we allow the principal to partition agents’ performance data into any finite categories, and to pay for the amount of information the output signal carries. Through analy- sis of the trade-off between giving incentives to agents and saving the monitoring cost, we obtain characterizations of optimal monitoring technologies such as in- formation aggregation, strict monotone likelihood ratio property, likelihood ratio– convex performance classification, group evaluation in response to rising moni- toring costs, and assessing multiple task performances according to agents’ en- dogenous tendencies to shirk. We examine implications of these results for work- force management and firms’ internal organizations. Keywords. Incentive contract, endogenous monitoring technology. JEL classification. D86, M5, M15. 1. Introduction Recent technology advances have enabled firms to flexibly process and analyze sophisti- cated employee performance data at a reduced and yet significant cost. Speech analytics software, natural language processing tools, and cloud-based systems are increasingly used to convert hard-to-process contents into succinct and meaningful performance ratings such as “satisfactory” and “unsatisfactory” (Murff et al.
    [Show full text]