Downloaded from Brill.Com09/30/2021 07:13:43AM Via Free Access 20 Van Der Linden Subordinates

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Downloaded from Brill.Com09/30/2021 07:13:43AM Via Free Access 20 Van Der Linden Subordinates chapter 1 Workers and Revolutions A Historical Paradox Marcel van der Linden The concept of “revolution”, which derives from astrology and astronomy, be- came more widely known after Copernicus published De revolutionibus orbium coelestium in 1543, in which he used the term to describe both the rotation of the planets around the sun and that of the Earth around its axis.1 In the three centuries that followed, huge social changes became increasingly described as revolutions.2 Often, such changes encompassed all aspects of life and were supposed to lead to a better future.3 Distinguishing different aspects of revolu- tions easily followed from this: economic, political or social. The term “social revolution” first appeared in a book titled Considérations sur la révolution so- ciale, published by the Comte de Ferrand in 1794.4 In this period, revolution was regarded mainly as a conflict between the aristocracy and the increasingly class- conscious bourgeoisie.5 Between 1831 and 1848, German intellectuals comparing recent develop- ments in different parts of Western Europe then discovered that the working classes could also figure in revolutions. In 1842, the economist Lorenz von Stein published his book The Socialism and Communism of Contemporary France, in which he argued that the rising industrial society either made workers ob- stinate and malicious or transformed them into dull instruments and servile 1 I would like to thank Pepijn Brandon and Peyman Jafari for their helpful comments on this article’s first draft. 2 The first transition identified as a “revolution” was probably the upheaval in the North Ger- man town of Emden in 1595. See Die “Emder Revolution” von 1595, ed. Hajo van Lengen (Au- rich: Ostfriesische Landschaft, 1995). 3 Reinhart Koselleck et al., “Revolution. Rebellion, Aufruhr, Bürgerkrieg”, in Geschichtliche Grundbegriffe. Historisches Lexikon zur politisch- sozialen Sprache in Deutschland, vol. 5, ed. Otto Brunner, Werner Conze and Reinhart Koselleck (Stuttgart: Klett- Cotta, 1984), 653– 788, esp. 655. 4 Antoine François Claude Comte de Ferrand, Considérations sur la révolution sociale (Lon- don: no publisher, 1794). 5 See e.g. Ralph Miliband, “Barnave: A Case of Bourgeois Class Consciousness”, in Aspects of History and Class Consciousness, ed. István Mészáros (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1971), 22– 48. © Marcel van der Linden, 2021 | DOI:10.1163/9789004440395_003 This is an open access chapter distributed under the terms of the CC-BY-NC 4.0 license.Marcel van der Linden - 9789004440395 Downloaded from Brill.com09/30/2021 07:13:43AM via free access 20 van der Linden subordinates. He considered personal and hereditary property to be the root cause of this decline of the working classes, since it resulted in the dominant power of some and the unfreedom of others. However, a proletarian revolution was not inexorable. Von Stein proposed a reformist political strategy in which the state guides the redistribution of economic resources so as to prevent class polarization.6 In late 1843 or early 1844, Karl Marx characterized the proletariat as: “a class with radical chains, a class in civil society which is not a class of civil society, an estate which is the dissolution of all estates, a sphere which has a universal character by its universal suffering and claims no particular right because no particular wrong, but wrong generally, is perpetrated against it”. The proletariat was the “all- round antithesis” to existing society, which is “the complete loss of man and hence can win itself only through the complete re- winning of man”.7 Gradually, the nature of this proletarian self- emancipation became clearer to Marx. In a fragment from around 1845, written jointly with Friedrich Engels, he asserted that the abolition of bourgeois society would require the collective appropriation of all productive forces. This could be effected only through “a revolution, in which, on the one hand, the power of the earlier mode of produc- tion and intercourse and social organisation is overthrown, and, on the other hand, there develops the universal character and the energy of the proletariat, which are required to accomplish the appropriation, and the proletariat more- over rids itself of everything that still clings to it from its previous position in society”.8 Moses Hess, the philosopher who together with Karl Marx, Friedrich Engels and others worked on The German Ideology, wrote in 1847 about the “Consequences of a Revolution of the Proletariat”.9 Engels noted in Principles of Communism, published the same year: “In all probability, the proletarian revolution will transform existing society gradually and will be able to abolish private property only when the means of production are available in sufficient quantity”.10 6 Lorenz von Stein, Der Socialismus und Communismus des heutigen Frankreichs: Ein Beitrag zur Zeitgeschichte (Leipzig: Wigand, 1842); Joachim Singelmann and Peter Singelmann, “Lorenz von Stein and the Paradigmatic Bifurcation of Social Theory in the Nineteenth Century”, British Journal of Sociology 37, no. 3 (1986): 431– 452. 7 Karl Marx, “A Contribution to the Critique of Hegel’s Philosophy of Right”, in Marx Engels Collected Works [hereafter mecw], vol. 3 (1975), 186, translation corrected. 8 Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, “The German Ideology”, mecw, vol. 5 (1976), 88. 9 Moses Hess, “Consequences of a Revolution of the Proletariat”, in The Holy History of Mankind and Other Writings, Moses Hess, translated and edited by Shlomo Avineri (Cam- bridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004), 128– 135. 10 mecw, vol. 6, 684 (§ 17). Marcel van der Linden - 9789004440395 Downloaded from Brill.com09/30/2021 07:13:43AM via free access Workers and Revolutions 21 The discovery of radical labour struggle of course related directly to its growing visibility in the three most important countries in Western Europe. Between 1831 and 1834 the uprising by silk workers in Lyon had instigated a general strike, unique for that era, as well as two very bloody confrontations with the authorities.11 In England, the proletarian Chartist movement for po- litical reform had an enormous impact from 1838 onwards,12 and in 1844, the rebellion of weavers in Peterswaldau and Langenbielau (Silesia) revealed that the working class was also starting to awaken in Germany.13 1 The Marx- Hess- Engels Hypothesis Marx, Hess, Engels and others believed that the rise of capitalism would bring about continuous expansion of the working class in the decades ahead. Labour would therefore become ever more important in future revolutions, which would soon result in the subversion of capitalist relations. This view seemed to find resounding confirmation in the revolutions of 1848– 1849 in France, Cen- tral Europe and other regions, which explicitly shifted the focus to the working class as an emergent – albeit not yet dominant – vector in the social and polit- ical field of forces.14 Was this perception accurate? 11 Fernand Rude, Les Révoltes des canuts, novembre 1831- avril 1834 (Paris: Maspero, 1982); Maurice Moissonnier, La Révolte des canuts, Lyon, novembre 1831 (Paris: ed. Sociales Messidor, 1958). The best monograph in English is Robert J. Bezucha, The Lyon Uprising of 1834: Social and Political Conflict in the Early July Monarchy (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1974). 12 The body of literature about the Chartists is vast. See e.g., Dorothy Thompson, The Chartists: Popular Politics in the Industrial Revolution (London: Temple Smith, 1984); Malcolm Chase, Chartism: A New History (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2007). Marx and Engels were in contact with a few Chartist leaders. See e.g. Peter Cadogan, “Harney and Engels”, International Review of Social History 10, no. 1 (1965): 66– 104; Henry Collins and Chimen Abramsky, Karl Marx and the British Labour Movement (London: Macmillan, 1965). 13 Lutz Kroneberg and Rolf Schloesser, Weber- Revolte 1844: Der schlesische Weberaufstand im Spiegel der zeitgenössischen Publizistik und Literatur (Cologne: C. W. Leske, 1979); Christina von Hodenberg, Aufstand der Weber: Die Revolte von 1844 und ihr Aufstieg zum Mythos (Bonn: Dietz, 1997). 14 Extensive information appears in the journal La révolution de 1848, published in France since 1904. Bulletin de la Société d’Histoire de la Révolution de 1848, later renamed Revue d’histoire du xixe siècle. Studies focusing explicitly on the role of the workers in 1848 include Rémi Gossez, Les ouvriers de Paris. Vol. 1: L’organisation, 1848– 1851. Preface by Jacques Godechot (La Roche- sur- Yon: Imprimerie Centrale de l’Ouest, 1968); Maria Grazia Meriggi, L’invenzione della classe operaia: Conflitti di lavoro, organizzazione del lavoro e della società in Francia intorno al 1848 (Milan: Franco Angeli, 2002); P. H. Noyes, Marcel van der Linden - 9789004440395 Downloaded from Brill.com09/30/2021 07:13:43AM via free access 22 van der Linden In answering this question, I apply the broad concept of the working class as elaborated in Global Labour History in recent years. In this perception, the history of capitalist labour must encompass all forms of physically or eco- nomically coerced commodification of labour power: wage labourers, slaves, sharecroppers, convict labourers, and so on – plus all the labour that creates such commodified labour or regenerates it; that is, parental labour, household labour, care labour and subsistence labour. This broad description enables us to acknowledge the role of housewives (for example as instigators of the Feb- ruary
Recommended publications
  • Genealogy of German Intellectual Impacts on Making of Economic Planning in South Korea
    Genealogy of German Intellectual Impacts on Making of Economic Planning in South Korea Young-Sue Han* <Abstract> This paper aims to explore the path of the genealogy of German intellectuals in the making of economic planning. The Schools of Liberalism criticised economic planning implements in communist states during the Cold War era. In spite of the hostile attitude of the liberalists to economic planning, American policy makers in South Korea consistently recommended introducing economic planning in the nation-making period of the last century. This paper will show that the American reliance on economic planning originates from German intellectuals’ influence by performing a three-fold task. First, this paper backgrounds the influx of the German Historical School into wartime economic planning in Imperial Japan. Consequently, this papers explores American scholarship in Germany in the early 20th century. Finally, this paper explores the roles of scholars in making theories on economic planning in Developmental State School. Key words: Economic planning, The German Historical School, Developmental State, Werner Sombart, Karl Mannheim, Lorenz von Stein * International Institute for Regional & Cultural Studies, Sogang University. 32 제9권 1집(통권 제16호, 2018년 3월) Contents Ⅰ. Introduction Ⅳ. German intellectual influences on Ⅱ. Japanese reception of the German the theoreticalization of economic Historical School of Economics planning Ⅲ. German intellectual influences on the Ⅴ. Conclusion formation of economic planning in the USA I. Introduction This paper aims to explore the path of the genealogy of German intellectuals in the making of economic planning. The purpose of this exploration arises from the lack of a considerable body of academic literature on economic development based on the economic planning of South Korea in the last century.
    [Show full text]
  • Freedom and Economic Theory
    FREEDOM AND ECONOMIC THEORY Second research report on Menger's unpublished paperl By EMIL KAUDER Professor of Economics ' Floride Presbyteria'e College I . Carl Menger's Library The Menger library is more than 100 years old. Carl Menger's father, a small-town lawyer in former Austrian Poland, collected the first 4,000 volumes.2 Carl Menger, who was a famous economist, an avid reader and a book collector, enlarged the collection to 25.000 volumes. After his death the works dealing with the social sciences were ac- quired by the Japanese government and are kept at the Hitotsubashi University, Kunitachi, Tokyo. The books by themselves are of great literary and scientific value ; they are es- pecially important for the historian of economic thought, becauSe they contain essential parts of Menger's scientific legacy. Menger's collection reflects his working habits, his thinking, and his personality. He wrote corrections, short notes, and fragmentary essays on the flyleaves, margins and other empty spots of the books he owned. More often than not these notes have only an indirect connection with the printed text. They are monologues by which he clarified and developed his own thoughts. Most important are his notes in Rau's Gruardsdtze der Volkste,irtschafts- lehre and his copy of his own Principles of 1871. Menger's remarks in Rau's handbook (abbreviated : Rm.) contain an early version of his theories of value, ,price, and money. Menger'shand copy of his theory of 187 1 (abbreviated : fragment) includes an unfinished correction of this work which was planned as an introduction for a four-volume handbook.
    [Show full text]
  • Paternalism and the Public Household. on the Domestic Origins of Public Economics Maxime Desmarais-Tremblay
    Paternalism and the public household. On the domestic origins of public economics Maxime Desmarais-Tremblay To cite this version: Maxime Desmarais-Tremblay. Paternalism and the public household. On the domestic origins of public economics. 2017. halshs-01560189 HAL Id: halshs-01560189 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-01560189 Submitted on 11 Jul 2017 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Documents de Travail du Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne Paternalism and the public household. On the domestic origins of public economics Maxime DESMARAIS-TREMBLAY 2017.32 Maison des Sciences Économiques, 106-112 boulevard de L'Hôpital, 75647 Paris Cedex 13 http://centredeconomiesorbonne.univ-paris1.fr/ ISSN : 1955-611X Paternalism and the public household On the domestic origins of public economics Maxime Desmarais-Tremblay∗ June 16, 2017 Abstract The ancient Greek conception of oikonomia is often dismissed as irrelevant for making sense of the contemporary economic world. In this paper, I emphasise a thread that runs through the history of economic thought connecting the oikos to modern public economics. By conceptualising the public economy as a public household, Richard A. Musgrave (1910-2007) set foot in a long tradition of analogy between the practically oriented household and the state.
    [Show full text]
  • Government Debt in Economic Thought of the Long 19Th Century
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Institutional Repository of the Freie Universität Berlin Government Debt in Economic Thought of the Long 19th Century Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich School of Business & Economics Discussion Paper Economics 2013/4 Government Debt in Economic Thought of the Long 19th Century Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich J.F. Kennedy Institute for North American Studies, Free University of Berlin Contributed to the symposium on “Government Debt in Democracies” in Berlin 30 November and 1 December 2012 I. Introduction The first half of the long 19th century covers the publication of Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations in 1776 through the work of subsequent representatives of classical political economy in Great Britain. The second half of that long century is marked by the contributions of German economists to public finance theory spanning the sixty years preceding the First World War. In this paper I will contrast the views of four classical British economists regarding the issue of public debt, namely those of Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Thomas Robert Malthus and John Stuart Mill, with those of three German economists, Carl Dietzel, Lorenz von Stein, and, with the internationally prominent (at least up to the First World War), Adolph Wagner. The position of British economists of the classical school that government debt was an impediment to economic progress is relatively familiar. Maybe due to their harsh judgment they treated the issue only in passing. In contrast, considerably less well-known today are the contributions of these three German economists who published entire books devoted to the issue of public debt with a subtly differentiated analysis and who were led to significantly more favorable assessments of the use of debt finance by governments.
    [Show full text]
  • German Social Science, Meiji Conservatism, and the Peculiarities of Japanese History*
    German Social Science, Meiji Conservatism, and the Peculiarities of Japanese History* erik grimmer-solem Wesleyan University The German Origins of Japanese Exceptionalism Sir Rutherford Alcock, the first British minister in Tokyo, remarked in 1863 that Japan was a land of paradoxes impelled “by some occult law . in a perfectly opposite direction and reversed order.” 1 This view of Japan, borrowed directly from Herodotus’s description of the ancient Egyptians, has had a long career among foreign observers of Japan and drives the notion of Japanese exceptionalism to this day. Yet as histori- ans of Japan know, the Western notion of Japanese peculiarity is newer than is often realized. Engelbert Kaempfer (1651–1716), a German doctor in Dutch service in Japan and author of the celebrated History and Description of Japan (1777–1779), admired Japan as familiar, simi- lar to Europe, and, in some respects, a civilization ahead of the West.2 * An early version of this article was presented at the University of Chicago workshop “Japan in the World, the World in Japan” in May 2001, and I gratefully acknowledge the helpful suggestions of Tetsuo Najita. A revised draft was then presented at the German Studies Association conference in Washington, DC, in October 2001. I thank Dieter Buse and Nancy Wingfield for their useful comments. Bill Johnston, Donald Levine, Bruce Mas- ters, Devin Pendas, and David Titus gave valuable feedback on later drafts, and Michael Eastwood and Miwa Katsumata provided assistance translating Japanese sources. 1 Quoted in Endymion Wilkinson, Japan versus the West: Image and Reality (London: Penguin, 1991), p.
    [Show full text]
  • Karl Polanyi and Discussions on a Renewed Socialism
    Culture, Practice & Europeanization, 2019, Vol. 4, No. 1, 116-134 …………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………. Karl Polanyi and discussions on a renewed socialism Michael Brie ([email protected]) Rosa Luxemburg Foundation, Germany _________________________________________________________________________ The paper reconstructs Karl Polanyi's search process for a socialist answer to the crisis of capitalist civilization in the first half of the 20th century. Polanyi focused on the question of how the conditions for responsible freedom can be realized under the conditions of a complex society. For Polanyi, this only seemed possible if a new Great Transformation of society were to take place, leaving the capitalist market society behind. Polanyi concen- trated on three paths: (1) the diminishing of the commodity character of natural resources, labor and money; (2) the comprehensive democratization of economic decisions on the basis of deglobalization and intraregional cooperation; and (3) the institutional safeguard- ing of individual freedom at the expense of economic efficiency. Keywords: Gemeinschaft and Gesellschaft, Transformation of Capitalism, Neo-Socialism 1. Gemeinschaft and Gesellschaft – the complexity of society The last chapter of Karl Polanyi's famous work The Great Transformation was titled Free- dom in a Complex Society. This title itself expresses one of the most fundamental contra- dictions at the heart of the socialist tradition and in Polanyi's thinking itself – the contra- diction between Gemeinschaft and Gesellschaft. Socialism in general and Polanyi’s under- standing of socialism in particular are visions of an "association, in which the free develop- ment of each is the condition for the free development of all" (Marx & Engels, 1976, 506). From their early beginnings in the aftermath of the Great French Revolution, socialism and communism challenged the emerging modern capitalist societies, demanding that free- dom should not be a privilege but accessible to the last favored classes and groups.
    [Show full text]
  • LORENZ VON STEIN AS a DISCIPLE of SAINT-SIMON and the FRENCH UTOPIANS Stefan KOSLOWSKI*
    LORENZ VON STEIN AS A DISCIPLE OF SAINT-SIMON AND THE FRENCH UTOPIANS Stefan KOSLOWSKI* Para citar este artículo puede utilizarse el siguiente formato: Stefan Koslowski (2017): «Lorenz von Stein as a disciple of Saint-Simon and the french utopians», en Revista europea de historia de las ideas políticas y de las instituciones públicas, nº 11 (octubre de 2017). Puede leerse este artículo en: http://www.eumed.net/rev/rehipip/11/koslowski.html. RESUMEN: Estudio sobre las teorías sociales de Lorenz von Stein como discípulo de Saint-Simon y de los pensadores utópicos franceses. El autor contextualiza su artículo con las ideas de relevantes ideólogos políticos y sociales. La autoridad de Lorenz von Stein en su momento, a nivel europeo y su influencia en Francia, es algo de sobra conocido y reconocido por la doctrina. Incluso el propio Karl Marx se hizo eco de las obras de Lorenz von Stein. En España, Ángel López- Amo le prestó atención y escribió sobre su legado doctrinal. PALABRAS CLAVE: Lorenz von Stein, Saint-Simon, Karl Marx, Auguste Comte, Victor Considérant, Louis Reybaud, Joseph Proudhon. RESUM: Estudi sobre les teories socials de Lorenz von Stein com a deixeble de Saint-Simon i dels pensadors utòpics francesos. L'autor contextualitza el seu article amb les idees de rellevants ideòlegs polítics i socials. L'autoritat de Lorenz von Stein al seu moment, a nivell europeu i la seva influència a França, és una mica de sobra conegut i reconegut per la doctrina. Fins i tot, el propri Karl Marx es va fer ressò de les obres de Lorenz von Stein.
    [Show full text]
  • How the Young Karl Marx Became a Marxist
    IS MARX THE ANSWER TO PIKETTY? READ THIS BOOK By Marcel H. Van Herpen Paperback: 295 pages Publisher: Cicero Foundation Press Year of Publication: 2016 Language: English ISBN: 978-90-75759-14-3 Product Dimensions: 14.7 x 1.8 x 21.4 centimeters Shipping Weight: 450 grams Includes: Bibliography and Index Price: Euro 32, 90 MARCEL H. VAN HERPEN is director of the Cicero Foundation, a think tank based in Maastricht and Paris. He specializes in political philosophy and defense and security developments in Russia and the countries of the former Soviet Union. His books include Putinism – The Slow Rise of a Radical Right Regime in Russia; Putin’s Wars – The Rise of Russia’s New Imperialism; and Putin’s Propaganda Machine – Soft Power and Russian Foreign Policy. Visit his author’s website at www.marcelhvanherpen.com or follow him on Twitter @MarcelHVanHerpe WHY YOU SHOULD BUY THIS BOOK: “AN IMPORTANT BOOK” – HANS ACHTERHUIS, Dutch philosopher and official ‘Thinker of the Fatherland’ (2011 - 2013) on the Dutch edition of this book. In recent years the philosophy of Karl Marx has met with a new interest. The problems of the modern capitalist market economy have showed that Marx - far from being a ‘dead dog’ to be buried in the dustbin of history - has still a lot to tell to our contemporary world. This book proposes a critical assessment of his thinking. The young Karl Marx was a typical representative of German Romanticism, who, under the influence of his father, began to be interested in theories of human alienation . In this book we follow in detail his intellectual development.
    [Show full text]
  • Readingsample
    German Social Policy 1 Thinking About Social Policy The German Tradition Bearbeitet von Franz-Xaver Kaufmann 1. Auflage 2012. Buch. x, 166 S. Hardcover ISBN 978 3 642 19500 6 Format (B x L): 15,5 x 23,5 cm Gewicht: 432 g Weitere Fachgebiete > Medien, Kommunikation, Politik > Regierungspolitik > Sozialpolitik Zu Inhaltsverzeichnis schnell und portofrei erhältlich bei Die Online-Fachbuchhandlung beck-shop.de ist spezialisiert auf Fachbücher, insbesondere Recht, Steuern und Wirtschaft. Im Sortiment finden Sie alle Medien (Bücher, Zeitschriften, CDs, eBooks, etc.) aller Verlage. Ergänzt wird das Programm durch Services wie Neuerscheinungsdienst oder Zusammenstellungen von Büchern zu Sonderpreisen. Der Shop führt mehr als 8 Millionen Produkte. Thinking About Social Policy: The German Tradition Franz-Xaver Kaufmann 1 Introduction Social policy [Sozialpolitik] is a scholarly term that has had a career in practical politics. It arose first in the German-speaking realm, within the horizon of the Hegelian distinction between state and civil society. It was gradually codified academically by scholars belonging to the Verein fur€ Socialpolitik [Association for Social Policy], which was founded in 1873. Its institutional career began with Bismarck’s social reforms, though it took quite some time before it won out over competing German as well as international terms. Until the end of the Weimar Republic, social policy remained chiefly an academic term for the institutional developments taking place under different names. Its introduction into practical affairs took place gradually and especially after the Second World War. The international career of the term dates only to the last three decades. Unlike the term itself, the subject matter of social policy did not originate in the German-speaking realm.
    [Show full text]
  • A Classical German View of Public Debt and Investment in Romania and Other Ex-Socialist Economies
    Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja ISSN: 1331-677X (Print) 1848-9664 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rero20 A classical German view of public debt and investment in Romania and other ex-socialist economies Gheorghe Săvoiu, Vasile Dinu & Marian Ţaicu To cite this article: Gheorghe Săvoiu, Vasile Dinu & Marian Ţaicu (2015) A classical German view of public debt and investment in Romania and other ex-socialist economies, Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 28:1, 907-923, DOI: 10.1080/1331677X.2015.1083877 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2015.1083877 © 2015 The Author(s). Published by Taylor & Francis Published online: 27 Oct 2015. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 547 View related articles View Crossmark data Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rero20 Download by: [95.168.107.53] Date: 27 December 2016, At: 07:40 Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 2015 Vol. 28, No. 1, 907–923, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2015.1083877 A classical German view of public debt and investment in Romania and other ex-socialist economies Gheorghe Săvoiua*, Vasile Dinub and Marian Ţaicua aFaculty of Economic Sciences, University of Pitesti, 1 Târgul din Vale Street, 110040 Pitesti, Arges, Romania; bFaculty of Commerce, Bucharest Academy of Economic Studies, 6 Romana Square, Mihai Eminescu Building, 010374 Bucharest, Romania (Received 28 April 2015; accepted 13 August 2015) The article uses the angle, and it is placed under the influence of the contributions of the representatives of German classical financial economic school, from Carl Dietzel and Lorenz von Stein to Adolph Wagner, whose works, reassessed by Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich in 2013, are comparable, through their originality, to the English and other European classical schools of economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Government Debt in Economic Thought of the Long 19Th Century
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Holtfrerich, Carl-Ludwig Working Paper Government debt in economic thought of the long 19th century Diskussionsbeiträge, No. 2013/4 Provided in Cooperation with: Free University Berlin, School of Business & Economics Suggested Citation: Holtfrerich, Carl-Ludwig (2013) : Government debt in economic thought of the long 19th century, Diskussionsbeiträge, No. 2013/4, Freie Universität Berlin, Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaft, Berlin This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/73682 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Government Debt in Economic Thought of the Long 19th Century Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich School of Business & Economics Discussion Paper Economics 2013/4 Government Debt in Economic Thought of the Long 19th Century Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich J.F.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction
    Introduction “So many as the stars of the sky in multitude, and as the sand which is by the sea shore innumerable”: European Social Movement Research in Perspective Guya Accornero and Olivier Fillieule Th e emergence of social movements, ‘the sustained, organised challenge to existing authorities in the name of a deprived, excluded or wronged popula- tion’ (Tilly 1995: 144), is closely intertwined with the development of state building and nationalization, capitalism (i.e., industrialization and commu- nication networks), urbanization and print capitalism (Anderson 1991; Gell- ner 1983; and Tilly 2004). Th is is why social movements initially appeared in Western Europe, around the mid-nineteenth century, apparently fi rst in Great Britain (Tilly 1995: 144) and, subsequently, in the wake of the 1848 revolution, in continental Europe. Th erefore, it is not surprising that all the founding fathers of the sociology of contentious politics were Europeans: German scholar yes Lorenz von Stein fi rst introduced the term ‘social move- ment’ into scholarly discussion in his History of the French Social Movement from 1789 to the Present (1850); French thinkers Hypolyte Taine, Gustave Le Bon, Gabriel Tarde and particularly Emile Durkheim (with his Th e Ele- mentary Forms of Religious Life published in 1912) can be considered the an- cestors of the collective behaviour paradigm; and, above all, Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels were the fi rst to develop a robust theory of working-class mobilization in Th e Communist Manifesto (1848) and inspired major politi- cal and theoretical contributions by thinkers such as Vladimir I. Lenin, Leon Trotsky, Rosa Luxemburg and later Antonio Gramsci.
    [Show full text]