Epidemiology and Econometrics: Two Sides of the Same Coin Or Different Currencies?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Epidemiology and Econometrics: Two Sides of the Same Coin Or Different Currencies? Epidemiology and Econometrics: Two Sides of the Same Coin or Different Currencies? Marcella Vigneri1 , Edoardo Masset1 , Josephine Exley2, Howard White3 1CEDIL, 2London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, 3Campbell Collaboration Centre of Excellence in Impact Evaluation and Learning (CEDIL) Inception Paper Draft version: 19 January 2018 Abstract This paper discusses differences observed in the practice, conduct and reporting of evaluation studies conducted by economists and clinical epidemiologists. There has been much informal debate around the reasons for these differences and the missed opportunities that they lead to, but we are not aware of any formal review of the key areas where these disciplines diverge and why. This paper fills this gap, drawing on a workshop organized by the Centre of Excellence in Impact Evaluation and Learning (CEDIL) with evaluation specialists from both disciplines, published papers and a systematic approach to illustrate idiosyncrasies from each discipline. The paper also includes an epidemiology-economics evaluation glossary that speaks to both disciplines to facilitate cross learning and synergies between the evaluations that they do 1. Introduction Economics and epidemiology are disciplines that share a research interest in investigating and measuring the impact of interventions in international development. In a 2016 contribution to the American Journal of Public Health, Spiegelman (Spiegelman, 2016) claimed that similarities in the conduct of impact evaluations across disciplines like epidemiology and economics overwhelm the differences, and that the distinctions that have been made confuse the underlying common ground. She broadly defined impact evaluation as a method for assessing the efficacy and effectiveness of an intervention in terms of intended and unintended health, social, and economic outcomes, and involving the explicit statement of a counterfactual. While the principles of Spiegelman’s definition are clear, it is also important to recognize and understand the boundaries that separate how economists and epidemiologists conduct evaluations. Although the principles of their analytical methods are similar (by research questions, type of intervention, intended goal of the intervention), their practice for conducting and reporting evaluations is often different. This paper addresses these boundaries by reviewing evaluation practices of economists and epidemiologists. For the purposes of this paper, we would include the work done by health economists within epidemiological evaluations (for instance to estimate the cost effectiveness of an intervention) as “epidemiology” rather than “economics”. The paper was initially motivated by two debates around differences in these practices. The first debate - led by CEDIL Intellectual Leadership Team members - looked at how the increase in research on global health and international development by scholars in economics (who typically have greater influence on LMIC1 government policymakers in using evidence than researchers in clinical epidemiology), has generated a critical gap in the research methods and practice of evaluation tools between the impact evaluations they do and those within the discipline of clinical epidemiology. This paper builds on this debate to compare the two different approaches, highlighting similarities and differences, and areas for cross learning. The second debate comes from a research paper written by economists and epidemiologists based at the London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine (LSHTM) (Powell-Jackson et al., forthcoming 2018) on the practice of randomized trials by the two disciplines. Those authors suggest that evidence-based public health can be strengthened by a better understanding of the differences in the use, practice and reporting of results from trials, and in so doing promote cross-disciplinary learning. In response to these debates, the CEDIL organized a workshop in November 2017 gathering economists and epidemiologists specialising in evaluation research to discuss areas of overlap and of divergence. In preparation for the workshop we collected some evidence of differences in approaches between economists and epidemiologists in two ways. First, we selected a number of systematic reviews of interventions in early child development/nutrition specific programmes and in Conditional Cash Transfer (CCT) programmes, and used the discussion and results of the reviews to reflect on approaches and differences between primary researchers and reviewers in the two disciplines. Second, we identified a few publications of project types evaluated by economists and by epidemiologists to identify main methodological differences in the conduct of impact evaluations. 1 Low and Middle-Income Countries 1 This paper resulted as the critical elaboration of what emerged in the workshop. Section 2 identifies areas where economist and epidemiologist differ in the practice of evaluation studies. After a brief description of the issues relevant in each area, examples from peer reviewed papers in each discipline are used to illustrate differences in practice. The common themes selected for this exercise are conditional cash transfers (CCT), bednets, WASH (Water, Sanitation and Hygiene), anti- retroviral treatment (ART) for the reduction of HIV incidence, and gender interventions to reduce the risk of Intimate Partner Violence (IPV). Section 3 draws reflections from comparing systematic reviews in health insurance, school feeding and conditional and unconditional cash transfers programmes to illustrate further differences in the evaluation methods used in the two disciplines. Section 4 explains the rationale for collating a unified “epi-econ” evaluation glossary (included in the annex) to compare terms used by the two disciplines and try to reduce the clashes which often cloud cross-discipline understanding of evaluation studies. This glossary will help evaluation researchers to identify a common lexicon of their different approaches. Section 5 concludes the paper, reflecting on learning opportunities across the two approaches. 2. Comparing economic and epidemiology approaches to evaluation How do economists and epidemiologists conduct evaluation studies? In general, economists are interested in measuring the success of a program—where success can be broadly or narrowly defined. Their goal is to differentiate less effective interventions from successful ones, and help improve existing programs. The primary purpose of impact evaluation for economists is to determine whether a program has an impact (on a set of key outcomes), and more specifically, to quantify how large that impact is (insert ref. from J-Pal). On the other hand, epidemiologists operating in public health services conduct evaluations as a process for determining, as systematically and objectively as possible, the likely future relevance, effectiveness, efficiency, and impact of activities with respect to established health outcomes (insert ref. from Centres for Disease Control and Prevention). One could say that although evaluations conducted in both disciplines share the common goal to identify presence or absence of impact, their ‘journey’ to an estimate of impact differs in many ways. In the November 2017 workshop, we identified eight key areas where differences in evaluation practices are prominent: 1. The use of theory to underpin model evaluation; 2. The generalizability and transferability of findings from the specifics of an individual case study; 3. The definition of research questions; 4. Study design, and endpoint/outcome measure of impact; 5. Power calculations and powered studies; 6. Publication of protocols and pre-specified outcomes; 7. Reporting findings, and timing of publications; and 8. Replicability. We discuss each of these below to highlight differences. A word of caution is warranted in reading the discussion that follows: while the paper reviews issues that often contrast how economist and epidemiologists conduct evaluation studies, by no means it intends to claim universal truths. There are, of course, evaluations done by economists that more closely resemble those carried out by epidemiologists than those completed by other economists, and vice versa. 2.1 Using Theory to underpin the evaluation problem In ‘best practice’ economics, it is not unusual to find that impact evaluations are the empirical translation of some theory of economic behavior. Economists use theory both to model behaviour, and to identify ex-ante predictions about changes in behavior that can be attributed to an 2 intervention. While the use of theory is not universal among economists, it is generally seen as giving stronger grounding to impact evaluations; theory informs the design of the study, and guides the empirical testing. For instance, economists sometimes use structural models to investigate the mechanisms behind the impacts of a given intervention and to guide the interpretation of the results after estimation. The practice of using theory is much less common in epidemiology, where modelling is rather employed to look at transmission mechanisms (process evaluation) that capture the dynamic nature and spread of – for example - diseases from infectious to susceptible individuals, and to incorporate positive and negative feedback characteristics of infectious processes. Epidemiology also uses theory to inform clinical decision analysis (for example by using decision trees, Markov models to assess the probability of transitions from one state
Recommended publications
  • UNEMPLOYMENT and LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION: a PANEL COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS for EUROPEAN COUNTRIES OZERKEK, Yasemin Abstract This
    Applied Econometrics and International Development Vol. 13-1 (2013) UNEMPLOYMENT AND LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION: A PANEL COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS FOR EUROPEAN COUNTRIES OZERKEK, Yasemin* Abstract This paper investigates the long-run relationship between unemployment and labor force participation and analyzes the existence of added/discouraged worker effect, which has potential impact on economic growth and development. Using panel cointegration techniques for a panel of European countries (1983-2009), the empirical results show that this long-term relation exists for only females and there is discouraged worker effect for them. Thus, female unemployment is undercount. Keywords: labor-force participation rate, unemployment rate, discouraged worker effect, panel cointegration, economic development JEL Codes: J20, J60, O15, O52 1. Introduction The link between labor force participation and unemployment has long been a key concern in the literature. There is general agreement that unemployment tends to cause workers to leave the labor force (Schwietzer and Smith, 1974). A discouraged worker is one who stopped actively searching for jobs because he does not think he can find work. Discouraged workers are out of the labor force and hence are not taken into account in the calculation of unemployment rate. Since unemployment rate disguises discouraged workers, labor-force participation rate has a central role in giving clues about the employment market and the overall health of the economy.1 Murphy and Topel (1997) and Gustavsson and Österholm (2006) mention that discouraged workers, who have withdrawn from labor force for market-driven reasons, can considerably affect the informational value of the unemployment rate as a macroeconomic indicator. The relationship between unemployment and labor-force participation is an important concern in the fields of labor economics and development economics as well.
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Econometrics?
    Robert D. Coleman, PhD © 2006 [email protected] What Is Econometrics? Econometrics means the measure of things in economics such as economies, economic systems, markets, and so forth. Likewise, there is biometrics, sociometrics, anthropometrics, psychometrics and similar sciences devoted to the theory and practice of measure in a particular field of study. Here is how others describe econometrics. Gujarati (1988), Introduction, Section 1, What Is Econometrics?, page 1, says: Literally interpreted, econometrics means “economic measurement.” Although measurement is an important part of econometrics, the scope of econometrics is much broader, as can be seen from the following quotations. Econometrics, the result of a certain outlook on the role of economics, consists of the application of mathematical statistics to economic data to lend empirical support to the models constructed by mathematical economics and to obtain numerical results. ~~ Gerhard Tintner, Methodology of Mathematical Economics and Econometrics, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1968, page 74. Econometrics may be defined as the quantitative analysis of actual economic phenomena based on the concurrent development of theory and observation, related by appropriate methods of inference. ~~ P. A. Samuelson, T. C. Koopmans, and J. R. N. Stone, “Report of the Evaluative Committee for Econometrica,” Econometrica, vol. 22, no. 2, April 1954, pages 141-146. Econometrics may be defined as the social science in which the tools of economic theory, mathematics, and statistical inference are applied to the analysis of economic phenomena. ~~ Arthur S. Goldberger, Econometric Theory, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York, 1964, page 1. 1 Robert D. Coleman, PhD © 2006 [email protected] Econometrics is concerned with the empirical determination of economic laws.
    [Show full text]
  • An Econometric Examination of the Trend Unemployment Rate in Canada
    Working Paper 96-7 / Document de travail 96-7 An Econometric Examination of the Trend Unemployment Rate in Canada by Denise Côté and Doug Hostland Bank of Canada Banque du Canada May 1996 AN ECONOMETRIC EXAMINATION OF THE TREND UNEMPLOYMENT RATE IN CANADA by Denise Côté and Doug Hostland Research Department E-mail: [email protected] Hostland.Douglas@fin.gc.ca This paper is intended to make the results of Bank research available in preliminary form to other economists to encourage discussion and suggestions for revision. The views expressed are those of the authors. No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Bank of Canada. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The authors would like to thank Pierre Duguay, Irene Ip, Paul Jenkins, David Longworth, Tiff Macklem, Brian O’Reilly, Ron Parker, David Rose and Steve Poloz for many helpful comments and suggestions, and Sébastien Sherman for his assistance in preparing the graphs. We would also like to thank the participants of a joint Research Department/UQAM Macro-Labour Workshop for their comments and Helen Meubus for her editorial suggestions. ISSN 1192-5434 ISBN 0-662-24596-2 Printed in Canada on recycled paper iii ABSTRACT This paper attempts to identify the trend unemployment rate, an empirical concept, using cointegration theory. The authors examine whether there is a cointegrating relationship between the observed unemployment rate and various structural factors, focussing neither on the non-accelerating-inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) nor on the natural rate of unemployment, but rather on the trend unemployment rate, which they define in terms of cointegration. They show that, given the non stationary nature of the data, cointegration represents a necessary condition for analysing the NAIRU and the natural rate but not a sufficient condition for defining them.
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • The Ends of Four Big Inflations
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Inflation: Causes and Effects Volume Author/Editor: Robert E. Hall Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-31323-9 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/hall82-1 Publication Date: 1982 Chapter Title: The Ends of Four Big Inflations Chapter Author: Thomas J. Sargent Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11452 Chapter pages in book: (p. 41 - 98) The Ends of Four Big Inflations Thomas J. Sargent 2.1 Introduction Since the middle 1960s, many Western economies have experienced persistent and growing rates of inflation. Some prominent economists and statesmen have become convinced that this inflation has a stubborn, self-sustaining momentum and that either it simply is not susceptible to cure by conventional measures of monetary and fiscal restraint or, in terms of the consequent widespread and sustained unemployment, the cost of eradicating inflation by monetary and fiscal measures would be prohibitively high. It is often claimed that there is an underlying rate of inflation which responds slowly, if at all, to restrictive monetary and fiscal measures.1 Evidently, this underlying rate of inflation is the rate of inflation that firms and workers have come to expect will prevail in the future. There is momentum in this process because firms and workers supposedly form their expectations by extrapolating past rates of inflation into the future. If this is true, the years from the middle 1960s to the early 1980s have left firms and workers with a legacy of high expected rates of inflation which promise to respond only slowly, if at all, to restrictive monetary and fiscal policy actions.
    [Show full text]
  • Gravity Models and Panel Econometrics” 21 – 25 September 2020
    World Trade Institute, University of Bern “Gravity Models and Panel Econometrics” 21 – 25 September 2020 Course Goals and content Course Content Grading The objective of this course is to serve as a A Trade Theory and the Gravity-Model Class participation (20 %); take-home exam practical guide for trade policy analysis with (80 %). Participants taking this course for 1. The Anderson and van Wincoop and the gravity model offering a balanced credit must attend all lectures and complete the Krugman Model approach between trade theory and econ- the take home exam. 2. The Eaton and Kortum Model metrics. We will discuss recent developments 3 Trade with Heterogeneous Firms in the economic foundation of gravity models 4. Zero Trade and the Helpman-Melitz- and describe best practices for quantifying the Rubinstein Model Organization general equilibrium impact of changes in trade 5. Measuring the Gains from Trade barriers and, especially, trade policies. The course is intended for PhD students. A 6. Universal Gravity limited number of people with relevant The course is organized in three modules. professional or academic interest may be also Module A concentrates on recent contri- B The Econometrics of Gravity Models of admitted. butions from trade theory that motivate Trade gravity models and form the basis of policy Lecture hours: 24 ECTS : 4 trade policy analysis. The second module will 1. Estimation of Linear High-dimensional take a closer look at the econometric issues of Fixed Effects models the estimation of gravity models and of 2. The Incidental Parameter Problem Timetable and Registration performing policy simulations. Starting point is 3.
    [Show full text]
  • Econometric Theory
    ECONOMETRIC THEORY MODULE – I Lecture - 1 Introduction to Econometrics Dr. Shalabh Department of Mathematics and Statistics Indian Institute of Technology Kanpur 2 Econometrics deals with the measurement of economic relationships. It is an integration of economic theories, mathematical economics and statistics with an objective to provide numerical values to the parameters of economic relationships. The relationships of economic theories are usually expressed in mathematical forms and combined with empirical economics. The econometrics methods are used to obtain the values of parameters which are essentially the coefficients of mathematical form of the economic relationships. The statistical methods which help in explaining the economic phenomenon are adapted as econometric methods. The econometric relationships depict the random behaviour of economic relationships which are generally not considered in economics and mathematical formulations. It may be pointed out that the econometric methods can be used in other areas like engineering sciences, biological sciences, medical sciences, geosciences, agricultural sciences etc. In simple words, whenever there is a need of finding the stochastic relationship in mathematical format, the econometric methods and tools help. The econometric tools are helpful in explaining the relationships among variables. 3 Econometric models A model is a simplified representation of a real world process. It should be representative in the sense that it should contain the salient features of the phenomena under study. In general, one of the objectives in modeling is to have a simple model to explain a complex phenomenon. Such an objective may sometimes lead to oversimplified model and sometimes the assumptions made are unrealistic. In practice, generally all the variables which the experimenter thinks are relevant to explain the phenomenon are included in the model.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 5. Structural Vector Autoregression
    Chapter 5. Structural Vector Autoregression Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 The structural moving average model 1 2.1 The impulse response function . 2 2.2 Variance decomposition . 3 3 The structural VAR representation 4 3.1 Connection between VAR and VMA . 5 3.2 The invertibility requirement . 5 4 Identi…cation of the structural VAR 8 4.1 The order condition . 9 4.2 What shouldn’tbe done . 9 4.3 A common normalization that provides n(n - 1)/2 restrictions . 11 4.4 Identi…cation through short run restrictions . 11 4.5 Identi…cation through long run restrictions . 12 5 Estimation and inference 13 5.1 Estimating exactly identi…ed models . 13 5.2 Estimating overly identi…ed models . 13 5.3 Inference . 14 6 Structural VAR versus fully speci…ed economic models 14 1. Introduction Following the work of Sims (1980), vector autoregressions have been extensively used by economists for data description, forecasting and structural inference. The discussion here focuses on structural inference. The key idea, as put forward by Sims (1980), is to estimate a model with minimal parametric restrictions and then subsequently test economic hypothesis based on such a model. This idea has attracted a great deal of attention since it promises to deliver an alternative framework to testing economic theory without relying on elaborately parametrized dynamic general equilibrium models. The material in this chapter is based on Watson (1994) and Fernandez-Villaverde, Rubio-Ramirez, Sargent and Watson (2007). We begin the discussion by introducing the structural moving average model, and show that this model provides answers to the “impulse” and “propagation” questions often asked by macroeconomists.
    [Show full text]
  • A Gravity Model for Trade Between Vietnam and Twenty-Three European Countries
    DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND SOCIETY D THESIS 2006 A GRAVITY MODEL FOR TRADE BETWEEN VIETNAM AND TWENTY-THREE EUROPEAN COUNTRIES Supervisor: Reza Mortazavi Author : Thai Tri Do Abstract This thesis examines the bilateral trade between Vietnam and twenty three European countries based on a gravity model and panel data for years 1993 to 2004. Estimates indicate that economic size, market size and real exchange rate of Vietnam and twenty three European countries play major role in bilateral trade between Vietnam and these countries. Distance and history, however, do not seem to drive the bilateral trade. The results of gravity model are also applied to calculate the trade potential between Vietnam and twenty three European countries. It shows that Vietnam’s trade with twenty three European countries has considerable room for growth. Key words: Gravity model, panel data, trade potential, European countries, Vietnam. Table of Contents 1. Introduction ............................................................................................................................ 1 2. Vietnam’s foreign trade overview.......................................................................................... 2 3. Trade with European countries in OECD .............................................................................. 5 4. Theory and Literature review................................................................................................. 6 4.1 Absolute and comparative advantage..............................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 6: Vector Autoregression∗
    Lecture 6: Vector Autoregression∗ In this section, we will extend our discussion to vector valued time series. We will be mostly interested in vector autoregression (VAR), which is much easier to be estimated in applications. We will fist introduce the properties and basic tools in analyzing stationary VAR process, and then we’ll move on to estimation and inference of the VAR model. 1 Covariance-stationary VAR(p) process 1.1 Introduction to stationary vector ARMA processes 1.1.1 VAR processes A VAR model applies when each variable in the system does not only depend on its own lags, but also the lags of other variables. A simple VAR example is: x1t = φ11x1,t−1 + φ12x2,t−1 + 1t x2t = φ21x2,t−1 + φ22x2,t−2 + 2t where E(1t2s) = σ12 for t = s and zero for t 6= s. We could rewrite it as x φ φ x 0 0 x 1t = 11 12 1,t−1 + 1,t−2 + 1t , x2t 0 φ21 x2,t−1 0 φ22 x2,t−2 2t or just xt = Φ1xt−1 + Φ2xt−2 + t (1) and E(t) = 0,E(ts) = 0 for s 6= t and 2 0 σ1 σ12 E(tt) = 2 . σ21 σ2 As you can see, in this example, the vector-valued random variable xt follows a VAR(2) process. A general VAR(p) process with white noise can be written as xt = Φ1xt−1 + Φ2xt−2 + ... + t p X = Φjxt−j + t j=1 or, if we make use of the lag operator, Φ(L)xt = t, ∗Copyright 2002-2006 by Ling Hu.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 the Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
    Cover design: Jordi Uriel INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMETRICS Ezequiel Uriel 2019 University of Valencia I would like to thank the professors Luisa Moltó, Amado Peiró, Paz Rico, Pilar Beneito and Javier Ferri for their suggestions for the errata they have detected in previous versions, and for having provided me with data to formulate exercises. Some students have also collaborated in the detection of errata. In any case, I am solely responsible for the errata that have not been detected. Summary 1 Econometrics and economic data ..................................................... 9 1.1 What is econometrics? ................................................................................ 9 1.2 Steps in developing an econometric model .............................................. 10 1.3 Economic data .......................................................................................... 13 2 The simple regression model: estimation and properties............... 15 2.1 Some definitions in the simple regression model ..................................... 15 2.1.1 Population regression model and population regression function .............................. 15 2.1.2 Sample regression function ........................................................................................ 16 2.2 Obtaining the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) Estimates .......................... 17 2.2.1 Different criteria of estimation ................................................................................... 17 2.2.2 Application of least square criterion .........................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Econometric Methods - Roselyne Joyeux and George Milunovich
    MATHEMATICAL MODELS IN ECONOMICS – Vol. I - Econometric Methods - Roselyne Joyeux and George Milunovich ECONOMETRIC METHODS Roselyne Joyeux and George Milunovich Department of Economics, Macquarie University, Australia Keywords: Least Squares, Maximum Likelihood, Generalized Method of Moments, time series, panel, limited dependent variables Contents 1. Introduction 2. Least Squares Estimation 3. Maximum Likelihood 3.1. Estimation 3.2. Statistical Inference Using the Maximum Likelihood Approach 4. Generalized Method of Moments 4.1. Method of Moments 4.2 Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) 5. Other Estimation Techniques 6. Time Series Models 6.1 Time Series Models: a Classification 6.2 Univariate Time Series Models 6.3 Multivariate Time Series Models 6.4. Modelling Time-Varying Volatility 6.4.1. Univariate GARCH Models 6.4.2. Multivariate GARCH models 7. Panel Data Models 7.1. Pooled Least Squares Estimation 7.2. Estimation after Differencing 7.3.Fixed Effects Estimation 7.4. Random Effects Estimation 7.5. Non-stationary Panels 8. Discrete and Limited Dependent Variables 8.1. The Linear Probability Model (LPM) 8.2. The LogitUNESCO and Probit Models – EOLSS 8.3. Modelling Count Data: The Poisson Regression Model 8.4. Modelling Censored Data: Tobit Model 9. Conclusion Glossary SAMPLE CHAPTERS Bibliography Biographical Sketches Summary The development of econometric methods has proceeded at an unprecedented rate over the last forty years, spurred along by advances in computing, econometric theory and the availability of richer data sets. The aim of this chapter is to provide a survey of econometric methods. We present an overview of those econometric methods and ©Encyclopedia of Life Support Systems (EOLSS) MATHEMATICAL MODELS IN ECONOMICS – Vol.
    [Show full text]