Inheritance and Succession Taxes J

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Inheritance and Succession Taxes J Cornell Law Library Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository Historical Theses and Dissertations Collection Historical Cornell Law School 1894 Inheritance and Succession Taxes J. John Hassett Cornell Law School Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/historical_theses Part of the Estates and Trusts Commons, and the Tax Law Commons Recommended Citation Hassett, J. John, "Inheritance and Succession Taxes" (1894). Historical Theses and Dissertations Collection. Paper 14. This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Historical Cornell Law School at Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Historical Theses and Dissertations Collection by an authorized administrator of Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE SIS INHERITANCE AND SUCCESSION TAXES Presented for the Degree of Bachelor of Laws by J. John Hassett Cornell University Ithaca, -------- New York 1894 IN T R 0 D U C T I 0 N. The almost total lack of a systematic treatise on the subject of lheritance and Succession Taxes in English and inaccessibility of those admirable treatises in Franch and German caused me to select this subject, which, upon careful investigation, proved to be a great deal broader tian I had anticipated and which my limited amount of time and space would allow iie to treat exhaustively in every particular. The position and objections of the different politi- al economists being so varied, although readily susceptible of claasification, caused me to simply aesignate the trend of their opinions, objections and arguments. The lack of time and space made it necessary that I should leave out my proposed chapter on "The trend of leg- islation on this subject". This necessarily limitet Chap- ter IV. to the decisions Of the New York courts. TABLE OF CONTENTS Page I. History of Inheritance and Succession Taxes 2 (a) Origin, (b) In England, (c) In United tates. 11. Such taxes considered from an Economic Standpoint point ................................... 9 111. Trendof the Legislaticn Upon the Subject... IV. Important Decisions with dpecial reference to New York .... ...................... l (a) Constitutionality, (b) Property Subject to the Tax, (c) Value of the Property, (d) Exemptions, (e) Practice. TABLE OF CASES. ... -- 0---- A*stor, Estate of, (20 Abb. i. C. 405)..........29 E'k Clerk',- M1ut. Ben. Ass. (22 Abb. N.C. 50) ...e28 Bird, Mvatter of, (32 U1. Y. t. Rep. 89 )20 Bittinger's Eatat (129 Pa. St. 338)..............17 Butler, Matter of (58 Hun 400)...................*24 Cager, Matter of (111 N. Y. 343)...................18 Catlin v. Trustees Trinity Col. (113 11. Y. 133). 27 Coleman'.s Estate, In re (28 At. Rep. 137) Co monwealth v. :iangy (82 Va. 883)................24, Commonwelth v. Sharpless (2 Chester, Pa., 246) .17 Crosby, Matter of (46 N. Y. St. Rep. 442)........17 Davison v. New Orleans (96 U. S. 97-106).17 Euston, Miatter of (113 N. Y. 174)............... 18 Eyre v. Jacobs (14 Gratt. 427). ................ 14 Herr, Matter of (55 Hun 167).17 Howe, Matter of (112 U. Y. 100)......18 Hoyt v. Commissioners (23 N. Y. 224)a.........15,21 Hulse, Matter of (39 N. Y. St. Rep. 402)..........18 Johnson, Matter of (49 IT. Y. St. R ep. W1) ..... 22 Keech, Matter of (32 N. Y. St. Rep.227)........ 28 Kirtland v. Hotchkiss (100 U. S. 491)............ 12 Leavitt, Matter of (4 N. Y. Supp. 179).......... 20 Lenox, Matter of (31 N. Y. St. Rep. 959)......27, 28 McCullough v Maryland (4 Wheat. 316)........... 12 McPhe.son, Matter rf (104 N. Y. 306) s......12f13, 26 Millers Est-, Matter of (110 N. Y. 216)....'7 22 Miller, Estate of (5 Denio 132)................. 26 Mixer, Matter of (10 Pa. Or. Ct. Rep. 409) ..... 18 Nash v. White's Bk. of Buffalo (105 N.Y. 243)... 24 Neale, Matter (-f Estate of (32 N. Y. St. Rep. 910 )27 Orcut t's Appeal (97 Pa. St. 179) 17 Peck, Matter of (30 N. Y. t. -ep.) 209) 19 People ex rel Society of N. Y. Hospital v. Purdy (58 Hun 386) .................... 28 Peters v. City of Lynchburg (76 Va. 927) 13 Prine, Matter of (136 N. Y. 347)............... 27 Prout, Matter of (136 N. Ye 347)............... 29 Pullen v. Com. of Wake Co. (5 Denio 292) 29 Robertson, Matter of (6 3 N. C. 361).......13, 14 Rogers, Mtter of (30 N. Y. St. Rep. 943)....... 18 Romaine, Matter of (127 N. Y.l) .. .. 27 Scholey v. Rew (23 Wall. 331) .............. 14 Schofield v. City of Lynchburg (78 Va. 367) ..... 13 Sherwell, Matter of (32 N. Y. St. Rep. 1020) ... 19 Small's Estate (151. Pa. St. l1) ............ 17 Smith, Matter of (5 Denio 90)...................18 Stewart's Estate, In re (131 N. Y. 274)...........22 Stroder v. C.ormnonwealth (52 Pa. ST. 181).........14 Swift Estate, Matter of (137 N. Y. 7).....18,17,22 Thorn v. Gardner (ll . Y.198)................. 19 Twigg's Estat--, In re (15 1. Y. Supp. 239) ..... 28 Tyson v. Maryland (28 Md. 597) ..... ....... 13 Vanderbilt's Estate (10 N. Y. 2upp. 23,9).28 Wallace v. Meyers (38 Fed. Fep. 184) Wolfls Estate (19 N. Y. St..Repo263).17,29 2 CHAPTER 1. Inheritance and Succession Tax may be' defined gener- ally to be a burden imposed on all property whether real or personal, passing to certain persons by will, by intestate law, or by deed or instrument intervivos, in- tendedto take effect at or after the death of the testa- tor. The eldest evidence we rtave of the existence of an inheritance tax id a papyrus which was found in Egypt and relates that one iermias was sentenced to pay a heavy penalty for failing to pay the tax upon succeeding to his fathre's house. Another papyrus, which might be construed as evidence of an attempt to avoid the payment of such a tax, records the sale of property by an old man to his sons for a nominal sum. The origin of Inheritance and succession taxes has usually been attributed to the Emperor Augustus, who is known to have established such a tax in the #ear 67_. D. which, in connection with the excise tax, was used to establish a permanent military. Exemptions from the tax were allowed for funeral ex- penses and when it was undaer a certain value or amount, most probably of 50 or 100 pieces of gold(wh~ich sum was only fixed by conjecture). Tne near relations on the fathee's side were also exempt but those on the mother's icde, called the Cognati, were not according to the law of the twelve tables, called to the succession. This Larsh institution was gradually undermined by humanity and finally abolished by Justinian. It is impossible to state the exact time that the Roman inheritance tax wias repealed but we have evidence of its existence as late as the reign of Gordian 111. and it had disappearea before the Code of Justinian, so it is probable that it was repealed either by Justinian or Diocletian. (Gibbon, Hist. ofDecline and Fall of the Ro- man Empire, Bk. V., Chap. VI.) When the Emperor Augustus submitted the plan of the inheritance tax to the Senate he said that he had found a draft of such a tax among the private papers of Julius Caesar and apparetntly it had been his intention to lay such a tax . As the Romans were well acquaintedwith the financial systems of Egypt about that time, it is safe to presume that they borrowed this system of taxation from the Egyptians. During the Miiddle Ages the only representation of 4 the inheritance tax that existed was the relief of h-eriot of feudal tenure together with some chargeS of a similar nature. There seems to be no historiaal connection traceable between these and the old inheritance tax whic., existed in Rome and her provinces. in many countries you can trace a direct historical connection between these and their present 3ystem of inh-eritance and suc- cession taxes. In England there seems to be no istor- ical connection between the relief and heriot of feudal tenure and either the present system of inheritrnce and succession taxes which exist in England or the old Roman inheritance taxes. England borrowed the idea of stamp taxes from Hol- land and the original Stamp Act of 1694 contained a pro- vision for a tax of five shillings on probates ana lettel of administration in the case of estates over 20 pounds. Four years later it was douhlea; and in 1779 it was grad- uated from 10 to 15 shillings according to the value of the estate. In 1780 Lord North introduced a tax on re- ceipts i'or legacies and distributive shares and which was afterwart increase i and s ometh~ing approximatimg a n ad- valowem scale introduced, ania discriminations were made in favor of the widow, children aria grana-chilaren. Th~e 5 tax was evaded by omitting to use receipts until 1796 when it was made a tax on the transfer itself and the t taking and giving of receipts s iaue compulsory and ex- ecutors and administrators,were uj.-iade personally liable for its payment. British legislation for two centuries has resulted in a complicated system of five distinct but alliea tax- es, known collectively as "Death duties" a name said to have been given them by Mr. Gladstone, ana separately as the probate, account, legacy, succession, and estate duties. (a) The "probate duty" is a name commonly applied to a stamp tax paid on the affidaavit required to be celivered before the issue of probate or letters of administra- tion.
Recommended publications
  • Exorbitant Privilege and Exorbitant Duty∗
    Exorbitant Privilege and Exorbitant Duty∗ Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas Hel´ ene` Rey Nicolas Govillot University of California at Berkeley London Business School Direction Gen´ erale´ du Tresor First dra: August 2010. is Version: October 25, 2017 Abstract We provide a quarterly time series of the historical evolution of US external assets and liabilities at market value on the 1952-2016 period. e center country of the International Monetary System enjoys an “exorbitant privilege”, a sizeable excess return of gross external assets over liabilities that signicantly weakens its external constraint. In exchange for this “exorbitant privilege” we document that the US provides insurance to the rest of the world, especially in times of global stress. We call this the “exorbitant duty” of the hegemon. During the 2007-2009 global nancial crisis, wealth transfers from the US to the rest of the world amounted to about 19% of US GDP. We present a stylized model that accounts for these facts and links the shrinking size of the hegemon in the world economy to the decline in the world real rate of interest. ∗We are very grateful to our discussants Jesus Fernandez Villaverde and Fabrizio Perri. We also thank Hanno Lustig and Adrien Verdelhan as well as 2017 NBER Summmer Institute participants for useful comments. Pierre- Olivier Gourinchas acknowledges nancial support from the International Growth Center grant RA-2009-11-002. Contact email: [email protected]´ ene` Rey is grateful for the funding of the European Research Council (grant number 695722). Email: [email protected] 1 Introduction Understanding the structure of the International Monetary System is an important task.
    [Show full text]
  • HVPE Prospectus
    MERRILL CORPORATION GTHOMAS// 1-NOV-07 23:00 DISK130:[07ZDA1.07ZDA48401]BA48401A.;44 mrll.fmt Free: 11DM/0D Foot: 0D/ 0D VJ J1:1Seq: 1 Clr: 0 DISK024:[PAGER.PSTYLES]UNIVERSAL.BST;67 8 C Cs: 17402 PROSPECTUS, DATED 2 NOVEMBER 2007 Global Offering of up to 40,000,000 Shares of 1NOV200718505053 This document describes related offerings of Class A ordinary shares (the ‘‘Shares’’) of HarbourVest Global Private Equity Limited (the ‘‘company’’), a closed-ended investment company organised under the laws of Guernsey. Our Shares are being offered (a) outside the United States, and (b) inside the United States in a private placement to certain qualified institutional buyers (‘‘QIBs’’) as defined in Rule 144A under the U.S. Securities Act of 1933, as amended (the ‘‘U.S. Securities Act’’), who are also qualified purchasers (‘‘qualified purchasers’’) as defined in the U.S. Investment Company Act of 1940, as amended (the ‘‘U.S. Investment Company Act’’) (the ‘‘Global Offering’’). We intend to issue up to 40,000,000 Shares in the Global Offering. In addition, we intend separately to issue Shares to certain third parties in a private placement in exchange for either cash or limited partnership interests in various HarbourVest-managed funds (the ‘‘Directed Offering’’ and, together with the Global Offering, the ‘‘Offerings’’). We will not issue, in the aggregate, more than 85,000,000 Shares in the Offerings. The Shares carry limited voting rights. No public market currently exists for the Shares. We have applied for the admission to trading all of the Shares on Euronext Amsterdam by NYSE Euronext (‘‘Euronext Amsterdam’’), the regulated market of Euronext Amsterdam N.V.
    [Show full text]
  • Following the Money: Lessons from the Panama Papers Part 1
    ARTICLE 3.4 - TRAUTMAN (DO NOT DELETE) 5/14/2017 6:57 AM Following the Money: Lessons from the Panama Papers Part 1: Tip of the Iceberg Lawrence J. Trautman* ABSTRACT Widely known as the “Panama Papers,” the world’s largest whistleblower case to date consists of 11.5 million documents and involves a year-long effort by the International Consortium of Investigative Journalists to expose a global pattern of crime and corruption where millions of documents capture heads of state, criminals, and celebrities using secret hideaways in tax havens. Involving the scrutiny of over 400 journalists worldwide, these documents reveal the offshore holdings of at least hundreds of politicians and public officials in over 200 countries. Since these disclosures became public, national security implications already include abrupt regime change and probable future political instability. It appears likely that important revelations obtained from these data will continue to be forthcoming for years to come. Presented here is Part 1 of what may ultimately constitute numerous- installment coverage of this important inquiry into the illicit wealth derived from bribery, corruption, and tax evasion. This article proceeds as follows. First, disclosures regarding the treasure trove of documents * BA, The American University; MBA, The George Washington University; JD, Oklahoma City Univ. School of Law. Mr. Trautman is Assistant Professor of Business Law and Ethics at Western Carolina University, and a past president of the New York and Metropolitan Washington/Baltimore Chapters of the National Association of Corporate Directors. He may be contacted at [email protected]. The author wishes to extend thanks to those at the Winter Conference of the Anti-Corruption Law Interest Group (ASIL) in Miami, January 13–14, 2017 who provided constructive comments to the manuscript, in particular: Eva Anderson; Bruce Bean; Ashleigh Buckett; Anita Cava; Shirleen Chin; Stuart H.
    [Show full text]
  • An Optimal Benefit-Based Corporate Income
    An optimal benefit-based corporate income tax Simon Naitram∗ June 2020 Abstract In this paper I explore the features of a benefit-based corporate income tax. Benefit-based taxation defines a firm’s fair share of tax as the returns to the public input. When the government is constrained to fund the public input through the use of a distortionary tax on the firm’s profit, the optimal benefit-based corporate income tax rate is a function of three estimable elasticities: the direct public input elasticity of profit, the indirect public input elasticity of profit, and the (net of) tax elasticity of profit. Using public capital as a measure of the public input, I calculate optimal benefit-based tax rates. Under plausible parameters, these optimal tax rates are quantitatively reasonable and are progressive. I show that benefit-based taxation delivers inter-nation equity. JEL: H21; H25; H32; H41 Keywords: benefit-based taxation; optimal corporate tax; public input 1 Introduction There is no consensus on the purpose of the corporate income tax. This lack of consensus on the purpose of the tax makes it almost impossible to agree on the design of the corporate tax system. Without guidelines on what we are trying to achieve, how do we assess any proposal for corporate tax reform? This concern is expressed most clearly by Weisbach(2015): \The basic point is that we cannot know what the optimal pattern of international capital income taxation should be without understanding the reasons for taxing capital income in the first place... To understand the design of firm-level taxation, however, we need to know why we are taxing firms.” ∗Adam Smith Business School, University of Glasgow and Department of Economics, University of the West Indies, Cave Hill, St Michael, Barbados.
    [Show full text]
  • Percentage Tax Designation Institutions. on Sugden's
    International Review of Economics (2021) 68:101–130 https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-021-00364-2 RESEARCH ARTICLE Percentage tax designation institutions. On Sugden’s contractarian account Paolo Silvestri1 Received: 12 September 2020 / Accepted: 27 January 2021 / Published online: 27 February 2021 © The Author(s) 2021 Abstract “Percentage Tax Designation Institutions”, also known as “Percentage Philanthropy Laws”, are fscal institutions through which taxpayers can freely designate a cer- tain percentage of their income tax to organizations whose main activity is of public interest: churches, third-sector organizations, political parties, etc. A comprehensive explanation of such systems is still lacking. In The Community of Advantage, Robert Sugden provides an original theoretical account of the Italian “8 × 1000” institution as one of those forms of regulation that “would be justifed as ways of expanding opportunity for mutually benefcial transactions” and, more particularly, as a lib- eral and “contractarian approach to the provision of public goods”. This article is an attempt to expand and deepen the understanding not only of the 8 × 1000 but also of the 5 × 1000 and 2 × 1000 institutions, by refecting on and possibly refning Sug- den’s contractarian account, at least with regard to the part that relies on and devel- ops the voluntary exchange tradition (Wicksell, Lindahl and Buchanan). To remain faithful to two normative premises of Sugden’s approach—the opportunity criterion and the correlated freedom of choice—we must introduce some theoretical adjust- ments to take into due account the way in which taxpayers’ freedoms—not only freedom of choice but also autonomy—are afected by default rules and the related redistribution procedures.
    [Show full text]
  • Ocument’’) and You Are Therefore Advised to Read This Carefully Before Reading, Accessing Or Making Any Other Use of the Attached Document
    NOT FOR DISTRIBUTION DIRECTLY OR INDIRECTLY IN OR INTO THE UNITED STATES OR TO ANY U.S. PERSON IMPORTANT: You must read the following disclaimer before continuing. The following disclaimer applies to the attached prospectus (the ‘‘document’’) and you are therefore advised to read this carefully before reading, accessing or making any other use of the attached document. In accessing the document, you agree to be bound by the following terms and conditions, including any modifications to them from time to time, each time you receive any information from us as a result of such access. You acknowledge that this electronic transmission and the delivery of the attached document is confidential and intended only for you and you agree you will not forward, reproduce or publish this electronic transmission or the attached document to any other person. The document and the offer when made are only addressed to and directed at persons in member states of the European Economic Area (“EEA”) who are “qualified investors” within the meaning of Article 2(1)(e) of the Prospectus Directive (Directive 2003/71/EC) (the “Prospectus Directive”) (“Qualified Investors”). In addition, in the United Kingdom (“UK”), this document is being distributed only to, and is directed only at, Qualified Investors (i) who have professional experience in matters relating to investments falling within Article 19(5) of the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (Financial Promotion) Order 2005, as amended (the “Order”) and Qualified Investors falling within Article 49 of the Order, and (ii) to whom it may otherwise lawfully be communicated (all such persons together being referred to as “relevant persons”).
    [Show full text]
  • Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States
    1 Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States GA Res. 3281(xxix), UN GAOR, 29th Sess., Supp. No. 31 (1974) 50 The General Assembly, Recalling that the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, in its resolution 45 (III) of 18 May 1972, stressed the urgency to establish generally accepted norms to govern international economic relations systematically and recognized that it is not feasible to establish a just order and a stable workd as long as a charger to protect the rights of all countries, and in particular the developing States, is not formulated. Recalling further that in the same resolution it was decided to establish a Working Group of governmental representatives to draw up a draft Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States, which the General Assembly, in its resolution 3037 (XXVII) of 19 December 1972, decided should be composed of forty Member States. Noting that, in its resolution 3082 (XXVIII) of 6 December 1973, it reaffirmed its conviction of the urgent need to establish or improve norms of universal application for the development of international economic relations on a just and equitable basis and urged the Working Group on the Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States to complete, as the first step in the codification and development of the matter, the elaboration of a final draft Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States, to be considered and approved by the General Assembly at its twenty-ninth session. Bearing in mind the spirit and terms of its resolutions 3201 (S-VI) and 3202 (S-VI) of 1 May 1974, containing, respectively, the Declaration and the Programmed of Action on the Establishment of a New International Economic Order, which underlined the vital importance of the Charter to be adopted by the General Assembly at its twenty-ninth session and stressed the fact that the Charter shall constitute an effective instrument towards the establishment of a new system of international economic relations based on equity, sovereign equality and interdependence of the interests of developed and developing countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Free Versus Fair Trade: the Dumping Issue Thomas Klitgaard and Karen Schiele
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE August 1998 Volume 4 Number 8 Free versus Fair Trade: The Dumping Issue Thomas Klitgaard and Karen Schiele Trade liberalization has had little effect on the use of antidumping tariffs—tariffs imposed on imports judged by a government to be unfairly priced. As more countries resort to such tariffs, questions arise about the merits of this form of trade protection, particularly when other remedies are available to industries hurt by import competition. In recent years, the international community has made and review the claims made for and against this type of significant progress in lowering trade barriers. The trade barrier. Although we cannot evaluate these claims Uruguay Round of trade negotiations, the North in detail, our analysis points to problems in both the theory American Free Trade Agreement, and the Information and the application of antidumping regulations. Technology Agreement are eliminating or sharply Following our discussion of these problems, we identify reducing tariffs and customs duties on imports in many alternative remedies available to industries coping with areas of the world. In addition, these agreements are unfair competition. dismantling nontariff barriers to trade, including quotas on exports of textiles and apparel and the export The Growing Use of Antidumping Tariffs restraints that protected such major U.S. industries as The use of tariffs to target specific imports began in steel and autos in the 1980s (see box). 1904, when Canada sought to discourage a U.S. manu- Although these agreements have removed many facturer from selling steel to the Canadian railroads.
    [Show full text]
  • “Optimal Taxation & Provision of Public Goods”
    1 DEPARTMENT OF INTERNATIONAL AND EUROPEAN ECONOMIC STUDIES “Optimal Taxation & Provision of Public Goods” Spyridon Kypraios 4150055 Supervisor: George Economides Athens June 2019 2 3 Abstract This inquiry presents the optimal way of financing a public good through taxes with the construction of three alternative simple models of optimal taxation and public good provision. In the first model, the public good affects only the household‟s utility. In the second model, the public good affects only the firm‟s production. In the third model, the public good affects both the household‟s utility and the firm‟s production. My target is to solve for the optimal income tax levels in the three models. Also, I tried to find an established relation between the tax levels and the importance which have the public good for the households and the firms. A bibliographic research shows the theory of public goods, the classification of the goods in general and the significance which have nowadays via global public goods. Furthermore, this paper explains the connection of the public goods with all the theories of political economy during the history. It represents some basic first best solutions (without taxes) such as Samuelson and Lindhal solutions. In addition, it illustrates the free riding problem and potential solutions of it. In the end, I describe and analyze some useful conclusions about the optimal taxation and provision of public goods. Keywords: Public Goods, Free Riding, Optimal Taxation, First Best Solutions, Second Best Solutions, Public Provision Acknowledgment This inquiry was conducted in my fourth final year in Athens University of Economics and Business.
    [Show full text]
  • Customs and Tariff
    Section 14 Customs and Related Taxes Legal Notice N0. 18/1994 Custom Tariff Regulations Article 1. Short Title These regulations may be cited as “the Custom Tariff Regulations No. 18 of the 1994” Article 2. Repeals All tariff regulations and directives which have been in force are hereby Repealed by these regulations and directives issued there under. Article 3. Tariff All imports into and exports from Eritrea shall be governed by the following Customs tariff: 1 FIRST SCHEDULE CUSTOMS IMPORT TAFIFF 2 Div. No Item Rate Section 0- Foodstuffs, Beasts of burden and live Animals chiefly for food 00 Beasts of burden and animals for food 1. Cattle 2% 2. Sheep 2% 3. Goat 2% 4. Mule 2% 5. Horse 2% 6. Camel 2% 7. Donkey 2% 8. Chicken duck, Turkey, fowls 2% 9. Pig 2% 10. Other animals used for food not included here 2% 01 Meat and Meat preparation 1. Fresh bovine meat 50% 2. Fresh meat of sheep and goats 50% 3. Fresh Chicken meat 50% 4. Fresh meat of swine 50% 5. Canned meat, of various type 50% 6. Canned meat sauce 50% 7. Salted and dried meat 50% 8. Any other edible meat 50% 02 Dairy Products and Birds egg 1. Concentrated milk, sweetened and canned 50% 2. Milk, not concentrated, not sweetened: yoghurt, whey…. etc. 50% 3. Powdered milk in sacks 10% 4. Powdered milk, canned ex. cerelac, lactogen, Nido, My bay…..etc. 10% 5. Animal derived butter 10% 3 6. Butter oil 10% 7. Cheese, curd 50% 8. Eggs, dried eggs (powdered) 10% Div.
    [Show full text]
  • Jury Duty Is a Poll Tax: the Case for Severing the Link Between Voter Registration and Jury Service
    Jury Duty is a Poll Tax: The Case for Severing the Link Between Voter Registration and Jury Service ∗ ALEXANDER E. PRELLER Federal jury service has been formally connected to voter registration since 1968. Congress intended for this linkage to improve the American jury system by increasing representation of groups previously excluded from the jury pool. However, as legislative inaction and judicial acquiescence have exacerbated the economic costs of jury service, this practice has also para- sitically burdened the right to vote, creating a “self-disenfranchising incen- tive.” This Note argues that jury duty is sufficiently burdensome, and that this burden sufficiently impacts voting, so as to constitute a poll tax in vio- lation of the Twenty-Fourth Amendment and the Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. There is a simple, effective solution to this problem: prohibiting the use of voter registration lists to create jury lists, and instead using any number of available alternative sources to create a representative jury pool. I. INTRODUCTION People hate getting jury duty.1 Even those who enjoy serving on a jury report that they try to avoid it whenever possible.2 One ∗ Articles Editor, COLUM.J.L.&SOC.PROBS., 2012−13. J.D. Candidate 2013, Co- lumbia Law School. The author would like to thank Professors Jamal Greene, Richard Briffault and Mark Barenberg, as well as the Journal’s editorial staff, for their help. 1. See generally K.B. Battaglini et al., Jury Patriotism: The Jury System Should Be Improved for Texans Called to Serve, 35 ST.MARY'S L. J. 117 (2003); Mark A.
    [Show full text]
  • The Constitutionality of National Anti-Poll Tax Bills
    University of Minnesota Law School Scholarship Repository Minnesota Law Review 1949 The onsC titutionality of National Anti-Poll Tax Bills Janice E. Christensen Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mlr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Christensen, Janice E., "The onC stitutionality of National Anti-Poll Tax Bills" (1949). Minnesota Law Review. 1583. https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mlr/1583 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the University of Minnesota Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in Minnesota Law Review collection by an authorized administrator of the Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW Journal of the State Bar Assoczatwn VOLUME 33 FEBRUARY, 1949 No. 3 THE CONSTITUTIONALITY OF NATIONAL ANTI-POLL TAX BILLS JANICE E. CHRISTENSEN* V ITAL constitutional issues are posed by the anti-poll tax bills debated in Congress during the past decade. These bills seek to abolish the requirement now prevailing in seven southern states that a poll taxi of one to two dollars be paid before voting in national elections.2 In providing for the abolition of the poll tax requirement for voting, the bills raise the broad constitutional issue of the relative powers of the nation and states in national elections under our federal system. The issue is raised primarily because the bills propose to broaden national control of voting qualifications and requirements hitherto largely within the province of the states. That unprecedented national control is envisaged is indicated by *Instructor in Government, University of Texas.
    [Show full text]