Copyrighted Material Not for Distribution

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Copyrighted Material Not for Distribution Contents MATERIAL List of Figures vii List of Tables xi 1. Surplus: The Politics of ProductionDISTRIBUTION and the Strategies of Everyday and Life—An Introduction Christopher T. Morehart and Kristin De Lucia 3 FOR 2. The Cost ofCOPYRIGHTED Conquest: Assessing the Impact of Inka Tribute Demands on the Wanka of Highland Peru Cathy Lynne CostinNOT 45 3. Surplus and Social Change: The Production of Household and Field in Pre-Aztec Central Mexico Kristin De Lucia and Christopher T. Morehart 73 4. Surplus in the Indus Civilization: Agricultural Choices, Social Relations, Political Effects Heather M.-L. Miller 97 v vi Contents 5. Surplus from Below: Self-Organization of Production in Early Sweden T. L. Thurston 121 6. From Surplus Land to Surplus Production in the Viking Age Settlement of Iceland Douglas J. Bolender 153 7. Surplus Capture in Contrasting Modes of Religiosity: Perspectives from Sixteenth-Century Mesoamerica E. Christian Wells 175 8. Surplus Houses: Palace Politics in the Bight of Benin West Africa, AD 1650–1727 Neil L. Norman 203 9. Surplus Labor, Ceremonial Feasting, and Social Inequality at Cahokia: A Study MATERIALin Social Process James A. Brown and John E. Kelly 221 10. The Sociality of Surplus among Late Archaic Hunter-Gatherers of CoastalDISTRIBUTION Georgia Victor D. Thompson and Christopher R. Moore 245 11. The Transactional DynamicsFOR of Surplus in LandscapesCOPYRIGHTED of Enslavement: Scalar Perspectives from Interstitial West Africa Ann B. StahlNOT 267 12. Conclusions: Surplus and the Political Economy in Prehistory Timothy Earle 307 List of Contributors 327 Index 329 Figures 2.1. Inka empire MATERIAL 47 2.2. Ubiquity of hoes in Wanka II and Wanka III contexts, by household status 49 2.3. Evidence for the differential production and preparation of maize in Wanka II households DISTRIBUTION 50 2.4. Results of stable isotope analysis of Wanka II human bone collagen, illustrating similarity in eliteFOR and commoner diets 51 2.5. Distribution of tools used in cloth production in Wanka 53 2.6. Increase inCOPYRIGHTED maize production and consumption from Wanka II to Wanka III NOT 61 3.1. Map of the Basin of Mexico showing location of Xaltocan and other sites 78 3.2. Reconstructed map of Xaltocan’s chinampa system 79 3.3. Map of Structure 1 showing locations of rooms and features 81 4.1. Map of the Indus Valley and surrounding areas 102 4.2. Land-use zones of the Indus Valley floodplains 103 4.3. Water management regimes and zones of the Indus Valley floodplains 104 5.1. Sweden in the eleventh and twelfth centuries 122 vii viii Figures 5.2. Småland Plateau 124 5.3. Cairn areas of early vs. late clearance 131 5.4. Development of infrastructure in early Jönköping 134 5.5. Four study blocks with varying proximity to state-building infrastructure 137 5.6. Example of settlement phases and expansions—Skärstad-Ölmstad Valley 140 6.1. Land claims and later farm properties in Skagafjörður, northern Iceland 156 6.2. Chayanov’s model defining labor effort to meet household subsistence needs based on the marginal utility and increasing drudgery associated with increased work 157 6.3. Chayanov model of household production limits modified to define marginal threshold for surplus farmland 160 6.4. Settlement pattern in the Langholt survey region showing the timing and size of new farm establishment 162 6.5. Chayanov line defining expected laborMATERIAL effort based on household consumer-to-work ratio and the relative position of “overproducing” tenant and “underproducing” landlord households 167 6.6. Shift ni relative marginal utility of land as landlord households establish tenant farms on their land 168 7.1. Folios 97b and 102d from the MadridDISTRIBUTION Codex (ca. AD 1300–1500?) 185 7.2. Folio 64 from Book 9 of Sahagún’s Florentine Codex (1575–77), showing Nahua “featherFOR workers” with rectangular panels of green maguey cactus fiber and white cotton 193 8.1. Gbe polities,COPYRIGHTED Bight of Benin region, West Africa 205 8.2. ArchaeologicalNOT survey of Huedan countryside 207 8.3. Broken vessel fragments along curving arc of wall 211 8.4. Vessel containing human cranium 212 8.5. Contents of a shrine during excavation 213 9.1. Map of the center of Cahokia showing areas discussed in text 233 10.1. Location of selected shell ring sites in the American Southeast 250 10.2. LiDAR map of the Sapelo Island Shell Ring complex (9MC23) 253 10.3. Sapelo Island Shell Ring complex in relation to the broader landscape showing islands, ocean, and marshland 255 Figures ix 10.4. Photograph of Ring I and profile drawings of the crushed shell lens from the 1950 excavation 258 11.1. Metallurgical workshop at Ngre Kataa in the Banda area, Ghana 270 11.2. “Capping” shrine cluster centered on unit 48N 8W, Ngre Kataa, Banda, Ghana 271 11.3. Model of “Wealth-in-People” depicting overlapping constituencies of free and enslaved groups and the movements into and out of free and enslaved status through fictive kinship, pawning, and witchcraft accusation 278 11.4. Map of Banda in relation to Saharan and Atlantic networks 281 11.5. Shifting configuration of Banda production and exchange vis-à-vis the reorientation of trade to Atlantic networks 283 11.6. Shrine cluster, Unit 44N 6W, metal-working workshop, Ngre Kataa, Banda, Ghana 285 MATERIAL DISTRIBUTION FOR COPYRIGHTED NOT Tables 2.1. Estimates of calories in chicha MATERIAL 55 2.2. Caloric loss in producing chicha, assuming 3,470 calories per kg of maiz de jora seca and 280 calories per liter of chicha 55 2.3. Estimates of labor expended in weaving; all items were made of wool and woven on a backstrap loom DISTRIBUTION 59 2.4. Estimates of the amount of land and labor needed to produce chicha for imperial personnel at FORHatun Xauxa 65 2.5. Potential unmet food needs if maize grown in 10-km catchment around the Inka administrativeCOPYRIGHTED center, Hatun Xauxa, was used in chicha production NOT 66 4.1. Possible cropping regimes in Indus Valley floodplains 101 4.2. Agricultural regime models for Indus Valley floodplains 107 4.3. Land ownership implications for Indus Valley floodplains 108 xi CHAPTER ONE Surplus: The Politics of Production and the Strategies of Everyday Life An Introduction Christopher T. Morehart and Kristin De Lucia Archaeologists identify surplus as a central pivotMATERIAL in the big issues of historical change: the development of state society, the emergence of inequality and social stratification, the creation and intensification of agriculture, specialization and technological evolution, the division of labor (including between men and women), the formation of exchange networks andDISTRIBUTION markets, the beginning of sedentism and eventually urban life. Observed through the lenses of such macro-theoretical issues, surplus occupies an interpretive position not unlike other variables considered to be basic “triggers” to societal transformation,FOR such as demographic growth and cli- matological change. Like these variables, the role of surplus in reconstructions of change is often COPYRIGHTEDvague, assumed, and monolithic or is difficult to pinpoint in rela- tion to emergent conditionsNOT in a sociopolitical landscape (Dalton 1960). “The pro- duction of surplus . permitted the . .” is a common phrase repeated throughout archaeological literature to explain why changes occurred but also why societies in the past seemingly became more like our own. Surplus’s legacy in archaeology is associated closely with social evolutionary models of change. Such models tend to emanate from top-down approaches to political economy, conceived either managerially or coercively (see Brumfiel and Earle 1987), and view surplus production as part of macro-level processes. However, the explicit study of surplus as a major intellectual theme has become less common today than during the heyday of the New Archaeology from the 1960s through the 1980s. With the rise of theoretical perspectives influenced by “post-processual” DOI: 10.5876/9781607323808.c001 3 4 Christopher T. Morehart AND Kristin DE Lucia critique, many archaeologists have progressively either rejected the targeted study of surplus or simply abandoned it in favor of the social and cultural dimensions of consumption. The analyses of important social archaeological topics, such as identity, being, temporality, and materiality (e.g., Meskell and Preucel 2007), we argue, are essentially matters of consumption. They represent an intellectual shift toward subjectivity, particularly through its experiential and phenomenological dimensions. Some scholars have argued, however, that when taken to an extreme, such approaches lead to a “bleaching” (Carrier 1997) of production in favor of consumption, either producing an idealized romantization of the past or imped- ing archaeological understanding of history’s material reality (see Brumfiel 1992; Harvey 1989; Jameson 1991; Trigger 1998). These studies also can be overly particu- larlistic, rejecting the existence of common processes operating in otherwise very different sociocultural contexts and inhibiting efforts to promote a comparative anthropology and archaeology. However, as the studies in this volume attest and the critical genealogy of sur- plus reveals, the social dynamics of consumption are inextricably tied to production. The politics that produce subjects and surplus are always entangled with consump- tion (see Ekstrom and Brembeck 2004; MillerMATERIAL 1987), in ways that differ depend- ing on the social, temporal, and geographic scale at which we focus our analytical gaze. A dialectical tie—simultaneously biological, physical, material, and cultural— between consumption and production is a major relationship that shapes not only practice but also historical change, a dynamic that few fields but archaeology can truly capture. Archaeologically, indeed,DISTRIBUTION our narratives of surplus often emanate not from an abstract conception of productive capacity but from the material results of this dialectic—the archaeological record. Even in social anthropology, this duality cannot be easily resolved despiteFOR the ethnographer’s ability to engage with living and speaking subjects.
Recommended publications
  • Gifts and Commodities (Second Edition)
    GIFTS AND COMMODITIES Hau BOOKS Executive Editor Giovanni da Col Managing Editor Sean M. Dowdy Editorial Board Anne-Christine Taylor Carlos Fausto Danilyn Rutherford Ilana Gershon Jason Throop Joel Robbins Jonathan Parry Michael Lempert Stephan Palmié www.haubooks.com GIFTS AND COMMODITIES (SECOND EditIon) C. A. Gregory Foreword by Marilyn Strathern New Preface by the Author Hau Books Chicago © 2015 by C. A. Gregory and Hau Books. First Edition © 1982 Academic Press, London. All rights reserved. Cover and layout design: Sheehan Moore Typesetting: Prepress Plus (www.prepressplus.in) ISBN: 978-0-9905050-1-3 LCCN: 2014953483 Hau Books Chicago Distribution Center 11030 S. Langley Chicago, IL 60628 www.haubooks.com Hau Books is marketed and distributed by The University of Chicago Press. www.press.uchicago.edu Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper. For Judy, Polly, and Melanie. Contents Foreword by Marilyn Strathern xi Preface to the first edition xv Preface to the second edition xix Acknowledgments liii Introduction lv PART ONE: CONCEPTS I. THE COmpETING THEOriES 3 Political economy 3 The theory of commodities 3 The theory of gifts 9 Economics 19 The theory of modern goods 19 The theory of traditional goods 22 II. A framEWORK OF ANALYSIS 25 The general relation of production to consumption, distribution, and exchange 26 Marx and Lévi-Strauss on reproduction 26 A simple illustrative example 30 The definition of particular economies 32 viii GIFTS AND COMMODITIES III.FTS GI AND COMMODITIES: CIRCULATION 39 The direct exchange of things 40 The social status of transactors 40 The social status of objects 41 The spatial aspect of exchange 44 The temporal dimension of exchange 46 Value and rank 46 The motivation of transactors 50 The circulation of things 55 Velocity of circulation 55 Roads of gift-debt 57 Production and destruction 59 The circulation of people 62 Work-commodities 62 Work-gifts 62 Women-gifts 63 Classificatory kinship terms and prices 68 Circulation and distribution 69 IV.
    [Show full text]
  • Play As a Foundation for Hunter-Gatherer Social Existence
    Play as a Foundation for Hunter- Gatherer Social Existence • Peter Gray The author offers the thesis that hunter-gatherers promoted, through cultural means, the playful side of their human nature and this made possible their egalitar- ian, nonautocratic, intensely cooperative ways of living. Hunter-gatherer bands, with their fluid membership, are likened to social-play groups, which people could freely join or leave. Freedom to leave the band sets the stage for the individual autonomy, sharing, and consensual decision making within the band. Hunter- gatherers used humor, deliberately, to maintain equality and stop quarrels. Their means of sharing had gamelike qualities. Their religious beliefs and ceremonies were playful, founded on assumptions of equality, humor, and capriciousness among the deities. They maintained playful attitudes in their hunting, gathering, and other sustenance activities, partly by allowing each person to choose when, how, and how much they would engage in such activities. Children were free to play and explore, and through these activities, they acquired the skills, knowl- edge, and values of their culture. Play, in other mammals as well as in humans, counteracts tendencies toward dominance, and hunter-gatherers appear to have promoted play quite deliberately for that purpose. I am a developmental/evolutionary psychologist with a special inter- est in play. Some time ago, I began reading the anthropological literature on hunter-gatherer societies in order to understand how children’s play might contribute to children’s education in those societies. As I read, I became in- creasingly fascinated with hunter-gatherer social life per se. The descriptions I read, by many different researchers who had observed many different hunter- gatherer groups, seemed to be replete with examples of humor and playfulness in adults, not just in children, in all realms of hunter-gatherers’ social existence.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Do the Indians Wear Adidas? Or, Culture Contact and the Relations of Consumption Richard R
    1984 Unpublished Article Why do the Indians Wear Adidas? Or, Culture Contact and the Relations of Consumption Richard R. Wilk and Eric J. Arnould Abstract Page 1 of 31 The study of the consumption of goods has never achieved the JBA 5(1): 6-36 prominence in anthropology of either production or exchange. Yet the Autumn 2016 accelerating consumption of western goods in non-western societies is © The Author(s) 2016 one of the most obtrusive cultural and economic trends of the last three ISSN 2245-4217 centuries. This article addresses the general issue of why goods flow www.cbs.dk/jba between cultural groups by re-examining the concept of consumption. It raises questions of importance to studies of development, material culture, ethnohistory, and symbolic anthropology. Keywords Economic anthropology, consumption, acculturation, symbolic anthropology, material culture Wilk and Arnould / Why do the Indians Wear Adidas? Introduction Peruvian Indians carry around small rectangular rocks painted to look like transistor radios.1 San Blas Cuna households hoard boxes of dolls, safety pins, children's hats and shoes, marbles, enamelware kettles, and bedsheets with pillowcases in their original cellophane wrappings. Japanese newlyweds cut three-tiered white frosted inedible cakes topped with plastic figures in western dress. Q’eqchi’ Maya swidden farmers relax at night listening to Freddie Fender on a portable cassette player while Bana tribesmen in Kako, Ethiopia, pay a hefty price to look through a Viewmaster at “Pluto Tries to Become a Circus Dog.” Tibetans, bitterly opposed to Chinese rule, sport Mao caps. Young Wayana Indians in Surinam spend hours manipulating a Rubik's cube.
    [Show full text]
  • Is Settling Good for Pastoralists?
    Is Settling Good for Pastoralists? The Effects of Pastoral Sedentarization on Children’s Nutrition, Growth, and Health Among Rendille and Ariaal of Marsabit District, Northern Kenya Elliot Fratkin, Martha A Nathan, and Eric A. Roth Elliot Fratkin PhD, Department of Anthropology, Smith College, Northampton, Massachusetts 01063 USA and Graduate Faculty, Department of Anthropology, University of Massachusetts-Amherst, Amherst MA 01002 USA ([email protected] for correspondence) Martha A Nathan MD, Brightwood Health Center, Baystate Medical Center, 380 Plainfield Street, Springfield MA 01107 and Tufts University School of Medicine, Boston MA Massachusetts 02111 ([email protected]) Eric A. Roth PhD, Department of Anthropology, University of Victoria, P.O. Box 3050, Victoria, British Columbia Presentation for “Pastoralism and Poverty Reduction in East Africa: A Policy Research Conference” International Livestock Research Institute, 27-28 June 2006, Nairobi Abstract The settling of formerly mobile pastoral populations is occurring rapidly throughout East Africa. Pastoral sedentarization has been encouraged by international development agencies and national governments to alleviate problems of food insecurity, health care delivery, and national integration. However, it has not been demonstrated that abandoning the pastoral way of life, and particularly access to livestock products, has been beneficial to the health and well-being of pastoral populations. This paper reports the results of a three-year study of pastoral and settled Rendille and Ariaal (mixed Samburu/Rendille) communities in Marsabit District northern Kenya, which compares levels of child malnutrition and illness between five different Rendille communities, ranging from purely pastoral to agricultural and urban communities. Analysis of bimonthly dietary recalls, anthropometric measurements, morbidity data, and economic differentiation and specialization among 202 mothers and their 488 children under age 9 reveals large differences in the growth patterns and morbidity of nomadic vs.
    [Show full text]
  • Sacredness in an Experimental Chamber
    BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29, 161–209 Printed in the United States of America Moneyastool,moneyasdrug:The biological psychology of a strong incentive Stephen E. G. Lea University of Exeter, School of Psychology, Washington Singer Laboratories, Exeter EX4 4QG, United Kingdom [email protected] http://www.exeter.ac.uk/SEGLea Paul Webley University of Exeter, School of Psychology, Washington Singer Laboratories, Exeter EX4 4QG, United Kingdom [email protected] http://www.exeter.ac.uk/pwebley Abstract: Why are people interested in money? Specifically, what could be the biological basis for the extraordinary incentive and reinforcing power of money, which seems to be unique to the human species? We identify two ways in which a commodity which is of no biological significance in itself can become a strong motivator. The first is if it is used as a tool, and by a metaphorical extension this is often applied to money: it is used instrumentally, in order to obtain biologically relevant incentives. Second, substances can be strong motivators because they imitate the action of natural incentives but do not produce the fitness gains for which those incentives are instinctively sought. The classic examples of this process are psychoactive drugs, but we argue that the drug concept can also be extended metaphorically to provide an account of money motivation. From a review of theoretical and empirical literature about money, we conclude that (i) there are a number of phenomena that cannot be accounted for by a pure Tool Theory of money motivation; (ii) supplementing Tool Theory with a Drug Theory enables the anomalous phenomena to be explained; and (iii) the human instincts that, according to a Drug Theory, money parasitizes include trading (derived from reciprocal altruism) and object play.
    [Show full text]
  • Exploring Exchange and Direct Procurement Strategies for Natufian
    www.nature.com/scientificreports OPEN Exploring exchange and direct procurement strategies for Natufan food processing tools of el‑Wad Terrace, Israel Danny Rosenberg1*, Tatjana M. Gluhak2, Daniel Kaufman3, Reuven Yeshurun3 & Mina Weinstein‑Evron3 We present the results of a detailed geochemical provenance study of 54 Natufan (ca. 15,000– 11,700 cal. BP) basalt pestles from the site of el‑Wad Terrace (EWT), Israel. It is the frst time precise locations from where basalt raw materials were derived are provided. The results indicate that the Natufan hunter‑gatherers used multiple sources of basaltic rocks, distributed over a large area surrounding the Sea of Galilee. This area is located at a considerable distance from EWT, ca. 60–120 km away, in a region where contemporaneous Natufan basecamps are few. We consider two possible models that suggest vehicles for the transportation of these artifacts to EWT, namely the exchange obtaining model (EOM) and the direct procurement model (DPM). We argue that these mechanisms are not mutually exclusive and may have operated together. We also suggest that at a time of increasing Natufan territoriality, a large area around the Sea of Galilee remained unclaimed. The paper concludes with a brief discussion of the implications for the two models. In particular, we note that the DPM implies that technological know‑how for pestle production was maintained within the EWT community. Te nascence of sedentism profoundly impacted human societies’ mobility patterns, requiring a host of adjust- ments. Among its immediate implications are economic intensifcation and preoccupation with production and territoriality, both within and across communities.
    [Show full text]
  • The Anthropology of Money
    ANRV287-AN35-02 ARI 13 August 2006 6:41 The Anthropology of Money Bill Maurer Department of Anthropology, University of California, Irvine, California 92697–5100; email: [email protected] Annu. Rev. Anthropol. 2006. 35:15–36 Key Words First published online as a Review in abstraction, commensuration, currency, finance, number, Advance on July 6, 2006 quantification The Annual Review of Anthropology is by University of California - Irvine on 09/21/06. For personal use only. online at anthro.annualreviews.org Abstract This article’s doi: This review surveys anthropological and other social research on Annu. Rev. Anthropol. 2006.35:15-36. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org 10.1146/annurev.anthro.35.081705.123127 money and finance. It emphasizes money’s social roles and meanings Copyright c 2006 by Annual Reviews. as well as its pragmatics in different modalities of exchange and circu- All rights reserved lation. It reviews scholarly emphasis on modern money’s distinctive 0084-6570/06/1021-0015$20.00 qualities of commensuration, abstraction, quantification, and reifi- cation. It also addresses recent work that seeks to understand the social, semiotic, and performative dimensions of finance. Although anthropology has contributed finely grained, historicized accounts of the impact of modern money, it too often repeats the same story of the “great transformation” from socially embedded to disembedded and abstracted economic forms. This review speculates about why money’s fictions continue to surprise. 15 ANRV287-AN35-02 ARI 13 August 2006 6:41 INTRODUCTION: THE COIN’S The difficulty in reviewing the anthropol- MANY SIDES ogy of money is compounded by the reliance of much anthropological research on theories A special difficulty arises when reviewing the of meaning and symbol that derived analyt- anthropology of money.
    [Show full text]
  • Downloaded From
    J. Alexander P. Alexander Commodification and consumption in a central Borneo community In: Bijdragen tot de Taal-, Land- en Volkenkunde 151 (1995), no: 2, Leiden, 179-193 This PDF-file was downloaded from http://www.kitlv-journals.nl Downloaded from Brill.com10/02/2021 07:02:47PM via free access JENNIFER ALEXANDER AND PAUL ALEXANDER Commodification and Consumption in a Central Borneo Community A long-established tradition of explanation in anthropology and social history has seen money as the principal mechanism promoting individu- alism and greed, and consequently subverting values of community. When money enters a society, so the argument runs, commodification rapidly follows, initially altering consumption patterns and later transforming pro- duction relationships as well. In one recent formulation, money conquers the internal economy of non-monetized societies, setting free the 'drive inherent in every exchange system towards optimum commoditization' (Kopytoff 1986:72). Other anthropological studies, however, suggest that this view of the association between monetization and commoditization is far too simple; when they have had the power to do so, non-industrialized communities have demonstrated a remarkable ability to domesticate money and to resist any presumption that equality in price is equivalent to equal- ity in value (e.g., Parry and Bloch 1989; Humphrey and Hugh-Jones 1992). This essay is concerned with the ways in which a relatively remote and very small Central Borneo community, that of the Lahanan, has responded to its increasingly rapid incorporation into the world system. The speed and the extent of changes, more often than not initiated from outside, are undeniable. In the past thirty years, new forms of political power have been established; new medical, educational and, to a much lesser degree, agricultural services have been welcomed; and some parts of the economy have been commodified.
    [Show full text]
  • 314131983.Pdf
    Economic Anthropology History, Ethl:)ography, Critique Chris Han� and Keith Hart 'I Dolity ' II ' I I Copyright© Chris Hann and Keith Hart 2011 The right of Chris Hann and Keith Hart to be identified as Authors ofthis Work has been asserted in accordance with the UK Copyright, Designs and Patents Act Contents 1988. First published in 2011 by Polity Press Reprinted in 2011 Polity Press 65 Bridge Street Cambridge CB2 1 UR, UK Polity Press Preface lX 350 Main Street Malden, MA 02148, USA 1 Introduction: Economic Anthropology 1 3 All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purpose Some Issues of Method 'r of criticism and review, no part of this publication may be reproduced, stored 'I 6 :,1, The Human Economy in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, Critical Anthropology 9 mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior permission Organization of the Book 15 of the publisher. 2 Economy from the Ancient World to the Age of the ISBN-13: 978-0-7456-4482-0 Internet 18 ISBN-13: 978-0-7456-4483-7(pb) 'I 1 8 I, Economy as Household Management Medieval and Early Modern Roots of Economic A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. Theory 20 24 Typeset in 11 on 13 pt Sabon The Rise of Political Economy by Servis Filmsetting Ltd, Stockport, Cheshire The Economic Anthropology of Karl Marx 27 Printed and bound in the United States by Odyssey Press Inc., Gonic, New Hampshire National Capitalism and Beyond 29 Conclusion 34 The publisher has used its best endeavours to ensure that the URLs for external 3 The Rise of Modern Economics and Anthropology 37 websites referred to in this book are correct and active at the time of going to The German Tradition 39 press.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Anthropology History, Ethnography, Critique
    Economic Anthropology History, Ethnography, Critique Chris Hann and Keith Hart polity Economic Anthropology also historians and sociologists (and many varieties under each of those labels) - must join forces. Some economists 1 claim a special status for their discipline and locate it closer to the 'hard' sciences than to 'soft' disciplines in the humanities. We take a critical and historical view of such claims, but it is Introduction: Economic not our intention to offer a romantic, utopian alternative to Anthropology economics. We are aware that economics is in some ways as diverse as anthropology. Our aim is to bring the two closer together and this makes us critical of mainstream positions on both sides. Previous accounts of economic anthropology linked it to the founding fathers of modern social theory - notably Marx, Weber and Durkheim. Occasionally the history was Anthropologists aim to discover the principles of · social traced back to the political economists of the Enlightenment. organization at every level from the most particular to the We argue that the core questions are much older than this. universal. The purpose of economic anthropology in the nine­ Ultimately, economic anthropology addresses questions of teenth century, even before it took shape as 'the economics of human nature and well-being, questions that have preoc­ primitive man', was to test the claim that a world economic cupied every society's philosophers from the beginning. We order must be founded on the principles that underpinned make a case for an economic anthropology that is able to a Western industrial society striving for universality. The investigate this 'human economy' anywhere in time and search was on for alternatives that might support a more just space, as a creation of all humanity.
    [Show full text]
  • Beyond Affluent Foragers: Rethinking Hunter-Gatherer Complexity
    BOOK REVIEW Beyond affluent foragers: rethinking hunter-gatherer complexity Proceedings of the 9th Conference of the International Council of Archaeozoology. Durham August 2002. Editors: C Grier, J Kim, J Uchiyama Series Editors: P Rowley-Conwy, U Albarella, K Dobney ISBN 1-84217-125-9 Oxford: Oxbow Books, 2006 viii prelims, 200 pages, 126 figures £40.00 or $80.00 Whither affluently complex hunter-forager-gatherers? Kenneth M Ames Portland State University, Department of Anthropology, PO Box 751, Portland OR 97207, USA [email protected] Introduction and set out the goals for the current volume: Edited volumes play major roles in the affluent forager/ Over twenty years ago, “Affluent Foragers” was coined as a short hand term for the specific complex hunter-gather literature as they do for hunter- socioeconomic conditions of coastal fisher-hunters gatherer studies generally. Establishing the intellectual in productive environments. A central implication lineages among edited volumes is also important. The of this label was that during the Holocene certain prehistoric groups were recognized as having volumes growing out of the International Conferences achieved highly organized social structures and on Hunter-Gatherers (CHAGS) descend directly from high degrees of sedentism in the course of Man the Hunter. For affluent forager studies, the adapting to temperate coastal environments (Koyama & Uchiyama 2006:1). founding edited volumes (eg, Koyama &Thomas 1979; Price & Brown 1985) are especially important. Editors According to Koyama and Uchiyama, the term of more recent volumes carefully place themselves and ‘affluence’ was used by Koyama and Thomas in its their books into intellectual genealogies extending back common sense of material well-being in deliberate to either or both of these seminal works (eg, Habu et al opposition to Sahlins’ usage.
    [Show full text]
  • Explaining the Neolithic Demographic Transition
    Explaining the Neolithic Demographic Transition Jean-Pierre Bocquet-Appel Abstract Three main questions are raised in this chapter. 1. The part of the signal of the NDT which is demographically identifiable, based on the proportion of the immature skeletons in cemeteries, shows that a baby- boom occurred and, beyond that, with the onset of the change in the economic system, a fertility transition towards high values also occurred. What was the biodemographic cause of this fertility explosion, beyond the proxy variable rep- resented by sedentarism? The cause is a major shift in the maternal energetics of farming communities relative to mobile foragers. In the energy balance there was (i) on the intake side, an underlying trend towards a reduction in low-calorie food from hunting and fishing, and a correlative increase in high-calorie food from agriculture, (ii) on the expenditure side, a reduction in the physical energy devoted to mobility and the maternal stress of child transportation. 2. The NDT is detectable from a signal representing a fertility transition, but the transition relating to mortality is missing and must be inferred. If, during the fertility transition, mortality had remained the same as in the preceding forager period, then the population would have grown infinitely. The assumption of un- changed mortality during the entire fertility transition is therefore not realistic. Mortality, in its turn, must have begun to rise well before the end of the fertil- ity transition. But when? Why? One of the answers consists of a model where, except at the start of the process, birth and mortality rates rise more or less simul- taneously, bringing about a typical rate of increase for pre-industrial populations of slightly above zero.
    [Show full text]