The Role of the Marshall Plan in the Italian Post-WWII Recovery

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Role of the Marshall Plan in the Italian Post-WWII Recovery Reconstruction Aid, Public Infrastructure, and Economic Development⇤ NicolaBianchi MichelaGiorcelli July 24, 2018 Abstract This paper studies how the modernization of transportation infrastructure a↵ects long-term economic outcomes. It exploits plausibly exogenous di↵erences between Ital- ian provinces in the share of modern infrastructure—mainly roads and railways—built with grants disbursed through the Marshall Plan. Provinces that could modernize a larger portion of their infrastructure stock experienced higher increases in agricultural production, especially for perishable crops that benefitted the most from an efficient transportation system. Agricultural firms in these areas also invested more in motorized machines that decreased the employment of manual labor. In the same provinces, we observe more entry of small firms in the industrial sector, as well as a larger expansion of the industrial and service workforce. JEL Classification: H84, N34, N44, O12, O33 Keywords: international aid, economic growth, reconstruction grants, Marshall Plan, innovation ⇤Contact information: Nicola Bianchi, Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, and NBER, [email protected]; Michela Giorcelli, University of California, Los Angeles, and NBER, [email protected]. We thank Ran Abramitzky, Thor Berger, Meghan Busse, Nicholas Bloom, Dora Costa, Pascaline Dupas, Fran¸cois Geerolf, Therese McGuire, Katherine Meckel, Melanie Morten, Tommaso Porzio, Nancy Qian, Melanie Wasserman, and seminar and conference participants at UCLA, Northwestern, UC-San Diego, IFN Stockholm Conference, Barcelona GSE Summer Forum, and the Cliometric Society Annual Conference for helpful comments. Antonio Coran, Zuhad Hai, Jingyi Huang, and Fernanda Rojas Ampuero provided excellent research assistance. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Economic History Association through the Arthur H. Cole Grant. 1 Introduction Transportation network is considered a key factor for economic development. Many high- income countries in Western Europe and North America, however, have aging transportation infrastructure that is becoming increasingly inefficient and more congested than ever.1 In the US, for example, 37 percent of roads are in poor or mediocre condition, 9 percent of bridges are structurally deficient, and 45 percent of urban Interstates are congested at peak hours (TRIP, 2018). In a survey by the European Investment Bank, the share of municipalities reporting underinvestment in urban transportation is equal to 50 percent in Italy, 43 percent in the UK, 37 percent in Germany, and 19 percent in France (European Investment Bank, 2017). The average car drives in congested traffic for 74 hours a year in London, 69 hours in Paris, 63 hours in Washington DC, 44 hours in Berlin, and 39 hours in Rome (INRIX, 2018). More investments for maintenance would not be sufficient to completely address these issues. These countries, in fact, built most of their infrastructure stock several decades ago with di↵erent economic needs and predicted usage in mind. In the near future, their transportation systems might undergo more radical changes than just standard repairs, such as rebuilding with state-of-the-art materials, expanding capacity, rerouting, and adopting modern road design (ASCE, 2017). What is the e↵ect of modernizing the transportation network on the economy? Answer- ing this question is obviously important to evaluate the returns to investments in public infrastructure. An efficient transportation system can spur economic activity by decreasing the costs of moving goods and individuals. Building large infrastructure, however, can also disrupt existing businesses and households, decrease property values in already low-income areas (Carter, 2018), and depress rural areas by favoring urban agglomerations (Glaeser and Gottlieb, 2009). The existing research in this literature studies the returns to the creation of new transportation networks (for example, Morten and Oliveira, 2017). Most high-income countries, however, are debating over the redesign of their suboptimal infrastructure stock, which can generate a di↵erent set of economic consequences. In an ideal experiment, we would randomize the rebuilding of transportation systems. Locations in the treatment group would redesign their infrastructure according to their current needs, while locations in the control group would keep their existing stock. Upon 1 Sources are the 2017 Infrastructure Report Card by the American Society of Civil Engineers (ASCE, 2017), the Global Traffic Scorecard by INRIX(INRIX, 2018), Key Facts About America’s Surface Transportation System and Federal Funding by TRIP (TRIP, 2018), the Municipality Infrastructure Survey by the European Investment Bank (European Investment Bank, 2017), the Global Infrastructure Dossier by Statista (Statista, 2017), the Global Infrastructure Outlook by Oxford Economics (Oxford Economics, 2017), and the 2018 Global Competitiveness Report by the World Economic Forum (World Economic Forum, 2018). 1 completion of the public projects, the analysis would compare how economic outcomes change between the two groups. This thought experiment, however, is clearly not feasible. In addition to being too expensive, it would require convincing several local governments to swiftly modernize their transportation system. Instead of relying on experimental data, we propose to address this research question in a historical context. This paper studies the most recent episode of large-scale reconstruction of public in- frastructure in European history. Specifically, it uses evidence from the Marshall Plan in Italy to estimate how updating the transportation network a↵ects a wide array of economic outcomes. The Marshall Plan was an economic and financial aid program sponsored by the US that transferred approximately $130 billion (2010 USD) to Western and Southern Europe between 1948 and 1952. Getting more than 10% of total aid, Italy was the third largest recipient (Fauri, 2006). We digitized data on all 14,912 di↵erent reconstruction projects funded through the Marshall Plan in Italy. We show that provinces that had experienced intense Allied bombings during WWII could build new infrastructure with US funds, instead of just restoring pre- existing roads and railways. The average province in the top quintile of Allied bombings used 80 percent of their funds from the Marshall Plan to build new projects, while the average province in the bottom quintile assigned 98 percent of its budget to repairing its old stock. These findings are consistent with the hypothesis that more widespread destruction during the war decreased the opportunity cost of radical changes to the transportation system after the arrival of international grants. This setting allows us to measure how economic outcomes changed after the Marshall Plan between provinces that could redesign their transportation infrastructure and provinces that simply restored their pre-existing network. Specifically, we estimate reduced-form regressions in which we compare how economic outputs varied before and after the Marshall Plan, and between provinces with di↵erent amount of Allied bombings (and therefore varying degree of modernization of their infrastructure). Moreover, we directly measure the economic e↵ects of public investments in new infrastructure by instrumenting reconstruction grants received by each province during the Marshall Plan with the province-level amount of Allied bombings. Our analysis shows that the intensity of Allied air strikes during WWII was a major driver of modernization of public infrastructure during the Marshall Plan. But are Allied bombings truly exogenous with respect to postwar economic development? We address this issue by identifying a subset of air strikes that are correlated with war events, but not with local prewar economic conditions. Specifically, we exploit a change in the Allied military strategy from strategic to tactical bombing. Italy surrendered on September 3, 1943 after signing the Armistice of Cassibile. Before the armistice, the Allies employed strategic bombing to hit 2 the major economic and industrial centers. The goal was to weaken morale and decrease support for the ruling Fascist regime. The geographic distribution of these air attacks is clearly correlated with prewar economic output. After the armistice, however, Italy became an active warfront between the German army from the North and the Allied army from the South. The Allied air forces switched to tactical bombing to help their ground troops breaking enemy lines. The distribution of these tactical air attacks was mostly driven by war-related events, such as land battles and intelligence on movement of troops and supplies, but does not appear to be correlated with other local factors.2 We find three key results. First, provinces that could redesign their transportation system during the Marshall Plan experienced larger increases in agricultural production (between 10 and 20 percent for major crops). This e↵ect starts only after the completion of the first public projects and lasts until the end of our sample in 1969. More efficient roads and railways might have allowed farmers to reach farer markets more quickly, essentially increasing demand for agricultural products. Consistent with this hypothesis, the estimated e↵ect of new infrastructure is positive and large for perishable crops (3-fold increase for fruit with short shelf-life), but not statistically di↵erent from zero for products with a very
Recommended publications
  • Sicily's Ancient Landscapes & Timeless Traditions 2021
    YOUR O.A.T. ADVENTURE TRAVEL PLANNING GUIDE® Sicily’s Ancient Landscapes & Timeless Traditions 2021 Small Groups: 8-16 travelers—guaranteed! (average of 13) Overseas Adventure Travel ® The Leader in Personalized Small Group Adventures on the Road Less Traveled 1 Dear Traveler, At last, the world is opening up again for curious travel lovers like you and me. And the O.A.T. Sicily’s Ancient Landscapes & Timeless Traditions itinerary you’ve expressed interest in will be a wonderful way to resume the discoveries that bring us so much joy. You might soon be enjoying standout moments like these: Who doesn’t love to eat in Italy? But Sicilian food, which is heavily influenced by the Arabs who thrived here, is in a league of its own. Sample the local flavors when you visit the Tunisian-inflected town of Mazara del Vallo and share a traditional Sicilian lunch with a local family. As you savor the home-cooked fare, you’ll learn how the city’s identity continues to evolve, and the vital role of the local fishing industry. You’ll also visit a home of a very different sort, one that traveler Carol Bowman described as “a house full of hope.” It’s Casa di Maria, an organization (and Grand Circle Foundation partner) established by a family in Catania to provide a loving home for children who are refugees or victims of neglect and domestic violence. The daughter-in-law of the founders (Sergio and Carmela) will enlighten you about Sicily’s foster care system. And you’ll meet more of the Casa’s extended family, including a young Nigerian woman who literally showed up on Sicily’s shores with nothing and grew up here, and hear her harrowing—but ultimately inspiring—story.
    [Show full text]
  • Irno Scarani, Cronache Di Luce E Sangue (Edizione Del Giano, 2013), 128 Pp
    Book Reviews Irno Scarani, Cronache di luce e sangue (Edizione del Giano, 2013), 128 pp. Nina Bjekovic University of California, Los Angeles The contemporary art movement known as Neo-Expressionism emerged in Europe and the United States during the late 1970s and early 1980s as a reaction to the traditional abstract and minimalist art standards that had previously dominated the market. Neo-Expressionist artists resurrected the tradition of depicting content and adopted a preference for more forthright and aggressive stylistic techniques, which favored spontaneous feeling over formal structures and concepts. The move- ment’s predominant themes, which include human angst, social alienation, and political tension reemerge in a similar bold tone in artist and poet Irno Scarani’s Cronache di luce e sangue. This unapologetic, vigorous, and sensible poetic contem- plation revisits some of the most tragic events that afflicted humanity during the twentieth century. Originating from a personal urgency to evaluate the experience of human existence and the historical calamities that bear everlasting consequences, the poems, better yet chronicles, which comprise this volume daringly examine the fear and discomfort that surround these disquieting skeletons of the past. Cronache di luce e sangue reflects the author’s firsthand experience in and expo- sure to the civil war in Italy—the highly controversial period between September 8, 1943, the date of the armistice of Cassibile, and May 2, 1945, the surrender of Nazi Germany, when the Italian Resistance and the Co-Belligerent Army joined forces in a war against Benito Mussolini’s Fascist Italian Social Republic. Born in Milan in 1937 during the final period of the Fascist regime, Scarani became acquainted with violence and war at a very young age.
    [Show full text]
  • WHERE WAS MEAN SOLAR TIME FIRST ADOPTED? Simone Bianchi INAF-Osservatorio Astrofisico Di Arcetri, Largo E. Fermi, 5, 50125, Flor
    WHERE WAS MEAN SOLAR TIME FIRST ADOPTED? Simone Bianchi INAF-Osservatorio Astrofisico di Arcetri, Largo E. Fermi, 5, 50125, Florence, Italy [email protected] Abstract: It is usually stated in the literature that Geneva was the first city to adopt mean solar time, in 1780, followed by London (or the whole of England) in 1792, Berlin in 1810 and Paris in 1816. In this short paper I will partially revise this statement, using primary references when available, and provide dates for a few other European cities. Although no exact date was found for the first public use of mean time, the primacy seems to belong to England, followed by Geneva in 1778–1779 (for horologists), Berlin in 1810, Geneva in 1821 (for public clocks), Vienna in 1823, Paris in 1826, Rome in 1847, Turin in 1849, and Milan, Bologna and Florence in 1860. Keywords: mean solar time 1 INTRODUCTION The inclination of the Earth’s axis with respect to the orbital plane and its non-uniform revolution around the Sun are reflected in the irregularity of the length of the day, when measured from two consecutive passages of the Sun on the meridian. Though known since ancient times, the uneven length of true solar days became of practical interest only after Christiaan Huygens (1629 –1695) invented the high-accuracy pendulum clock in the 1650s. For proper registration of regularly-paced clocks, it then became necessary to convert true solar time into mean solar time, obtained from the position of a fictitious mean Sun; mean solar days all having the same duration over the course of the year.
    [Show full text]
  • Cornette, Carla. Colonial Legacies
    http://www.gendersexualityitaly.com g/s/i is an annual peer-reviewed journal which publishes research on gendered identities and the ways they intersect with and produce Italian politics, culture, and society by way of a variety of cultural productions, discourses, and practices spanning historical, social, and geopolitical boundaries. Title: Colonial Legacies in Family-Making and Family-Breaking: Carla Macoggi’s Memoirs as Semi-Autobiography Journal Issue: gender/sexuality/italy, 7 (2020) Author: Carla Cornette, Pennsylvania State University Publication date: February 2021 Publication info: gender/sexuality/italy, “Continuing Discussions” Permalink: https://www.gendersexualityitaly.com/13-colonial-legacies-family-making-and-family-breaking-carla- macoggis-memoirs Author Bio: Carla Cornette is an Assistant Teaching Professor of Italian at Pennsylvania State University and the faculty co-leader of Penn State’s study abroad program in Reggio Calabria. She holds a Ph.D. in Italian from the University of Wisconsin-Madison and a minor in African Cultural Studies and Gender and Women’s Studies. Her dissertation project (2018) is entitled “Postcolonial Pathology in the Works of Italian Postcolonial Writers Carla Macoggi, Ubah Cristina Ali Farah, and Igiaba Scego” and interrogates the notion of depression in Italian postcolonial literature as a politically and socially induced phenomenon. She is currently preparing a monograph based on this study which argues that melancholic psycho-affective sequelae that manifest in Black diaspora women literary figures are the natural and expected consequence to continual subjection to multiple axes of oppression including race, gender, geography, and class, inequalities which have their origins in Italy’s colonial history. Abstract: Kkeywa: Storia di una bimba meticcia (2011) and La nemesi della rossa (2012) constitute the sequential memoirs of Carla Macoggi, Ethiopian-Italian author and attorney.
    [Show full text]
  • Consensus for Mussolini? Popular Opinion in the Province of Venice (1922-1943)
    UNIVERSITY OF BIRMINGHAM SCHOOL OF HISTORY AND CULTURES Department of History PhD in Modern History Consensus for Mussolini? Popular opinion in the Province of Venice (1922-1943) Supervisor: Prof. Sabine Lee Student: Marco Tiozzo Fasiolo ACADEMIC YEAR 2016-2017 2 University of Birmingham Research Archive e-theses repository This unpublished thesis/dissertation is copyright of the author and/or third parties. The intellectual property rights of the author or third parties in respect of this work are as defined by The Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988 or as modified by any successor legislation. Any use made of information contained in this thesis/dissertation must be in accordance with that legislation and must be properly acknowledged. Further distribution or reproduction in any format is prohibited without the permission of the copyright holder. Declaration I certify that the thesis I have presented for examination for the PhD degree of the University of Birmingham is solely my own work other than where I have clearly indicated that it is the work of others (in which case the extent of any work carried out jointly by me and any other person is clearly identified in it). The copyright of this thesis rests with the author. Quotation from it is permitted, provided that full acknowledgement is made. This thesis may not be reproduced without my prior written consent. I warrant that this authorisation does not, to the best of my belief, infringe the rights of any third party. I declare that my thesis consists of my words. 3 Abstract The thesis focuses on the response of Venice province population to the rise of Fascism and to the regime’s attempts to fascistise Italian society.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of the Marshall Plan in the Italian Post-WWII Recovery
    The Role of the Marshall Plan in the Italian Post-WWII Recovery⇤ NicolaBianchi MichelaGiorcelli February 27, 2018 Abstract This paper studies the e↵ects of international aid on long-term economic growth. It exploits plausibly exogenous di↵erences between Italian provinces in the amount of grants disbursed through the Marshall Plan for the reconstruction of public in- frastructures. Provinces that received more reconstruction grants experienced a larger increase in the number of industrial firms and workers after 1948. Individuals and firms in these areas also started developing more patents. The same provinces experienced a faster mechanization of the agricultural sector. Motorized machines, such as tractors, replaced workers and significantly boosted agricultural production. Finally, we present evidence that shows how reconstruction grants induced economic growth by allowing Italian provinces to modernize their transportation and communication network. JEL Classification: H84, N34, N44, O12, O33 Keywords: international aid, economic growth, reconstruction grants, Marshall Plan, innovation ⇤Contact information: Nicola Bianchi, Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, and NBER, [email protected]; Michela Giorcelli, University of California, Los Angeles, [email protected]. We thank Ran Abramitzky, Nicholas Bloom, Dora Costa, and Pascaline Dupas. Antonio Coran, Zuhad Hai, Jingyi Huang, and Fernanda Rojas Ampuero provided excellent research assistance. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Economic History Association through a Arthur H. Cole Grant. 1 Introduction International aid is one of the main sources of revenues for many developing countries. Starting in 1970, the United Nations set an explicit target for member countries of OECD’s Development Assistance Committee (DAC): 0.7 percent of national income spent for de- velopment assistance.1 In recent years, the UN re-endorsed this target by including it in the 2005 Millennium Development Goals and the subsequent 2015 Sustainable Development Goals.
    [Show full text]
  • Policy Department C Citizens Rights and Constitutional Affairs INTERNATIONAL ADOPTION in the EUROPEAN UNION
    Directorate-General Internal Policies Policy Department C Citizens Rights and Constitutional Affairs INTERNATIONAL ADOPTION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION Final Report – 2009, March 27th Résumé: The main purpose of the report consists of proposing an up-dated comparative vision in the field of intercountry adoptions at European level, in particular following an interdisciplinary perspective able to give adequate consideration both to social and legal aspects involved. In particular, the research envisages two different levels of analysis: a documentary analysis based mainly on a statistical profile of the phenomenon within EU countries followed by a review of the fundamental international and European instruments that actually regulate the international adoption system and a survey that will be realized specifically at national level. The study led to some concrete proposal for the interventions of EU level and national policy-makers as well as representatives of civil society directed to harmonize the different national rules and experiences and to create a European adoption system. IP/C/LIBE/IC/2008-003 This note was requested by: The European Parliament’s committee on Civil Liberties, Justice and Home Affairs. This study is published in the following language: EN The report has been coordinated by Istituto degli Innocenti, Florence Scientific Committee: Femmie Juffer, Isabelle Lammerant, Enrico Moretti, Piercarlo Pazè, Raffaella Pregliasco, Peter Selman, Elena Urso Texts by: Erika Bernacchi, Federico Brogi, Isabelle Lammerant, Femmie Juffer,
    [Show full text]
  • May 2008 Electronic Invoicing As A
    Electronic Invoicing as a ‘keystone’ in the collaboration between companies, banks and PA Report 2008 Observatory on Electronic Invoicing and Demateralisation May 2008 In collaboration with Index pages Introduction by Umberto Bertelè and Andrea Rangone 7 Executive Summary by Alessandro Perego 9 1. Electronic invoicing: the framework of reference 13 The various meanings of electronic invoicing 13 The “value” of electronic invoicing 15 The adoption 17 The barriers 19 The priorities 21 2. Electronic invoicing models 23 The adoption paradigms 23 The service fruition modes 28 The supply market 32 3. Adoption process 35 The diffusion of electronic invoicing models 36 The size of investments 39 The project sponsorship 40 The operational management of projects 42 The benefits 42 The critical operational features 43 The barriers 44 4. Assessment of profitability 63 The meta-model 63 Theanalysis of benefits 66 The analysis of profitability 70 Brief conclusions 82 5. Evolution of the legislative framework 83 A summary of the legislative framework 83 The open issues 86 The electronic invoicing to public sector authorities 90 Note on methodology 93 Workgroup 99 School of Management 101 The School of Management of Politecnico di Milano 101 ICT & Management Observatories 101 Supporters of Research 103 www.osservatori.net ELECTRONIC INVOICING AS A ‘KEYSTONE’ IN THE COLLABORATION BETWEEN COMPANIES, BANKS AND PA 1 Index of Figures pages Figure 1.1 The electronic invoicing as a ‘keystone’ in trade process integration 14 Figure 1.2
    [Show full text]
  • Illicit Adoptions
    ICAV Perspective Paper Illicit Intercountry Adoptions Lived Experience Views on How Authorities and Bodies Could Respond Compiled by Lynelle Long, July 2020 WWW.INTERCOUNTRYADOPTEEVOICES.COM ICAV PERSPECTIVE PAPER 1 Introduction n the past, ICAV Perspective Papers have brought together a range of views on a specific topic from intercountry adoptees all over the world. The goal of these Ipapers have been to raise greater understanding of the complexities we live. This paper attempts to bring together not only the voices and experiences of impacted intercountry adoptees who have lived experience with some form of illicit practice in their adoption, but we also include for the first time, a few adoptive parents and first family representation. For the purpose of this paper, we will use the term illicit adoption practice because it includes illegal adoptions but its meaning can also extend to unethical practices. Sometimes adoption practices are technically legal under the law of the relevant country but are fundamentally unethical under international or other standards such as the CRC, the Optional Protocol (Sale of Children), and the Palermo Protocol. Illicit practices can vary immensely but in general, participants experienced one or more of these 3 categories of instances: one category of illicit practices are instances where the child never should have been removed from (or should have been returned to) their family; a second group deals with subsidiarity in the sense that while it may have been necessary for the child not to be with their family, in-country solutions should have been used; then there are wrongs that go to matching--- such as falsified child study forms — in instances where an adoption could have been appropriate, but the wrongdoing led to creating a placement that was problematic.
    [Show full text]
  • INTERCOUNTRY ADOPTION PROCESS in ITALY Adoption
    International trends in intercountry adoption: New challenges for intercountry adoption practice – ensuring the child’s best interest Intercountry adoption in Italy Munich, 27-04-2016 1 Adoption law and policies in Italy Intercountry Adoption process in Italy Cooperation between central authorities and adoption organizations Nation-wide standards for good practice in ICA Future trends in intercountry adoption Future perspectives for Italian adoption practice 2 CIAI - ITALIAN CENTER FOR THE AID TO CHILDREN Founded in 1968, first italian adoption organization Contributed to the Law 184/83 and 476/98 Co-Founder of Euradopt More than 3500 children adopted in Italy through CIAI from Asia, Africa, Latin America In 2015 more than 80% adopted children were special needs 2015: 50 adoptions – 1450 Post-adoption interviews 3 ADOPTION LAW AND POLICIES IN ITALY Law no. 184 of May 1983 Domestic and Intercountry modified by Law no. 149 of adoption March 2001 on adoption and Who can adopt foster care Who can be adopted Law no. 476 of December The Central Authority 1998, ratifying the 1993 (D.P.R. 108 of June 2007) Hague Convention. The Accredited Bodies (Guidelines 2005) 4 ADOPTION LAW AND POLICIES IN ITALY Intercountry Adoption is possible only through Accredited Adoption Organizations Private adoption is NOT allowed 62 Accredited Bodies, 61 private, 1 public Private organizations do not receive any public contribution for adoption and post-adoption services Private organizations have to charge all the costs on the families 5 INTERCOUNTRY ADOPTION PROCESS IN ITALY Adoption: •The couple applies to a Juvenile court who will issue a decree of suitability •The couple approaches an adoption organization •The adoption organization handles the entire process abroad •The CA authorizes the adopted child’s entry to Italy •The Juvenile Court orders to transcribe the adoption decision in the registries of civil status.
    [Show full text]
  • The ICT Revolution and Italy's Two Lost Decades∗
    The ICT Revolution and Italy's Two Lost Decades∗ Fabiano Schivardi Tom Schmitz LUISS University, EIEF and CEPR Bocconi University and IGIER May 19, 2017 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE - PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE Abstract Since the middle of the 1990s, Italy's catching-up process with respect to other advanced economies has ended, and output per capita has started to diverge. One potential reason for this divergence is the failure of Italian rms to take up the ICT revolution. We provide micro-level evidence on low ICT adoption in Italy, and show how it is linked to inecient management practices and amplied by input- output linkages. We then build a general equilibrium model with heterogeneous rms, management and ICT adoption choices, and production networks, and use it to analyse the quantitative importance of the ICT revolution for Italy's divergence. We nd that the ICT revolution can account for approximately 25% of the divergence between Italy's and Germany's GDP per hour worked between 1995 and 2015, the largest part being due to inecient management lowering the adoption rate and the productivity of ICT technologies. While the best way for Italy to catch up would be to improve management practices, the fact that production networks create externalities which make ICT adoption ineciently low creates a role for subsidy policies to improve aggregate outcomes. Keywords: Italy, Productivity slowdown, Divergence, ICT, Technology adoption, Management. JEL Codes: L23, O33 ∗Schivardi: Department of Economics, LUISS University, Rome, Italy, [email protected]. Schmitz: Department of Eco- nomics, Bocconi University, Via Roentgen 1, 20136 Milan, Italy, [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • The ICT Revolution and Italy's Two Lost Decades∗
    The ICT Revolution and Italy's Two Lost Decades∗ Fabiano Schivardi Tom Schmitz Università Bocconi, EIEF and IGIER Università Bocconi and IGIER December 15, 2016 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE - PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE Abstract Since the middle of the 1990s, Italy's GDP and productivity growth rates have virtually fallen to zero, and Italy's economy is falling ever further behind Northern Europe and the United States. We argue that an important reason behind the Italian slowdown is the failure of Italian rms to take up the ICT revolution. This, in turn, may be due to long-standing distortions in their internal organization, characterized by small size, centralized management, and low numbers of non-family managers. To explore this hypothesis, we write a heterogeneous-rm model with ICT and management, assuming that ICT enters rms' production functions as management-augmenting technological change. In the model, inecient management causes low ICT adoption, both directly (as management and ICT are complements) and indirectly (as inecient management in large rms allows more unproductive non-ICT adopting rms to survive). Increases in ICT productivity widen income dierences between economies with ecient and inecient management, both because the former use more ICT and because ICT increases the importance of management for aggregate production. Using microdata from dierent surveys on ICT and managers in rms in Italy and other European countries, we document empirical regularities that are in line with the model's predictions. Eventually, we want to use this data to assess how much of Italy's divergence can be explained by the ICT revolution.
    [Show full text]