Failure of Trade Liberalization: a Study of the GATS Negotiation Christopher F

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Failure of Trade Liberalization: a Study of the GATS Negotiation Christopher F Journal of International Business and Law Volume 10 | Issue 2 Article 6 2011 Failure of Trade Liberalization: A Study of the GATS Negotiation Christopher F. Thornberg Ph D Frances L. Edwards J.D. Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarlycommons.law.hofstra.edu/jibl Recommended Citation Thornberg, Christopher F. Ph D and Edwards, Frances L. J.D. (2011) "Failure of Trade Liberalization: A Study of the GATS Negotiation," Journal of International Business and Law: Vol. 10: Iss. 2, Article 6. Available at: http://scholarlycommons.law.hofstra.edu/jibl/vol10/iss2/6 This Legal Article is brought to you for free and open access by Scholarly Commons at Hofstra Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal of International Business and Law by an authorized administrator of Scholarly Commons at Hofstra Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Thornberg and Edwards: Failure of Trade Liberalization: A Study of the GATS Negotiation FAILURE OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION: A STUDY OF THE GATS NEGOTIATION Christopher F. Thornberg, Ph D and Frances L. Edwards, J.D.t INTRODUCTION The General Agreement in Trade in Services (GATS) was touted as an exemplary international agreement among nations by which trade may be liberalized in the service sec- tors. The GATS negotiations differed in many ways from its predecessor, The General Agree- ment on Tariffs & Trade (hereinafter "GATT"). The most significant difference rested in the large degree of autonomy that nations had in determining the scope of liberalization to which they would commit. The outcome of the GATS negotiations resulted in a far less productive liberalization in service trade among the member nations. As, a result, it was not as successful as hoped. Instead, the first round of negotiations was rather disappointing due to the emergence of unwillingness to commit (to a large degree) to openness,. The whole process seemed to highlight the fact that countries tend to hesitate to venture into immediate openness for a number of reasons. This article discusses the GATS negotiation process and outcomes. In addition, it analyzes the cross-sectional results that emerged from the initial round of negotiation in 1995 in order to reveal the primary driving forces that determined the degree of liberalization that resulted. Five potential forces are considered: 1) the net gains from trade, 2) special interest influence, 3) international free-riding, 4) internal bureaucratic resistance, and 5) regionalism. The results of statistical analysis strongly suggest that special interests within nations have had the greatest impact on the degree of liberalization. Nations that have a comparative advan- tage in the production of services, and are therefore more likely to be exporting services, committed to the greatest degree of liberalization in service trade. This result stems from the implicit separation of negotiations over the liberalization of trade in goods (under the GATT) from the negotiations over trade in services (under the GATS). The impact of this separation would be to increase the influence of the special interest groups by reducing the number of competing interests. At the time, the implication was quite clear- that the future rounds of GATS negotiations would be much more successful if they were directly attached to the GATT. Section I discusses the GATS negotiation and the processes by which nations make commitments under it. Section II reviews the structure of trade protection, with a preliminary look at potential forces that are indirectly considered when analyzing the decisions by nations in their commitments under the GATS. Section III discusses five theories tested as potential explanations for the cross-country patterns of liberalization found in the data collected. Sec- tion IV discusses the quantification of the results of the GATS negotiations. The data was collected from the Schedule of Specific Agreements filed by the 137 nations associated with t Many thanks to Professor William Dougan of the Department of Economics, Clemson University and participants at a seminar given at the World Service Congress, 1999 for helpful comments and suggestions. 325 Published by Scholarly Commons at Hofstra Law, 2011 1 Journal of International Business and Law, Vol. 10, Iss. 2 [2011], Art. 6 THE JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS & LAW the agreement and then quantified into a measure of liberalization that is comparable across the countries for use in a statistical analysis. (See Appendix 1). Section V presents the results of a regression analysis that tests these various hypotheses. In conclusion, the authors discuss the potential reasons for the poor results of the GATS negotiations and discuss and recom- mend potential future strategies for negotiating international agreements. I. THE GATS NEGOTIATIONS The reduced costs of international travel and communication, combined with in- creasing world wealth and the corresponding increase in the demand for services, has lead to a steady increase in the international trade of services. These services include transport, commu- nications, finance, business and tourism. The total value of this trade in 1995 accounted for approximately 19% of total trade, which consists of merchandise and service trade combined (See Table 2.1). This percentage is up from 15% in 1980. Total world income flows, i.e. the payments from domestically owned overseas factors of production, which are arguably an- other form of service trade, totaled nearly the same as service trade and had been growing at a similar rate. Table 2.1: Services as Percent of Total International Trade, 1980-1999 North Western World America Europe Asia 1980 15.2% 13.3% 20.7% 13.3% 1985 16.4% 19.0% 20.0% 12.7% 1990 18.5% 22.4% 20.3% 14.2% 1995 19.0% 22.3% 20.3% 15.3% 1999 19.4% 23.5% 21.4% 14.6% Data source- the World Trade Organization. The World Trade Organization (hereinafter "WTO") acknowledged this trend when it set up the first round of the GATS talks in the late 1980's.1 This agreement was adopted as an extension of the GATT with a general mandate for the progressive liberalization of interna- tional trade in services by member nations.2 The GATS agreement set out the general obliga- tions of the members, the most important being Most Favored Nation treatment (hereinafter "MFN"), transparency, and freedom of payments and transfers. MFN treatment under GATS was equivalent to the treatment set up under GATT in that it obligated a member to treat a supplier of services from any VTO member nation with "no less favorable" treatment than would be given to suppliers of services of any other coun- try.3 Transparency created a requirement that each member clearly and fully reveal any laws 1 The General Agreement on Trade in Services, Uruguay Round Final Act, Annex 113, 33 I.L.M 1130 t April 15, 1994) [hereinafter "GATS"] (started in the 1986 as Punta de Este ministerial Declaration). 2 Id. at art. XIX(1). This process is discussed in Articles II-XV of the document. It is interesting that while the agreement indicates that existing barriers should be reduced over time in order to encourage increased access, it does not provide a direct mechanism through which this should occur. ' id. at art. II(l), (2). Due to the unilateral nature of the GATS commitments and the fear of international free- riding, nations were actually given the ability to exempt themselves from MFN under certain circumstances in order to restrict the access of specific other members to domestic markets. Any of these 'Article II exemptions' 326 http://scholarlycommons.law.hofstra.edu/jibl/vol10/iss2/6 2 Thornberg and Edwards: Failure of Trade Liberalization: A Study of the GATS Negotiation FAILURE OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION or regulations that would affect another entering member's producers in services.' Finally, the fundamental concern of members that there would be no restrictions regarding interna- tional transfer and payments related to a member's commitments was assured under the GATS articles. 5 It appears that the goal of the initial GATS round was primarily to negotiate service trade and to create a structure that would facilitate future rounds of negotiations. As such, nations were given a large amount of leeway as to their initial commitment in the way of service trade liberalization. Each member country was required to supply the WTO with a form known as a Schedule of Specific Commitments (hereinafter "SSC"). Under these sched- ules, members indicated the specific service sectors in which they were willing to make com- mitments to the ideals of Market Access and National Treatment. 6 Market Access dealt with the treatment of the service as it entered the economy.7 Member countries that agreed to complete liberalization in Market Access for a specific service sector agreed to not use any of the service trade barriers listed in Table 2.2. In contrast, National Treatment dealt with the manner in which the service provider was treated once it entered that market. Under the GATT, National Treatment was automatic something that was not true for GATS and distin- guished the two. Liberalization implied that treatment should be no less favorable to the entering foreign service provider, once entered into the economy, than would be given to domestic or national services. According to the SSC, the members were also supposed to clearly announce any limitations to these ideals as well.8 In practice, however, which sectors were actually listed on the schedule was left completely up to the nation in question after a series of rounds of bilateral negotiations between the various participating nations.9 These were to be described on a sector by sector basis, were to indicate the inconsistency of the measure and its duration, must outline the conditions that created the exemption, and indicate those countries to which the exemption applies.
Recommended publications
  • “Trade Liberalization” in the Encyclopedia of Global Business
    TRADE LIBERALIZATION Encyclopedia of Global Business in Today’s World by BEYZA URAL MARCHAND1 Assistant Professor Department of Economics University of Alberta June 2008 1 Contact: 7-12 HM Tory, University of Alberta, Edmonton, AB T6G2H4 Canada. Phone: 001-780-492-7628. Email: [email protected]. 1 The purpose of this entry is to provide descriptions and explanations of basic concepts on trade liberalization, and briefly introduce the main issues. Trade liberalization is a very broad subject, connected to virtually every aspect of the domestic economy, as well as economies of trading partners. In the entire literature of globalization, liberalization of trade constitutes a significant part. However, due to binding restrictions on the entry, the coverage will be restricted to two major eras of liberalization, protectionism and trade agreements. TRADE LIBERALIZATION Trade liberalization refers to a significant reduction or removal of trade barriers that restrict a country’s international trade. These trade barriers include tariffs, non-tariff barriers (such as quotas and other government-imposed regulations), subsidies (such as those on production and exports), and other restrictive trade instruments. In general, the liberalization of trade entails a greater integration with global markets. In the 1980s, many developing countries implemented trade liberalization as a part of a structural adjustment program offered by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank (WB). Following the oil crisis of the 1970s, countries that had run high debt-to-GDP ratios and high current account deficits, such as Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Mexico, and Turkey, were unable to continue their development strategies that relied heavily on foreign investments.
    [Show full text]
  • Liberalization, Privatization, Globalization
    Liberalization, Privatization, Globalization General Economics Reasons for implementing LPG Excess of consumption and expenditure over revenue resulting in heavy government borrowings. Growing inefficiency in the use of resources. Over protection to industry Mismanagement of firms and the economy Mounting losses of public sector enterprises General Economics:Liberalization,Privatization,Globa lization 2 Reasons for implementing LPG Various distortions like poor technological development shortage of foreign exchanges; and imprudent borrowings from abroad and mismanagement of foreign exchange reserves. Low foreign exchange reserves. Burden of national debt. Inflation. General Economics:Liberalization,Privatization,Globa lization 3 Liberalization Liberalization refers to relaxation of previous government restrictions usually in areas of social and economic policies. Thus, when government liberalizes trade it means it has removed the tariff, subsidies and other restrictions on the flow of goods and services between countries. General Economics:Liberalization,Privatization,Globa lization 4 Privatisation It refers to the transfer of assets or service functions from public to private ownership or control and the opening of the hitherto closed areas to private sector entry. Privatisation can be achieved in many ways- franchising, leasing, contracting and divesture. General Economics:Liberalization,Privatization,Globa lization 5 Conditions for privatisaton Liberalisation and de-regulation of the economy is an essential pre- requisite if privatisation is to take off and help realize higher productivity and profits. General Economics:Liberalization,Privatization,Globa lization 6 Conditions for privatisaton Capital markets should be sufficiently developed to be able to absorb the disinvested public sector shares. General Economics:Liberalization,Privatization,Globa lization 7 Arguments in favour of privatisation Privatisation will help reducing the burden on exchequer.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Freedom” and Economic Growth: Questioning the Claim That Freer Markets Make Societies More Prosperous
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive “Economic freedom” and economic growth: questioning the claim that freer markets make societies more prosperous Cohen, Joseph N City University of New York, Queens College 27 September 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/33758/ MPRA Paper No. 33758, posted 27 Sep 2011 18:38 UTC “Economic Freedom” and Economic Growth: Questioning the Claim that Freer Markets Make Societies More Prosperous Joseph Nathan Cohen Department of Sociology City University of New York, Queens College 65-30 Kissena Blvd. Flushing, New York 11367 [email protected] Abstract A conventional reading of economic history implies that free market reforms rescued the world’s economies from stagnancy during the 1970s and 1980s. I reexamine a well-established econometric literature linking economic freedom to growth, and argue that their positive findings hinge on two problems: conceptual conflation and ahistoricity. When these criticisms are taken seriously, a very different view of the historical record emerges. There does not appear to be enduring relationship between economic liberalism and growth. Much of the observed relationship between these two variables involves a one-shot transition to freer markets around the Cold War’s end. Several concurrent changes took place in this historical context, and it is hasty to conclude that it was market liberalization alone that produced the economic turnaround of the 1990s and early-2000s. I also question market fundamentalists’ view that all forms of liberalization are helpful, arguing that the data show little to no benefit from reforms that did not attract foreign investment. Word Count: 6,698 (excl.
    [Show full text]
  • The Evolution and Ideology of Global Constitutionalism
    California Law Review VOL. 99 OCTOBER 2011 No. 5 Copyright @2011 by California Law Review, Inc., a California Nonprofit Corporation The Evolution and Ideology of Global Constitutionalism David S. Law* & Mila Versteeg** It has become almost universal practice for countries to adopt formal constitutions. Little is known empirically, however, about the evolution of this practice on a global scale. Are constitutions unique and defining statements of national aspiration and identity? Or are they standardized documents that vary only at the margins, in predictable and patterned ways? Are constitutions becoming increasinglysimilar or dissimilarover time, or is there no discernible overall pattern to their development? Until very recently, scholars have lacked even basic empirical data on the content of the world's Copyright C 2011, David S. Law & Mila Versteeg. * Professor of Law and Professor of Political Science, Washington University in St. Louis; Visiting Scholar, New York University School of Law; Visiting Professor and Fulbright Scholar, National Taiwan University College of Law. B.A., M.A., Ph.D., Stanford University; J.D., Harvard Law School; B.C.L. in European and Comparative Law, University of Oxford. ** Associate Professor, University of Virginia School of Law. B.A., LL.M., Tilburg University; LL.M., Harvard Law School; D.Phil., University of Oxford. Earlier versions of this Article were presented at the 2010 annual meetings of the Law and Society Association in Chicago and the American Political Science Association in Washington, D.C., the Fifth Annual Conference on Empirical Legal Studies held at Yale Law School, and faculty colloquia at Brooklyn Law School and Washington University School of Law.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Liberalization, International Monetary Dis/Order, and the Neoliberal State Timothy A
    American University International Law Review Volume 15 | Issue 6 Article 4 2000 Financial Liberalization, International Monetary Dis/order, and the Neoliberal State Timothy A. Canova Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.wcl.american.edu/auilr Part of the International Law Commons Recommended Citation Canova, Timothy A. "Financial Liberalization, International Monetary Dis/order, and the Neoliberal State." American University International Law Review 15, no. 6 (2000): 1279-1319. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Washington College of Law Journals & Law Reviews at Digital Commons @ American University Washington College of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in American University International Law Review by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons @ American University Washington College of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. FINANCIAL LIBERALIZATION, INTERNATIONAL MONETARY DIS/ORDER, AND THE NEOLIBERAL STATE TIMOTHY A. CANOVA ° INTRODUCTION ............................................ 1279 I. THE NEW INTERNATIONAL MONETARY DIS/ORDER.. 1281 II. CENTRAL BANK AUTONOMY AND TRANSPARENCY IN THE NEOLIBERAL STATE ............................. 1294 EI. WE HAVE OTHER ALTERNATIVES .................... 1315 INTRODUCTION This International Economic Law Conference has charged itself with a rather lofty task -- that of analyzing the professed justifica- tions of the prevailing neoliberal path of globalization by asking the following question: "Will the new world economic order we de- scribe lead to greater peace, stability, fairness and justice'?"' The global monetary system constitutes perhaps the most important legal and institutional foundation of today's world economic order in an- * Assistant Professor of Law, University of New Mexico School of Law. Thanks to Stephen Zamora, Cynthia Lichtenstein, and Chantal Thomas for comments dur- ing a panel discussion that helped to inform this paper.
    [Show full text]
  • Markets Not Capitalism Explores the Gap Between Radically Freed Markets and the Capitalist-Controlled Markets That Prevail Today
    individualist anarchism against bosses, inequality, corporate power, and structural poverty Edited by Gary Chartier & Charles W. Johnson Individualist anarchists believe in mutual exchange, not economic privilege. They believe in freed markets, not capitalism. They defend a distinctive response to the challenges of ending global capitalism and achieving social justice: eliminate the political privileges that prop up capitalists. Massive concentrations of wealth, rigid economic hierarchies, and unsustainable modes of production are not the results of the market form, but of markets deformed and rigged by a network of state-secured controls and privileges to the business class. Markets Not Capitalism explores the gap between radically freed markets and the capitalist-controlled markets that prevail today. It explains how liberating market exchange from state capitalist privilege can abolish structural poverty, help working people take control over the conditions of their labor, and redistribute wealth and social power. Featuring discussions of socialism, capitalism, markets, ownership, labor struggle, grassroots privatization, intellectual property, health care, racism, sexism, and environmental issues, this unique collection brings together classic essays by Cleyre, and such contemporary innovators as Kevin Carson and Roderick Long. It introduces an eye-opening approach to radical social thought, rooted equally in libertarian socialism and market anarchism. “We on the left need a good shake to get us thinking, and these arguments for market anarchism do the job in lively and thoughtful fashion.” – Alexander Cockburn, editor and publisher, Counterpunch “Anarchy is not chaos; nor is it violence. This rich and provocative gathering of essays by anarchists past and present imagines society unburdened by state, markets un-warped by capitalism.
    [Show full text]
  • The Uk's Privatisation Experiment
    THE UK’S PRIVATISATION EXPERIMENT: THE P ASSAGE OF TIME PERMITS A SOBER ASSESSMENT DAVID PARKER CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 1126 CATEGORY 9: INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION FEBRUARY 2004 PRESENTED AT CESIFO CONFERENCE ON PRIVATISATION EXPERIENCES IN THE EU NOVEMBER 2003 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded • from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com • from the CESifo website: www.CESifo.de CESifo Working Paper No. 1126 THE UK’S PRIVATISATION EXPERIMENT: THE PASSAGE OF TIME PERMITS A SOBER ASSESSMENT Abstract This chapter looks at the UK’s privatisation experiment, which began from the late 1970s. It considers the background to the UK’s privatisations, which industries were privatised and how, and summarises the results of studies of performance changes in privatised companies in the UK. It looks at the relative roles of competition, regulation and ownership changes in determining performance improvement. It concludes by looking at the wider lessons that might be learned from the UK’s privatisation experiment, including the importance of developing competitive markets and, in their absence, effective regulatory regimes. Keywords: UK, privatisation, competition regulation, lessons. JEL Classification: L33, H82, L51. David Parker Cranfield University School of Management Cranfield Bedfordshire MK43 0AL United Kingdom [email protected] Introduction The Labour Government of 1974-79 arranged the sale of some of the state’s shareholding in the petroleum company BP. However, this sale was dictated by budgetary pressures and did not reflect a belief within government that state industries should be privatised. Indeed, the same Labour Government took into state ownership two major industries, namely aerospace and shipbuilding.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade Liberalization and Economic Reform in Developing Countries: Structural Change Or De-Industrialization?
    TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND ECONOMIC REFORM IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: STRUCTURAL CHANGE OR DE-INDUSTRIALIZATION? No. 179 April 2005 TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND ECONOMIC REFORM IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: STRUCTURAL CHANGE OR DE-INDUSTRIALIZATION? S.M. Shafaeddin* No. 179 April 2005 *The author is a senior economist in charge of Macroeconomics and Development Policies Branch, Division on Globalization and Development Strategy, UNCTAD. The opinions expressed in this paper are his own and do not necessarily reflect the views of the United Nations. An earlier version of this paper was presented to the Development Studies Association Annual Conference on “Globalization and Development”, University of Strathclyde, Glasgow, 10–12 September 2003. The author benefited from comments by the audience of that Conference. He would also like to thank Mr. Y. Akyüz and Mr. M. Tribe for their comments on the draft; Mr. Tribe had brought to my attention certain literature on de-industrialization. Sections II, III–V are drawn, to a large extent from “Trade Policy at the Crossroads: The Recent Experience of Developing Countries”, (Shafaeddin 2005). (Any remaining shortcomings are the author’s responsibility.) Comments are appreciated and may be sent by e-mail to [email protected] or [email protected] UNCTAD/OSG/DP/2005/3 The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of UNCTAD. The designations and terminology employed are also those of the author. UNCTAD Discussion Papers are read anonymously by at least one referee, whose comments are taken into account before publication. Comments on this paper are invited and may be addressed to the author, c/o the Publications Assistant, Macroeconomic and Development Policies, GDS, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), Palais des Nations, CH-1211 Geneva 10, Switzerland (Telefax No: (4122) 9070274).
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Liberalization and Its Impact on Human Development: a Comparative Analysis of Turkey and Azerbaijan Mayis G
    INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF ENVIRONMENTAL & SCIENCE EDUCATION 2016, VOL. 11, NO. 17, 9753-9771 OPEN ACCESS Economic liberalization and its impact on human development: A Comparative analysis of Turkey and Azerbaijan Mayis G. Gulaliyeva, Nuri I. Okb, Fargana Q. Musayevaa, Rufat J. Efendiyeva, Jamila Q. Musayevac, and Samira R. Agayevaa aThe Institute of Economics of Azerbaijan National Academy of Sciences, Baku, AZERBAIJAN; bIbrahim Chechen University, Agri, TURKEY; cMingachevir State University, Mingachevir, AZERBAIJAN. ABSTRACT The aim of the article is to study the nature of liberalization as a specific economic process, which is formed and developed under the influence of the changing conditions of the globalization and integration processes in the society, as well as to identify the characteristic differences in the processes of liberalization of Turkey and Azerbaijan economies (using the method of comparative analysis of these countries' development indices). The objectives of this study: the characterization of the liberalization process as a specific economic process; a comparative analysis of the Turkey and Azerbaijan economic development conditions; the improvement of the theoretical justification of influence the process of economic liberalization on the development of society. The article presents the comparative analysis of the Turkey and Azerbaijan economic development conditions by using new research method as index of leftness (rightness) of economy. It was revealed that the Azerbaijan economy compared with the economy of Turkey is using more “right” methods of economy regulation. The Turkish economy is more prone to fluctuations in the studied parameters, at the same time, a main way of Turkish economy development is the direction towards increased liberalization, while the simultaneous growth of indicators of the human development.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring Services Trade Liberalization and Its Impact on Economic Growth: an Illustration
    Journal of Economic Integration 21(1), March 2006; 64-98 Measuring Services Trade Liberalization and Its Impact on Economic Growth: An Illustration Aaditya Mattoo The World Bank Randeep Rathindran HDR Inc. Arvind Subramanian International Monetary Fund Abstract The paper has three purposes. First, it explains how the impact of liberalization of service sectors on output growth differs from that of liberalization of trade in goods. Second, it suggests a policy-based rather than outcome-based measure of the openness of a country’s services regime. Such openness measures are constructed for two key service sectors, basic telecommunications and financial services. Finally, it provides some econometric evidence-relatively strong for the financial sector and less strong, but nevertheless statistically significant, for the telecommunications sector-that openness in services influences long run growth performance . Our estimates suggest that countries with fully open telecom and financial services sectors grow up to 1.5 percentage points faster than other countries. *Corresponding address: Aaditya Mattoo, Development Research Group, World Bank, Room MC3-335, 1818 H St, NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA. Tel: +1-202-458-7611, Fax: +1-202-522-1159, E-mail: [email protected]. Authors can be reached at [email protected], randeep.rathindran@ hdrinc.com and [email protected] ©2006-Center for International Economics, Sejong Institution, All Rights Reserved. Measuring Services Trade Liberalization and Its Impact on Economic Growth: An Illustration 65 • JEL classifications: F13, F43, G2, G28 • Key words: Liberalization, Economic Growth, Services, Regulation I. Introduction A spate of empirical cross-country studies by Dollar (1992), Sachs and Warner (1995), Ben-David (1993), Edwards (1998) and Coe et al.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Liberalization and the Fallacy of Post- Neoliberalism in Latin America
    Texto para Discussão 004 | 2018 Discussion Paper 004 | 2018 Economic liberalization and the fallacy of Post- neoliberalism in Latin America Reinaldo Gonçalves Professor of International Economics, Institute of Economics, Federal University of Rio de Janeiro E-mail: [email protected] This paper can be downloaded without charge from http://www.ie.ufrj.br/index.php/index-publicacoes/textos-para-discussao Economic liberalization and the fallacy of Post- neoliberalism in Latin America March, 2018 Reinaldo Gonçalves Professor of International Economics, Institute of Economics, Federal University of Rio de Janeiro E-mail: [email protected] Abstract The central hypothesis of this study is that Post-neoliberalism in Latin America is a fallacious narrative insofar as it is based on unsound arguments and flawed evidences. At the beginning of the 21st century the post-neoliberal narratives started as an attempt to understand the causes of the resurgence of leftist, nationalist, populist and reformist political forces in the region. In this paper, emphasis has been laid on the actual trends of economic liberalization in Latin American countries, mostly in the 21st century. At issue is the extent to which actual economic changes have accompanied shifts in ideological narratives and political processes. The empirical evidence is conclusive insofar was only a minority of countries actually experienced falling economic liberalization. IE-UFRJ DISCUSSION PAPER: GONCALVES, TD 004 - 2018. 2 Introduction The central hypothesis of this study is that Post-neoliberalism in Latin America is a fallacious narrative insofar as it is based on unsound arguments and flawed evidences. At the beginning of the 21st century the post-neoliberal narratives started as an attempt to understand the causes of the resurgence of leftist, nationalist, populist and reformist political forces in Latin America.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Fundamentalism and the World Bank Group: from Structural Adjustment Programmes to Maximizing Finance for Development and Beyond
    Market Fundamentalism and the World Bank Group: from Structural Adjustment Programmes to Maximizing Finance for Development and Beyond International Trade Union Confederation Cover: © Adobe Stock Contents Acronyms .................................................................................................................................................................................. 4 Foreword ................................................................................................................................................................................... 5 Introduction .............................................................................................................................................................................. 6 The rise and fall of the Washington Consensus .............................................................................................................. 7 From post-war reconstruction to Washington Consensus ....................................................................................... 7 The failure of the Washington Consensus ................................................................................................................... 8 The World Bank Group in the 21st century ...................................................................................................................... 11 Lending and policy advice ..............................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]