<<

THE U.S.-SOUTH ALLIANCE Free-Riding or Bargaining?

Jong-Sup Lee and Uk Heo

Defense burden-sharing has been a much-debated issue in alliance management since the early 1960s. The raised this issue to increase allies’ defense burdens in order to reduce its defense spend- ing without major changes in roles and missions. The U.S. executive branch has utilized congressional pressure to request allies to increase their defense burdens.1 For example, the Nunn-Roth Amendment (1984), the Neal Resolu- tion (1987), the Ritter Resolution (1987), the Amendment by John McCain (1988), the Amendment by John Bryant (1988), and the Amendment by Tommy F. Robinson (1988) all required American allies to increase their defense expenditures to a certain percentage of their gross national product (GNP). The Mansfield Amendments (1966–74), which were intended to re- duce the number of U.S. forces in Europe and to increase European contribu- tions, also produced a great debate in the U.S. Senate. In general, there are two contending approaches to defense burden-sharing: the free-riding model and the bargaining model. According to the free-riding model, the larger country in an alliance (as measured by size of GNP) has a larger defense burden than the smaller country does. In addition, the more the larger nation provides, the less the smaller nation will spend on defense.2

Jong-Sup Lee, Ph.D, is Lieutenant Colonel of the Republic of Korea Army. Uk Heo is Associate Professor of Political Science at the University of Wisconsin-Mil- waukee. The authors would like to thank Robert Peterson, Anthony Nownes, Jeffrey Berejikian, Yang Zhong, and Yen-Ping Hao for their helpful comments and suggestions. Asian Survey, 41:5, pp. 822–845. ISSN: 0004–4687 Ó 2001 by The Regents of the University of California. All rights reserved. Send Requests for Permission to Reprint to: Rights and Permissions, University of California Press, Journals Division, 2000 Center St., Ste. 303, Berkeley, CA 94704–1223. 1. Anthony H. Cordesman, “Economics, Strategy, and Burden-sharing, ” in U.S. Defense Pol- icy in an Era of Constrained Resources, eds. Robert L. Pfaltzraff, Jr., and Richard H. Shultz, Jr. (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1990). 2. See Mancur Olson and Richard Zeckhauser, “An Economic Theory of Alliances,” Review of Economics and Statistics 48:3 (August 1966), pp: 266–79; Bruce M. Russett, What Price

822 JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 823 Conversely, the bargaining model suggests that the defense burdens of smaller countries move in the same direction as those of larger countries. In other words, a smaller nation will increase (or decrease) its contributions to defense as the larger nation increases (or decreases) its contribution.3 In this paper, we revisit the contending theories of defense burden-sharing to suggest a revised model and apply it to the U.S.- alliance to explain the alliance relationship. The reason that we have chosen this case is that the alliance between the U.S. and South Korea has confronted the bur- den-sharing issue. For instance, at the beginning of the alliance period, South Korea maintained a relatively low defense burden. In the 1960s, this amounted to less than 4% of GNP. U.S. military to South Korea, includ- ing direct and indirect assistance, was more than the South Korean defense budget during this period.4 However, pressure by the U.S. forced South Ko- rea to increase its defense spending. During the 1970s, South Korea’s de- fense burden increased, reaching a high of 5.9% in 1978. This rise was triggered by Seoul’s agreement, signed in June 1979, to raise its defense bur- den to 6% of GNP in return for the cancellation of then-president Jimmy Carter’s U.S. troop withdrawal plan. Since the late 1980s, however, South Korea’s defense burden has decreased continuously, paralleling a similar trend in the U.S.5

Contending Theories of Defense Burden-Sharing Olson and Zeckhauser initiated the study of the free-riding model by investi- gating disproportionate defense burden-sharing6 in the North Atlantic Treaty

Vigilance? The Burdens of National Defense (New Haven and London: Yale University Press, 1970); Harvey Starr, “A Collective Goods Analysis of the Warsaw Pact after Czechoslovakia,” International Organization 28:4 (1974); pp. 521–33; James C. Murdoch and Todd Sandler, “A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of NATO,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 26:2 (1982), pp. 237–63; Wallace J. Thies, “Alliances and Collective Goods: A Reappraisal,” ibid., 31:2 (1972), pp. 298–332. 3. Glenn Palmer, “Corralling the Free Rider: Deterrence and the Western Alliance,” Interna- tional Studies Quarterly 34:1 (1990), pp. 147–64; idem., “Deterrence, Defense Spending, and Elasticity: Alliance Contributions to the Public Good,” International Interactions 17:2 (1991), pp. 157–69. 4. Young-Sun Ha, “Analysis of South Korean Military Expenditures: Past, Present, and Fu- ture” (in Korean), Journal of International Studies 7:3 (1982), pp. 289–306. 5. In-Taek Hyun, “Between Compliance and Autonomy: American Pressure for Defense Bur- den-Sharing and Patterns of Defense Spending in and South Korea” (Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Los Angeles, 1990). 6. A general discussion of the defense-growth relationship can be found in Uk Heo, “Model- ing the Defense-Growth Relationship Around the Globe,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 42:5 (1998), pp. 637–57; see also idem., The Political Economy of Defense Spending Around the World (Lewiston, N.Y.: Edwin Mellen Press, 1999). 824 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001 Organization. Their notion of free-riding is adapted from Olson’s argument that “in the sharing of the costs of efforts to achieve a common goal in small groups, there is however a surprising tendency for the `exploitation’ of the great by the small.”7 Olson and Zeckhauser express this relation in a formula. The larger country A has to provide the amount of defense (call this D) needed to deal with a threat without help from its allies. With ally B, which faces a common threat, country A needs to provide less defense (da) because its ally B makes some contribution to defense (db), thus (D = da + db). When country A increases its military expenditures and provides a new level of defense da’, that is ( da’ = da + df, where f is the amount of change), country B needs to provide less defense db’, that is ( db’ = db - df) to obtain the needed level of defense. Thus, the smaller country, B, decreases its defense burden as much as the larger country, A, increases it.8

Free-Riding in Alliances It is assumed in the logic that is the basis of this formula that defense provided by an alliance is a purely public good. A purely public good is characterized by two elements: nonexcludability and nonrivalness of benefits. Nonexcludability means that once a good is provided for an alliance, none of the allies can be excluded from benefits of the defense. Nonrivalness means that when a good is provided to one ally it can be supplied to others at little cost. Because of these characteristics, according to Olson and Zeckhauser, the more burden the larger ally shoulders in an alliance, the less smaller allies spend on defense, that is, they “free-ride.” Using this logic, researchers have argued that larger states in an alliance (in terms of GNP) spend disproportion- ately more on defense than smaller countries.9

”Bargaining” in Alliances The bargaining model provides an alternative perspective on defense burden- sharing.10 According to Glenn Palmer, “Preferences for the supply and con- sumption of a public good are a Prisoner’s Dilemma,”and there is a positive defense burden relationship between (or among) alliance members.11 In

7. Olson and Zeckhauser, “An Economic Theory of Alliances,” p. 267. 8. Ibid., pp. 268–69. 9. See L. Hansen, J. C. Murdoch, and T. Sandler, “On Distinguishing the Behavior of Nuclear and Non-Nuclear Allies in NATO,” Defense Economics 1:1 (1990), pp. 37–55. 10. See W. M. Reisinger, “East European Military Expenditures in the 1970s: Collective Good or Bargaining Offer?” International Organization 37:1 (1983), pp. 143–55; John R. Oneal, “The Theory of Collective Action and Burden-sharing in NATO,” ibid., 44:3 (1990), pp. 377–402. 11. Palmer, “Corralling the Free Rider,” p. 151. See also Russell Hardin, Collective Action (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Coopera- tion (New York: Basic Books, 1984). JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 825 other words, cooperation between allies is attained through a bargaining pro- cess such that the smaller members will increase (or decrease) their contribu- tions to the supply of the good as the largest power increases (or decreases) its contribution. The logic of the bargaining model is derived from the theories of public goods and the Prisoner’s Dilemma (PD). According to Palmer, all states in an alliance have an identical hierarchy of preferences. The preferred out- come is to free-ride, or to enjoy the public goods (i.e., deterrence) provided by an alliance without contributing (DC). If actors cannot free-ride, the best alternative is to pay some of the costs for an alliance while receiving the benefits of others’ contributions. This is mutual cooperation (CC). The third preference is to pay no costs and receive no benefits (DD). The worst possi- bility is to pay the costs and receive no benefits, while others do not pay but enjoy whatever benefits are provided (CD).12 In a one-shot game, mutual defection (DD) is the dominant strategy for all players. But an alliance is an iterated PD game in which actors make contin- uous contributions to the alliance. The reason is that, according to Axelrod, the “Tit-For-Tat” strategy is the dominant strategy in the repeated PD game. Therefore, the bargaining model posits that mutual cooperation (CC) is the most likely outcome because small allies are likely to reciprocate the larger ally rather than free-ride.13

The Free-Riding Argument Revisited The free-riding argument needs to be revisited for several reasons. First, the free-riding perspective does not consider the possibility of allies’ voluntary contributions to an alliance. According to Oneal, “Greater cooperation in sharing the cost of could be either voluntary or the result of coercion” and “certainly, movement toward a more equal distribution of the costs of collective security, whether coerced or voluntary, would be facili- tated by the small size of the alliance.”14 Palmer argues that alliances have a coercive mechanism or norms that force allies to cooperate.15 Oneal also contends that cooperation in sharing the costs in alliances could be the result of coercion.16 The powerful ally may not allow the smaller allies to act independently and free-ride. Russett and Sullivan also believe that coercion is one of the conditions for the achievement of a public good. They argue that “[a]t one extreme the collec-

12. Palmer, “Corralling the Free Rider,” p. 151. 13. Robert Axelrod, “The Emergence of Cooperation among Egoists,” American Political Science Review 75:2 (1981), pp. 306–09. 14. Oneal, “The Theory of Collective Action,” pp. 386–87. 15. Palmer, “Corralling the Free Rider.” 16. Oneal, “The Theory of Collective Action.” 826 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001 tive good can be provided when members are coerced to pay their share of the costs.”17 Coercive cooperation, however, does not necessarily mean extreme force applied to unwilling allies. Instead, most cases probably involve situations in which the members have limited power or authority to coerce their partners through explicit negotiation within the scope of a specific alliance. Coopera- tion negotiated in an explicit bargaining process would be an example of this type of coercive cooperation. Thus, negotiation in an explicit bargaining pro- cess is an important and common way to achieve cooperation and provides the basis for the bargaining model of defense burden.18 Second, a number of scholars have argued that voluntary contribution is also an important aspect of cooperation among allies because of the pursuit of self-reliance motivation by a fear of abandonment.19 Fear of abandonment, first labeled by Glen Snyder under the anarchical context of the international system, forces allies to voluntarily allocate more to the defense sector to achieve self-reliance.20 In an anarchical international system, smaller allies who depend on a stronger ally worry about the risks of abandonment because there is no reliable authority to enforce contracts and commitments.21 Thus, the fear of abandonment limits confidence in collective security and de- creases the attractiveness of free-riding. Instead, fear of abandonment en- hances allies’ voluntary contribution to the alliance by motivating allies to seek self-reliance. Third, the free-riding perspective does not consider the interaction between state-level and domestic-level factors. For instance, Olson and Zeckhauser’s argument depends solely on the defense burden (defense expenditure as a percentage of GNP) and GNP. Their argument does not sufficiently examine domestic factors such as socio-political constraints and the role of costs in their free-riding model.22 However, since the late 1980s, much literature on the issue of cooperation among nations has been seeking to identify the sources of state behavior in

17. Bruce M. Russett and J. David Sullivan, “Collective Goods and International Organiza- tion,” International Organization 25:4 (1971), p. 850. 18. Joseph Grieco, Cooperation Among Nations (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Helen Milner, “International Theories of Cooperation Among Nations: Strengths and Weaknesses,” World Politics 44:4 (1972), pp. 466–96. 19. Oran R. Young, International Cooperation: Building Regimes for Natural Resources and the Environment (Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press, 1989). 20. Glenn H. Snyder, “The in Alliance Politics,” World Politics 36:4 (1984), pp. 461–95. 21. Avery Goldstein, “Discounting the Free Ride: Alliances and Security in the Postwar World,” International Organization 49:1 (1995), pp. 39–71. 22. Olson and Zeckhauser, “An Economic Theory of Alliances.” JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 827 domestic politics.23 For instance, Rosenau’s “linkage politics” 24 and Al- lison’s “bureaucratic politics” 25 suggest some linkages between domestic politics and foreign policy. Krasner also argues that foreign-policy decision makers must be concerned simultaneously with the domestic context.26 Put- nam even formularized international bargaining as a “two-level game,” which inspired many students studying the influence of domestic factors on foreign policy.27 Bennett, Lepgold, and Unger argue that the most important element in alliance bargaining is the interaction between decision-makers’ interna- tional and domestic pressures:

What makes sense at home or abroad is often hard to sell in the other arena. The bargaining occurs when political leaders use pressures in one arena as leverage against the other. Often the alliance leader suggests that his or her domestic part- ners might abandon another state if this support is inadequate. A smaller ally’s negotiators in turn may invoke this pressure at home to build support for a contri- bution or to soften the larger ally’s demands by citing domestic constraints. 28 According to their view, states’ behaviors are compromises reached amid the competing concerns of state autonomy, societal preferences, and bureaucratic politics, through bargaining. Whether or how many states contribute to the alliance depends on these domestic factors. Related to the general issue of alliance, Barnett and Levy emphasize the role of domestic social, economic, and political constraints in shaping states’ alliance policies. 29 They find that a combination of external security threats and domestic socio-political con- straints can explain Egyptian alignments.

23. See Peter B. Evans, “Building an Interactive Approach to International and Domestic Politics: Reflections and Projections,” in Double-Edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics, eds. Peter B. Evans, Harold K. Jacobson, and Robert D. Putnam (Berke- ley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1993); Michale G. Huelshoff, “Domestic Politics and Dynamic Issue Linkage: A Reformulation of Integration Theory,” International Studies Quarterly 38:2 (1994), pp. 255–79; Peter A. Gourevitch, “Squaring the Circle: The Do- mestic Sources on International Cooperation,” International Organization 50 (1996), pp. 349–73. 24. James N. Rosenau, “Toward the Study of National-International Linkages,” in Linkages Politics: Essays on the Convergence of National and International Systems, ed. James N. Rose- nau (New York: Free Press, 1969). 25. Graham T. Allison, Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis (Boston: Little, Brown, 1971). 26. Stephen D. Krasner, Defending the National Interest: Raw Materials Investments and U.S. Foreign Policy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978). 27. Robert D. Putnam, “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games,” International Organizations 42:3 (1988), pp. 427–60. 28. Andrew Bennett, Joseph Lepgold, and Danny Unger, “Burden-Sharing in the Persian Gulf ,” ibid., 48:1 (1994), p. 44. 29. Michael N. Barnett and Jack S. Levy, “Domestic Sources of Alliances and Alignments: The Case of Egypt, 1962–1973,” ibid., 45 (1991), pp. 369–95. 828 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001 Finally, the concept of “free-riding” needs to be clarified. National de- fense has two components: deterrence and protection.30 Deterrence is per- ceived as a pure public good. Deterrence requires a combination of power and will to use it for retaliation. When allies are clustered and share more vital interests, and nuclear weapons are possessed by the alliance, deterrence is likely. In addition, military power and the will to retaliate should be per- ceived by the potential enemy. Credibility is essential to successful deter- rence.31 Sandler and Forbes argue that, under such a condition of effective deterrence, benefits are nonexclusive:32

Whenever an alliance’s commitment to retaliate against aggressive acts directed at any ally is credible, then the punishment threat of deterrence weapons provides nonrival benefits to the entire alliance. That is, additional nations can join the alliance without diminishing the deterrence provided to the existing allies.33 However, when deterrence fails, protection begins. Protection is an action rather than a threat, and protective weapons systems are more effective when they remain secret. In addition, Sandler has pointed out problems that arise with ubiquity:

A defensive line around one strategic town diminishes the amount of protection that other towns can receive. Military bases of one ally certainly create spillovers to another ally; however, oftentimes these military bases would not produce the same protection for another ally as would be provided had these military bases been located in its own country. Defensive missile systems located in one section of a country reduce the protection available to other sections, unless, of course, the range and accuracy of the missiles are sufficient to overcome this spatial factor.34 De Luca agrees that there is a “ubiquity problem” in protection by the armed forces, arguing that “it is easy to see how it could be very costly and even

30. Kenneth Boulding, Conflict and Defense: A General Theory (New York: Harper and Row, 1962); Thomas C. Schelling, Arms and Influence (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1966); Jacques M. van Ypersele de Strihou, “Sharing the Defense Burden Among Western Al- lies,” Yale Economic Essays 8:2 (1968), pp. 261–320; Todd Sandler, “Impurity of Defense: An Application to the Economics of Alliances,” Kyklos 30 (1977), pp. 443–60; idem., “The Eco- nomic Theory of Alliances: A Survey,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 37:3 (1993), pp. 446–83. 31. Gavin Kennedy, Burden-sharing in NATO (New York: Holmes and Meier, 1972). 32. De Luca disagrees. According to her, deterrence is neither non-rival nor non-exclusive because of credibility problems and additional costs because of extending the alliance’s nuclear protection to an additional country. Loretta de Luca, “Free-Riding in NATO: Reality or . . . Myth?” (Ph.D. dissertation, Cornell University, 1986). 33. Todd Sandler and John F. Forbes, “Burden-sharing, Strategy, and the Design of NATO,” Economic Inquiry 18:3 (1980), pp. 427. 34. Sandler, “Impurity of Defense,” pp. 334–35. JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 829 impossible to use the same personnel and equipment to protect a city or in- dustrial district in another country.”35 Another characteristic of protection is that many of its benefits are im- purely public and thus are rival and excludable on the grounds that most allies rely on both deterrent and protective aspects of national defense. When purely protective armed forces are used to protect larger geographic areas, the quality and quantity of protection provided to each region will decrease. When protective forces are withdrawn from country A and deployed to coun- try B, the benefits of the protective forces for country A are excluded at the will of the provider. In other words, as protective forces are required to pro- tect a larger area due to the joining of a new ally, the new spatial rivalry results in a thinning of forces.36 For instance, shifting from the “Win-Win” strategy of the U.S. to the “Win-Hold-Win” strategy can be understood as an effort to diminish this thinning effect. The “Win-Hold-Win” strategy was reviewed and proposed by defense secretary Les Aspin in the early Clinton administration. However, it was never officially accepted as a national secur- ity strategy. Aspin argued that the U.S. could hold off a second adversary with only a small commitment of forces while the majority of U.S. forces were being used to defeat the main adversary.37 (This “Win-Hold-Win” strategy was designed to produce fewer thinning effects than the “Win-Win” approach, which posited two full-fledged .38 In addition to the impure public aspects of defense discussed thus far, the private good provided by the allies’ defense efforts also needs to be consid- ered. Relying on van Ypersele de Strihou’s notion of private benefits, San- dler argues that defense expenditures yield many benefits that are purely public for individual allies, though these same benefits may be purely private goods for the alliances as a whole. For instance, armed forces can keep do- mestic order in times of emergencies, provide disaster relief, and provide a coastal guard. Both deterrent weapons and protective goods may yield pri- vate goods.39 Private goods such as an augmented national prestige and the protection of coastal waters can be produced by deterrent weapons and protective weapons, respectively. However, purely protective weapons tend to provide relatively more private goods because they can be used for intra-country purposes. Purely deterrent weapons, primarily related to national strategic weapons,

35. De Luca, “Free-Riding in NATO,” p. 74. 36. Todd Sandler and Jon Cauley, “On the Economic Theory of Alliances,” Journal of Con- flict Resolution 19:2 (1975), pp. 330–48. See also de Luca, “Free-Riding in NATO.” 37. Washington Post, June 17 and 25, 1993. 38. See Sandler and Forbes, “Burden-sharing.” 39. Sandler, “Impurity of Defense”; Sandler and Forbes, “Burden-sharing. ” 830 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001 provide fewer intra-country benefits.40 In short, most goods provided by al- lies’ defense expenditures are classified as impure public goods and are lo- cated between the pure public good and the private good ends of the spectrum.41 Palmer also argues that “the purchase of a private good by one ally should not affect the purchase of a private or public good by other allies. States certainly purchase some private benefits from their defense spend- ing.”42 Thus, the “free-riding” model, which depends on the assumption that each ally’s defense spending provides pure public good for an alliance, seems to overlook the nature of impure public goods in it.

Relaxing the Bargaining Model There are two different ways of understanding bargaining. One of these grows out of the tradition of political realism and can be called the “strategic perspective” or “power approach.” The power approach relies on the realist argument that international politics can be understood as the pursuit of inter- ests defined in terms of power.43 Rationality and coercive bargaining are the emphasis of this perspective.44 The purpose of this perspective is to find out how to win rather than how to mutually satisfy.

The Concept of Bargaining Neorealists (and realists more generally) are pessimistic about bargaining among states. Neorealists argue that the military power of the larger state enables it to coerce other states to cooperate for its favor. Thus, they believe power is the critical element for bargaining among states and do not give any weight to intra-alliance bargaining as an important process for achieving co- operation among allies. The other way of understanding bargaining is termed the “interests ap- proach” by Fisher and Ury.45 According to this approach, the purpose of bargaining is not to find out how to win but rather to find out how to mutu- ally satisfy. One of their main arguments is to focus on interests, not posi- tions. According to this perspective, military power cannot always be transformed into bargaining power. Threats and coercion are not enough and are seen as failures of influence. Instead, there are many other factors that influence bargaining power. For example, in Russell J. Leng’s view, “How

40. Ibid. 41. Sandler and Cauley, “On the Economic Theory of Alliances.” 42. Palmer, “Corralling the Free Rider,” p. 156. 43. Thomas C. Schelling, The Strategy of Conflict (New York: Oxford University Press, 1963). 44. Russell J. Leng, “Influence Techniques Among Nations,” in Behavior, Society, and Inter- national Conflict, eds. Philip E. Tetlock et al. (ibid., 1993). 45. Roger Fisher and William Ury, Getting to Yes (New York: Penguin Books, 1993). JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 831 much influence one or another party is able to bring to bear depends on the issues at stake, which representatives of which actors are participating in the decision-making and bargaining, and the forum in which the bargaining takes place.”46 Neoliberal institutionalists rely on this perspective and argue that an alliance has valuable functions. In addition, power is not the critical ele- ment for intra-alliance bargaining, but is just one of many factors. Though much of international relations literature on cooperation has viewed the bargaining process as the most common way to achieve coopera- tion among states, intra-alliance bargaining was given little attention until the early 1990s.47 Palmer uses the assumption of public goods theory and the analogy of the Prisoner’s Dilemma to provide the logic for the intra-alliance bargaining process. Palmer’s argument is that the “smaller members will in- crease (or decrease) their contributions to the supply of the good as the larg- est power increases (or decreases) its contributions.”48 He uses the logic of the Prisoner’s Dilemma as a metaphor for bargaining among allies. Accord- ing to the “Tit-For-Tat” strategy, mutual cooperation is the most likely out- come among allies’ options. Consequently, there will be a positive relationship between changes in the defense burden of the largest ally and that of its allies. In other words, the allies will change their defense burdens in the same direction as the largest ally. Palmer then provides the basis for a logic of cooperation among allies through the bargaining process. In the following section, we attempt to go further to provide a broader concept of the bargaining process in alliances by slightly revising Palmer’s bargaining model. We argue that smaller allies do not necessarily adjust their defense burdens in the same direction as that of the larger ally. The reason is that different types of bargaining can play a role in defining the nature of the alliance relationship over time.

The Revised Bargaining Model Palmer relies on the symmetric Prisoner’s Dilemma game to explain the posi- tive relationship between the defense burdens of the largest and smaller al- lies. However, in the asymmetric Prisoner’s Dilemma game, it is not necessary that the direction of changes (e.g., positive or negative) in a smaller ally’s defense burden is the same as that of the larger ally. Two asymmetrical Prisoner’s Dilemma games are used to show this. Let’s assume that Game A

46. Leng, “Influence Techniques Among Nations,” p. 114. 47. Reisinger’s 1983 study on East European military expenditures is an exception. He ar- gues that Olson-Zeckhauser’s free-riding model cannot explain the burden-sharing patterns of the World Trade Organization in the 1970s. Instead, Reisinger argues that political intra-alliance bargaining provides a better model for explaining the pattern of Soviet-East European relations. Reisinger, “East European Military Expenditures.” 48. Palmer, “Corralling the Free Rider,” p. 162. 832 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001

FIG U RE 1 Asymmetric Prisoner’s Dilemma

Game A Game B U.S. U.S. 2, 6 10, 2 4, 5 9, 2 SK SK 1, 9 8, 7 2, 8 6, 7 Note: Both games satisfy preference ordering of PD, that is, DC > CC > DD > CD. Each number represents the size of cost (defense burden). and Game B in Figure 1 represent two different types of games played by the larger ally and the smaller ally during different periods. For now, let us say the countries are the U.S. and South Korea during the 1960s and 1990s. Since the 1960s, cooperation has existed between these two countries. Dur- ing the 1960s, South Korea contributed the value of 2 because of its weak economy (Game A). In contrast, the U.S. disproportionately paid the value of 6 because of material, purposive incentives (e.g., feeling responsibility for managing Third World countries). Though South Korea had few resources, it paid the value of 2 to meet U.S. expectations. Because of strong strategic and political incentives for the U.S., America voluntarily paid the value of 6 with- out explicit bargaining, and expected or agreed upon a contribution of 2 from South Korea. In the late 1970s, however, as a result of changing domestic and interna- tional contexts, the U.S. could not afford to pay the value of 6, and conse- quently decreased its contribution to 5 and coerced South Korea to pay more than before. This situation is represented by Game B. As a result, South Korea increased its defense burden from a value of 2 to 4, even though the U.S. decreased its defense burden only from 6 to 5. During the 1980s and 1990s, this asymmetric cost-pair (4,5) continued (i.e., Game B). If these changes were the results of negotiated agreements, they might be understood as the results of explicit bargaining. Thus, the direction of change (e.g., posi- tive or negative) in the defense burden for the smaller allies is not necessarily the same as that of the larger ally

Types of Bargaining There are three important types of bargaining: tacit bargaining, latent bar- gaining, and explicit bargaining (formal negotiation). A wide variety of fac- tors contributes to these types of bargaining. For example, the nature of actors and bargainers, the perception of other actors, the issues, and the status of third parties are important factors that impact on the outcome of bargain- ing. First, capability, as well as past experiences and interests of actors can be considered as elements of the nature of actors. Regarding these factors, Mitchell argues that the status of parties in conflict has an important impact upon what is discussed, the way it is discussed, and the outcome of bargain- JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 833 ing.49 Schelling also argues that the “outcome depends greatly on what anal- ogies or precedents the definition of the bargaining issue calls to mind.”50 Second, the nature of bargainers can be an important factor that impacts on the outcome of bargaining. Putnam (argues that “the greater the autonomy of central decision-makers, the larger their win-set and the greater the likelihood of achieving international agreement.”51 Schelling and Mitchell also main- tain that giving negotiators complete flexibility and authority is a well-known principle and that the nature of negotiators contributes to the success or fail- ure of bargaining.52 Third, the perception of other actors is also an important factor in the outcome of bargaining. Fisher and Ury argue that, “Understand- ing the other side’s thinking is not simply a useful activity that will help you solve your problem. Their thinking is the problem.”53 Schelling also con- tends that “the outcome is determined by the expectations that each player forms of how the other will play. . . . The players must jointly discover and mutually acquiesce in an outcome or in a mode of play that makes the out- come determinate. Explicit bargaining may be defined as a process of diplo- matic exchanges or formal negotiations intended to reach an agreement.”54 In contrast to explicit bargaining, tacit bargaining seeks to achieve or main- tain a cooperative status quo.55 Tacit bargaining was first discussed by strate- gists such as Schelling and Osgood.56 Later, Mitchell characterized tacit bargaining as “a process leading up to (and directed toward) a final negotia- tion.”57 The detailed concept and the wide scope of situations in which tacit bargaining can occur were provided by Downs and Rocke, who define tacit bargaining as follows:

Tacit bargaining takes place whenever a state attempts to influence the policy choices of another state through behavior, rather than by relying on formal or infor- mal diplomatic exchanges. The process is tacit because actions, rather than rheto- ric, constitute the critical medium of communication. It is bargaining and not

49. C. R. Mitchell, The Structure of International Conflict (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1980). 50. Schelling, Arms and Influence, p. 69. 51. Putnam, “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics,” p. 436. 52. Schelling, Arms and Influence; Mitchell, The Structure of International Conflict. 53. Fisher and Ury, Getting to Yes, p. 22. 54. Schelling, Arms and Influence, p. 197. 55. George W. Downs and David M. Rocke, Tacit Bargaining, Arms Races, and Arms Con- trol (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1990); Catherine C. Langlois and Jean-Pierre P. Langlois, “Tacit Bargaining in International Relations: A Game Model and a Case Study,” Jour- nal of Conflict Resolution 40:4 (1996), pp. 569–96. 56. Schelling, Arms and Influence; Robert E. Osgood, Alliance and American Foreign Policy (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1968). 57. Mitchell, The Structure of International Conflict, p. 197. 834 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001 coercion because the actions are aimed at influencing an outcome that can only be achieved through some measure of joint voluntary behavior.58 Tacit bargaining, thus, can be characterized as a process that relies more on actions than communications or face-to-face negotiations. The study con- ducted by Langlois and Langlois also presents empirical validation of tacit bargaining in the alliance context, based on the case study of relations be- tween Japan and the U.S.59 In short, tacit bargaining is a process that relies on actions intended to influence the allies’ policy through voluntary changes. The iterated Pris- oner’s Dilemma is one archetypal tacit bargaining situation. Thus, the tacit bargaining structure requires that “fear outweighs temptation” and that “deci- sions are made repeatedly in time with no precise expectation of whether or when the game could end.”60 Of course, pure tacit bargaining is rare. In- stead, states often link action-based tacit bargaining with communication- based formal or informal negotiations.61 Latent bargaining is another aspect of bargaining between or among allies. Latent bargaining results when one is in a bargaining context in an alliance without the support of any action or overt negotiation. It is not a process but a situation. Whenever an alliance is formed and comes into effect, latent bargaining begins to occur. In other words, latent bargaining always exists in the alliance context. Carpenter describes the existence of latent bargaining in the alliance context, although he categorizes it as tacit bargaining, arguing that

[d]uring the 1950s the United States established an elaborate network of alliances and bilateral security agreements with nations on the perimeter of the . The tacit bargain between the United States and its newly acquired allies, clients, and protectorates was that Washington would shield (with conventional and, if necessary, nuclear weapons) those countries from Soviet aggression. America’s dependents, in turn, would provide bases for U.S. forces and augment U.S. military strength with their own forces if deterrence failed. Although the bar- gain was never stated in such crass terms, that was always its substance.62 We argue that the above situation is not tacit bargaining but latent bargain- ing. The reason is that the above situation is not a process, although tacit bargaining presumes a process and latent bargaining merely refers to a situa-

58. Downs and Rocke, Tacit Bargaining, p. 3. 59. Langlois and Langlois, “Tacit Bargaining in International Relations.” 60. Ibid., pp. 573–74. 61. Downs and Rocke, Tacit Bargaining. 62. Ted G. Carpenter, “South Korea: A Vital or Peripheral U.S. Security Interest,” in The U.S.-South Korean Alliance: Time for a Change, eds. Doug Bandow and Ted G. Carpenter (New Brunswick and London: Transaction Publishers, 1992), p. 5. JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 835 tion. Although the bargaining is not stated in explicit terms, allies are in the bargaining context as long as the alliance exists. In the alliance context, la- tent bargaining always exists unless an action or explicit negotiation is under- taken to change the behavior of other allies. The status of latent bargaining tends to change to tacit or explicit bargaining when the context changes. Ta- ble 1 shows comparisons of these different types of bargaining.

A Case Study of the U.S.-South Korea Alliance Using the Revised Bargaining Model In order to explain the U.S.-South Korea alliance case, we employ a slightly revised concept of Putnam’s win-sets. Putnam’s win-sets are facilitating fac- tors and constraints that decide the size of win-sets, which in turn affect the outcome of bargaining. However, our concept of win-sets, denoted as “Win- Sets,” includes more diverse factors as determinants. While Putnam’s win- sets mainly concern domestic games among domestic constituents, Win-Sets consider situational factors at the state as well as at the domestic level. More specifically, threat and interests at the state level are considered along with domestic constituents as determinants of Win-Sets. Therefore, we investigate both constraining and facilitating factors at the state, as well as the domestic level. We also analyze how much each factor significantly functions as a constraint or facilitating factor. There are some difficulties in explaining how factors at both the state and domestic levels combine to determine the size of Win-Sets. The extent to which facilitating factor A expands and constraint B contracts Win-Sets is not simple to determine. Nor is it easy to calculate the size of Win-Sets consider- ing all facilitating and constraining factors at both the domestic and state levels. However, there is a similar problem in Putnam’s concept of win-sets, where it is also difficult to measure the size of win-sets decided by domestic constraints and domestic facilitating factors. For example, calculating how much the win-set is affected by company A, which may face low costs as result of the agreement, and by company B, which is A’s competitor and may face high costs, is similarly difficult. Another difference between our Win-Sets and Putnam’s win-sets is that the outcomes of bargaining at the international level and the domestic ratification process are not necessarily formal but could be informal or tacit. Putnam argues that ratification refers to any decision process at the domestic level that is necessary to endorse an international-level agreement.63 However, he does not limit it to a congressional function, even considering public opinion as one of the actors at the domestic level. Furthermore, these ratification

63. Putnam, “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics,” p. 436. 836 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001

TA BLE 1 Comparison of Latent, Tacit, and Explicit Bargaining in the Alliance Con- text

Type of Bargaining Differences in Form and Goal Latent Situation No formal or informal action or negotiation Tacit Process Goal is to achieve or maintain a cooperative status quo Relies on actions rather than formal negotiation Explicit Process Goal is to reach an agreement Relies on diplomatic exchanges or formal negotiations (some form of direct or face-to-face contact) processes can be assumed to be an informal or tacit bargaining form. For instance, Berejikian argues that “ratification processes differ by regime type but are assumed to exist in one form or another in all regimes.”64 Therefore, the outcomes of bargaining and the domestic ratification processes can be not only formal but also informal or tacit. Moreover, the outcome of bargaining can be a one-sided decision, because of tacit bargaining.

An Analysis of the U.S.-South Korea Alliance The defense burden of South Korea, measured as its defense share of GNP, is a dependent variable and the target of preferences for each country in the Win-Sets.65 This study sets out to examine whether the defense burdens of South Korea fall within the overlapped range of Win-Sets for each country. The U.S. defense burden, measured as overall U.S. defense expenditures as a

64. Jeffrey Berejikian, “Revolutionary Collective Action and the Agent-Structure Problem,” American Political Science Review 86:3 (1992), p. 650. 65. During the , keeping the mutual defense treaty and the U.S. military presence were vitally important for South Korea to deter threats. The presence of the American forces acted as a tripwire to automatically involve the U.S. in any conflict on the peninsula; this contrib- uted to the deterrence. The U.S. was thus viewed as an important supporter of South Korea. For the U.S., the presence of its military in South Korea was an important barrier to the expansion of the Soviet Union, because Korea was considered a front-line state in the global containment of communism. After the Cold War, the presence of U.S. forces played a less important role in South Korea’s security than during the 1960s and 1970s. Thus, South Koreans’ gratitude for wartime support is rather faded. For the U.S., with the demise of its major threat, the Soviet Union, the importance of the Korean Peninsula is also shrinking. Thus, the presence or extent of U.S. forces in South Korea is a more flexible issue compared to the previous period, though both countries have a consensus on the need for a certain role for U.S. forces. These changes in the U.S. and South Korean views on the U.S. military presence are related to the structure of their defense burden-sharing relationship. See Robert Martin, “Security Relations: A U.S. View,” in Korea-U.S. Relations: The Politics of Trade and Security, eds. Robert A. Scalapino and Hongkoo Lee (Berkeley: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, 1988). JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 837 percentage of its GNP, is used as an intervening variable. There may be a validity problem with this variable as an indicator of U.S. concerns about the alliance between two countries. The reason is that only part of total U.S. defense expenditure is used for this alliance. Thus, we assess this variable. For instance, when we look at U.S. troop presence in Korea, we see a direct correlation with the American defense burden. During the 1960s–when the defense burden was over 8%–the troops numbered more than 60,000. When the defense burden decreased, during the late 1960s and 1970s, the troop numbers also decreased, from 67,000 in 1968 to 39,000 in 1979. When the defense burden increased during the Reagan administration, the troop pres- ence also increased. In the 1990s, when the defense burden decreased, the troop presence level also decreased, to 35,000 in 1993.66 We can also as- sume that a high level of troop presence creates new expenditures, because a large portion of defense spending is used for personnel (salaries and bene- fits).67 Thus, we can say that the Korea-related portion of the U.S. defense burden indicates the level of concern about the alliance between the two countries. This is because some of the domestic factors such as public opin- ion or congressional activities affect the dependent variable through the U.S. defense burden.68 The first contextual factor is the threat, considered at the state level.69 Threat is assessed according to its source; the relative capability of that source as indicated by relative military expenditures as well as conventional weapons; and its intention, indicated through hostile provocation. The sec- ond factor is the economic condition of each country, which indicates its degree of ability to contribute to defense. For example, the high rate of cuts in congressional appropriation of defense spending, or public opposition to a high level of defense spending, negatively affect the U.S. defense burden. As a result, the U.S. could decrease its defense burden and pressure South Korea to increase its defense burden in order to maintain the status quo.70 This set

66. Department of Defense (DOD), Annual Reports, 1982 and 1995. 67. Gavin Kennedy, The Economics of Defense (London: Faber and Faber, 1975). 68. Thomas Hartley and Bruce Russett, “Public Opinion and the Common Defense: Who Governs Military Spending in the United States?” American Political Science Review 86:4 (1992), pp. 905–15. See also Uk Heo, “The Defense-Growth Nexus in the United States Revis- ited,” American Politics Quarterly 28:1 (2000), pp. 110–27. 69. Not all the contextual factors are equally influential, because of various domestic, social, and political differences in each country. For example, during the 1960s and 1970s, decision- making on the defense burden in South Korea was largely in the hands of a small group of people and was more affected by other pressures than by political or social ones. 70. A general discussion of the defense-growth relationship in South Korea can be found in Uk Heo, “Defense Spending and Economic Growth in South Korea: The Indirect Link,” Journal of Peace Research 36:6 (1999), pp. 699–708; idem., “The Political Economy of Defense Spend- ing in South Korea,” ibid., 33:4 (1996), pp. 483–90. See also Uk Heo and Karl DeRouen, Jr., 838 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001 of economic contextual factors includes the GNP share, the relative size of per capita GNP, and the Prosperity Index. In addition, the budget deficit or surplus is used as another indicator of economic condition. The next set of contextual factors includes political and public support within U.S. public opinion on issues of internationalism and the degree of defense spending. Congressional activities on defense burden-sharing among allies and appropriation of defense spending are also examined. Finally, in- terests for each country are considered as facilitating factors at the state level. Security, political, and economic interests are considered. Measurement of these variables and contextual factors is summarized in Table 2. How these contextual factors affect the defense burden of South Korea is shown in Figure 2. The level of South Korea’s defense burden is a result of the dynamic interactions among these domestic- and state-level factors. Some factors directly affect the defense burden of South Korea, while others indirectly affect it through the intervening variable of the U.S. defense bur- den. Figure 2 provides an explanation for the decision-making on the defense burden of South Korea that is more dynamic than the free-riding model or Palmer’s bargaining model, because more facilitating or constraining factors at both the state and domestic levels are considered. However, bargaining is an important process in producing an outcome based on these individual fac- tors. In other words, the outcome (South Korea’s defense burden) is achieved through bargaining that is influenced by these contextual factors. The concept of “Win-Set” will be applied to three cases to examine the influ- ence of the nature of bargaining types (latent, tacit, or explicit) on the defense burden. Latent bargaining (easy-riding): 1961–68. From 1961 until 1968, South Korea was able to enjoy a relatively small defense burden without any pres- sure from the U.S. to increase it. Several contextual factors at both the do- mestic and state levels can be identified as affecting this situation. First, during this period, the U.S. perceived the growing strength of the Communist bloc and the close link between and the bloc, especially , as a serious threat. North Korea’s greater military expenditures, superior weaponry, and willingness to attack–indicated by hostile provocation–lent credibility to this potential threat. Second, while economic conditions in the U.S. were not a constraint, they were in Seoul. South Korea could not afford to allocate more resources for defense because of its minimal economic capa-

“Military Expenditures, Technological Change, and Economic Growth in the East Asian NICs,” Journal of Politics 60:3 (1998), pp. 830–46; Uk Heo and Kwang H. Ro, “Military Expenditures and Economic Growth in South Korea and Taiwan,” International Interactions 24:2 (1998), pp. 201–16. JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 839

TA BLE 2 Description of Variables and Contextual Factors

Variables and Contextual Factors Descriptions and Measurements Dependent Defense South Korea’s defense expenditures as a SK variable burden percentage of its GNP; South Korea’s share of costs to station U.S. forces in the Korean Peninsula (1988) Intervening Defense U.S. overall defense expenditures as a U.S. variable burden percentage of its GNP State-level Threat Source; relative military expenditures and SK factors conventional weapons inventory (NK vs. SK); U.S. Intention reflected by hostile provocation by North Korea Interests Security interests–strategic, augmentive, and SK preemptive; U.S. Political interests–democracy, human rights, economic and social development, peace, Cold War politics; Economic interests–bilateral trade balance, U.S. government grants and credits toward South Korea Domestic Economic GNP share and relative size of per capita GNP SK factors conditions (SK vs. U.S.); U.S. Prosperity Index; Domestic budget deficit or surplus Political and Public support–effects of public opinion on U.S. public internationalism and the level of defense support spending; Political support–congressional legislative activities on defense burden-sharing among allies and cuts in appropriation of defense spending bility compared to that of the U.S. Neither country was constrained by a budget deficit. Third, the U.S. executive branch had public and bipartisan support for its foreign policy and defense-spending decisions. Lastly, the U.S. had a strong security interest in having military bases and other facilities in South Korea to promote deterrence. Therefore, as described in Figure 3, the U.S. Win-Set was extended to the point of b1 because of the reasons discussed above. South Korea’s Win-Set overlapped enough with that of the U.S. to ensure a stable alliance, although its defense burden was far short of that of the U.S. In short, respective Win-Sets largely overlapped without specific conflict or bargaining. 840 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001

FIG U RE 2 Multidimensional Interactions of Domestic and State-Level Factors for the Defense Burden of South Korea: Some Hypotheses

State Level Factors

Interests Threat Perception

Domestic Factors + + Economic Conditions + Defense Burden of SK South Korea

U.S. + - +/- Congressional - Economic Opposition + U.S. Defense Burden Conditions

- Domestic Public Opposition Factors - + +

Interests Threat Perception

State Level Factors

FIG U RE 3 Win-Sets on the Defense Burden of South Korea

South Korea’s Defense Burden (imaginary numbers) 0 5 12 . . . b1 a1

Ideal preference for Ideal preference for South Korea the U.S.

This large overlap explains why South Korea’s dependence on U.S. mili- tary support cannot be considered as free-riding or defection. As long as its contributions met U.S. expectations, South Korea was not free-riding. An ally can be charged with defection only when its contribution fails to meet a partner’s expectations or previously agreed levels. Thus, as long as the re- spective Win-Sets overlap, South Korea’s dependence cannot be considered free-riding. That means the smaller ally contributes more than (or at least as JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 841 much as) the larger ally expects, or as needed to conform to previously agreed levels (the larger ally’s Win-Set). Only when no overlapped range exists between respective Win-Sets can this be considered defection. That situation takes place when the smaller ally decreases its contribution and con- tributes less than the larger ally’s expectation or previously agreed level (the larger ally’s Win-Set) or when the larger ally increases the level of its expec- tation (i.e., contracts its Win-Set) because of changes in contextual factors. Since neither defection nor free-riding is indicated by South Korea in the 1960s, its dependence relationship with the U.S. is better designated “easy- riding,” meaning that Korea enjoyed asymmetrically smaller contributions without pressure from the U.S. to increase them. This study views easy- riding as the outcome of latent bargaining. As noted above, latent bargaining exists as a prevailing condition in any alliance. Latent bargaining exists as long as respective Win-Sets overlap without conflict. Only when a change in a contextual factor disturbs this equilibrium, decreasing or erasing the overlap in Win-Sets, does action or negotiation occur. Because no such change pro- voked the transformation of latent into explicit or tacit bargaining as regards the defense burden of the U.S.-South Korean alliance, South Korea must be considered an easy-rider, not a free-rider. Tacit bargaining (Nixon doctrine): 1969. Analysis of contextual factors at the domestic and state levels helps explain South Korea’s increased contribu- tions to the defense burden at a time when U.S. contributions decreased. During the late 1960s, the degree of threat from Pyongyang in terms of source, capabilities, and intention remained the same as during the early and middle parts of the decade. A possible North Korean attack supported by China and/or the Soviet Union was perceived as a serious threat by both the U.S. and South Korea. Although the relative economic capability of South Korea slightly in- creased in the late 1960s, it was still small compared to that of the U.S. South Korea’s constrained economic conditions hampered its ability to in- crease its contribution to the defense burden, whereas economic conditions in the U.S. did not constrain American foreign policy. However, major changes occurred on the U.S side after the War. The U.S. cut defense spend- ing and asked its allies, including South Korea, to increase their contribution to security. This change caused South Korea to fear abandonment by the U.S. Thus, South Korea increased its defense spending in both a voluntary and coerced manner. Another major change in the late 1960s was increasingly strong opposition in Congress and among the public toward the Johnson and Nixon administra- tions’ foreign policy. Congressional debates over whether the U.S. should reduce its troop presence abroad and increase allies’ defense burdens were 842 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001

FIG U RE 4 The Changes of Win-Sets on the Defense Burden of South Korea, 1969

South Korea’s Defense Burden (imaginary numbers) 0 5 12 . . . b1 a1 b2 a2

1960s 1970s Ideal preference for Ideal preference for South Korea the U.S. frequent. The public also showed strong opposition to active U.S. involve- ment in world affairs, and decreasing support for defense spending, as a re- sult of the . In short, strong opposition to foreign policy positions from the Congress and the public acted as significant constraints to foreign policy decision-making in the executive branch. In Figure 4, U.S. congressional and public opinion, as well as some changes in political interest, are shown to act as constraints, shifting the U.S. Win-Set from b1 to b2. These domestic constraints contracted the acceptable limit for South Korea’s defense burden from b1 to b2. South Korea, with a slightly improved economy, had to move its Win-Set from a1 to a2 to main- tain critical security interests. South Korea’s increase of its defense burden in that period can be under- stood as both voluntary and coerced. It was voluntary inasmuch as Seoul pursued self-reliance because of fear of abandonment. It was coerced in that new norms set by the alliance, namely, decreased U.S. support, compelled the change. Thus, analysis of contextual factors at the domestic and state levels based on the concept of Win-Sets provides the rationale for adopting a bar- gaining model. That is, there exists a bargaining process (formal or informal) between allies on the defense burden. This case of bargaining was largely initiated by the announcement of the Nixon Doctrine.71 There is no public record that diplomatic exchanges or formal negotiations were undertaken to reach an agreement on the defense burden of South Korea. Thus, this study characterizes this case as tacit bargaining. This case of tacit bargaining supports the point that the direction of changes (e.g., positive or negative) in defense burdens for a smaller ally is not necessarily the same as for the larger ally. As discussed above, although the U.S. decreased its defense burdens during the 1970s, South Korea in- creased its own. As Figure 4 shows, changes in respective Win-Sets are able

71. The Nixon Doctrine, in reality, threw responsibility for allies’ defense back to themselves. See Laura Stone, “Whither Trade and Security? A Historical Perspective,” in The U.S.-Japan Alliance: Past, Present, and Future, eds. Michael J. Green and Patrick M. Cronin (New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1999). JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 843 to explain why South Korea increased its defense burden even as the U.S. decreased its own. Thus, the relaxed bargaining model proves to have greater explanatory power than Palmer’s bargaining model, which argues only a pos- itive relationship between changes in the defense burden of the larger ally and the smaller ally. Explicit bargaining (6% of the GNP): 1979. Contextual factors have been analyzed to determine why South Korea increased its defense burden to the level of 6% of its GNP. To understand why South Korea made an agreement with the U.S., which required such a large level of defense burden, four sets of contextual factors must be considered using the logic of Win-Sets. First, unlike the previous period, there was little possibility of Chinese or Soviet support for North Korea during the late 1970s. North Korea alone was the main source of threat. Thus, the U.S. perception of threat from North Korea was lower than before. However, the quantitative superiority of North Korea’s weapons over those of South Korea still threatened South Korea. Thus, South Korea’s perception of threat from North Korea was still high. Second, during the late 1970s, the U.S. government had large budget deficits, which reached 4% of GNP. These growing budgetary constraints partly af- fected the Carter administration’s decreasing commitment to the U.S.-South Korean alliance. However, the budget deficit for South Korea was not a problem during the same period. Instead, relative economic capability, though it increased significantly, functioned as a moderate constraint in deci- sion-making on defense policy. Third, U.S. congressional legislative activi- ties related to the defense burden of its allies were not significant during the late 1970s. The congressional appropriation rate on defense spending was also very high, since there was little opposition in Congress to the Carter defense policy. Moreover, the public did not think the government was spending too much on defense. Public opinion functioned only as a con- straint on the U.S.’s active involvement in world affairs. Lastly, although the U.S. attempted to withdraw its ground forces, it continued to consider the Korean Peninsula vital to its security and essential to its national goals. Yet, due to a reduced threat of North Korea acting alone, security interests de- clined in importance compared to the 1960s. For South Korea, the U.S. alli- ance and, specifically, the presence of U.S. forces, were still critical to deterring any North Korean attack. South Koreans were particularly inter- ested in annulling the troop withdrawal plan, for security reasons. The U.S. also had a significant political interest in improving South Korea’s record on human rights. South Korea, on the other hand, had significant economic in- terests such as consecutive bilateral trade surpluses and U.S. grants and cred- its. 844 ASIAN SURVEY, VOL. XLI, NO. 5, SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001

FIG U RE 5 The Changes of Win-Sets on the Defense Burden of South Korea, 1979

South Korea’s Defense Burden (imaginary numbers) 0 5 12 . . . b1 a1 b2 a2

late 1970s early 1980s Ideal preference for Ideal preference for South Korea the U.S.

In sum, the U.S. faced constraints including a continuing federal deficit and public opposition, as well as facilitating factors such as significant secur- ity and political interests, and the perception of a moderate threat. South Korea was constrained by limited economic capability, plus facilitating fac- tors such as a high level of threat perception, crucial security interests, and significant economic interests. Constraints for each country, which con- tracted their respective Win-Sets, could be used as leverage in bargaining. These contextual factors played a role in constructing Win-Sets on South Korea’s defense burden. As shown in Figure 5, the continuing budget deficit, consecutive bilateral trade deficits, South Korea’s poor record on human rights, and lessened perception of threat all helped shrink the Win-Set for the United States (Congress did not play a significant role in contracting the Win-Set). As a result, the U.S. range for possible acceptance of South Ko- rea’s defense burden contracted, moving from b1 to b2. In view of these U.S. constraints, plus several facilitating factors for South Korea, Seoul could not help but comply by boosting its defense burden. The biggest factor that led South Korea to agree to a defense burden of 6% of its GNP was the annulment of the U.S. troop withdrawal plan. This was seen by South Korea as a critical security interest against the strong threat posed by North Korea. In addition, South Korea’s improved economic condition and bilateral trade surplus played partial roles in enlarging the Win-Set on its defense burden. This was an example of explicit bargaining between the two countries. It was fully discussed in meetings between respective ministries of South Korea and the U.S. with the objective of reaching an agreement. And the final agreement was made in the summit meeting between the presidents of the two countries in 1979.

Conclusion In this paper, we have revisited the free-riding and bargaining models of de- fense burden-sharing, and developed a relaxed bargaining model. By exam- ining defense burden-sharing in the U.S.-South Korean alliance, the model presents empirical validation of the theoretical arguments. We make three arguments based on the theoretical and empirical findings. First, we argue JONG-SUP LEE AND UK HEO 845 that South Korea’s pattern of disproportionately smaller contributions in terms of the defense burden during 1961–68 should be characterized as latent bargaining rather than free-riding. The reason is that South Korea, because it made the contributions expected by the U.S., committed neither defection nor the exploitation which, in the Prisoner’s Dilemma, characterizes free-riding. We suggest as a more precise formulation the new concept of “easy-riding,” which explains well why South Korea’s overall contribution to the common defense was disproportionately smaller than America’s. Second, the Nixon Doctrine is characterized as tacit bargaining because it was a process that relied on actions intended partly to influence South Korea’s policy on its defense burden, but whose goal was not to reach an agreement. The Nixon Doctrine was an action that significantly influenced South Korea’s defense burden. Third, the 1979 agreement, which set South Korea’s defense burden at 6% of GNP, can be seen as explicit bargaining because it was reached through formal and diplomatic negotiation. In conclusion, we argue that the logic of free-riding does not have enough explanatory power for defense burden-sharing in alliances nor enough per- suasive power to impact intra-alliance bargaining processes. We also argue that the relaxed bargaining model, which includes three types of bargaining (latent, tacit, and explicit), performs better in accounting for the defense bur- den relationship in the U.S.-South Korean alliance. The reason is that the nature of bargaining in the alliance changes as the context changes and is affected by changes in facilitating and constraining factors. This conclusion, however, needs to be made with caution because it is based on only one case study, the U.S.-South Korea alliance, although the model can still be applied to similar types of alliances.