Central Bank Balance Sheets and the Liquidity Trap

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Central Bank Balance Sheets and the Liquidity Trap Preliminary Centralbankbalancesheetsandtheliquiditytrap MichaelT.Kiley * March2003 Version2.1 *Address : WhileonLeave(September2001-August2003) —OECDEconomicsDepartmentCS1,2rue AndrePascal,75016ParisFRANCE. Email : [email protected] . PermanentAddress :MailStop67, FederalReserveBoard,Washington,DC20551. Email : [email protected] . Acknowledgements :Thisisasubstantiallyrevisedversionofanearlierpaper,“Escapingaliquiditytrap: Anold-fashionedanalysiswithanewtwist”.IwouldliketocolleaguesattheFederalReserveBoardand studentsatJohnsHopkinsUniversityinWashington,DCfordiscussionsthatprovidedthebaseforthis researchandDavidRomerforskepticalcommentsonanearlierdraft.Theviewsexpressedhereinare thoseoftheauthor,anddonotrepresentthoseoftheOECD,theFederalReserveBoard,ortheirrespective staffs. i Centralbankbalancesheetsandtheliquiditytrap Abstract Theeffectivenessofpolicyinaliquiditytrapisconsideredinasimplemodel.Themodel illustratestheinteractionbetweenfiscalandmonetarypolicy.Ithighlightshow traditionalpolicyresponses,suchasexpansionaryopen-marketoperationsorbond- financedtaxcuts,havenostimulativevalue,butnon-traditionalfiscal/monetaryactions, suchasmoney-financedtaxcutsornon-Ricardiantaxcuts,arestimulative.Thefiscal theoryofthepriceleveliscrucialinaliquiditytrap,asmoneylosesitsspecialcharacter oncethenominalinterestratehitszero.Finally,theanalysishighlightstworesultsof practicalrelevanceregardingcentralbanklossesandtheexchangerateeffectsofpolicies inaliquiditytrap.Withregardtotheformer,themodelillustratesthatanymonetary actionthatliftstheeconomyfromtheliquiditytrapmustinvolveadeteriorationofthe centralbank’sbalancesheet;hence,aninstitutionalframeworkthatforbidssuchlosses hindersanescapefromaliquiditytrap.Withregardtothelatter,monetaryactionsthat succeedinliftingtheeconomyfromaliquiditytrapgeneratearealcurrencyappreciation, reflectingthefiscalnatureofthemonetaryaction;hence,suchactionscannotbe criticizedon“beggar-thy-neighbor”grounds. JELCodes:E52,E31,B22 Keywords:LiquidityTrap,Deflation,FiscalandMonetaryPolicyInteraction,Fiscal TheoryofthePriceLevel ii 1. Introduction Previouslyrelegatedtothedustbinofhistory,theliquiditytrapisback–inmodernJapan andontheresearchagenda. 1Theappropriatepolicyresponsehasprovencontroversial. Suggestionsincludeaninflationtarget(Krugman(1998)),fiscalexpansion(Posen (1998)),aprice-leveltarget(Wolman(1998),Lilico(2002)),monetaryexpansion (Meltzer(1999)),ataxoncurrencyholdings(BuiterandPanigirtzoglou(1999)),currency depreciation(McCallum(1999),CoenenandWieland(2003)),andacombinationofa currencydepreciationandprice-leveltarget(Svensson(2001)).Mostoftheseproposals areatleastimplicitlydiscussedbelow,astheeffectsofdifferentmonetaryandfiscal actionsareexamined.Unfortunatelytheseproposalsmayhavelimitedeffectiveness,at leasttotheextentthatabaselinegeneralequilibriummodelwithmonetaryfrictions providesareasonableguideforpolicy. Themodeldevelopedhereinisatwo-period,deterministicopen-economymodel withanoptimizingrepresentativeconsumerandflexibleprices.Inthemodel, expectations(or,morepreciselygivenperfectforesight,futurevalues)areveryimportant (forconsumptiondecisions,assetprices,andhencefortheliquiditytrap).Theresults demonstratethatthemonetaryauthority,throughopen-marketoperations,cannot engineerinflation,price-leveltargetsorcurrencydepreciationoncetheeconomyenters theliquiditytrap.ThissuggeststhatSvensson’s(2001)foolproofpolicycannotliftthe economyfromaliquiditytrapwithoutfiscalorbalancesheeteffectsashasbeenclaimed (apointdevelopedmorebelow). 2Thisresultisstandardforthetypeofmodelanalyzed, buthighlightsthatsuggestionsforsuchpoliciesmusteitherinvolvemonetaryactions otherthansecuritypurchasesorimperfectionsnotincludedinthemodel,suchas imperfectsubstitutabilitybetweendifferentassetsthatgeneratesportfoliobalanceeffects. Suchimperfectionsmaynotallowforverypowerfuleffectsofmonetarypolicyina liquiditytrap. 3 1Krugman(1998)getscreditforthesnappyphrasingandanearlyreturntothetopic. 2SomereadersmayimmediatelyobjectbeforeturningtotheanalysisthatSvensson(2001)doesnotrelyon portfoliobalanceeffects.However,acarefulreadingofhisappendix2suggestsotherwise. 3Lebow(1993)presentsacogentdiscussionofthelimitedrole“non-traditional”monetarychannels,such asportfoliobalanceorcreditchannels,mayhaveinaliquiditytrap,evenifsuchchannelsarepowerful outsidealiquiditytrap. 1 Traditionalfiscalpolicymayalsoberelativelyimpotentforseveralreasons. First,whenfiscalpolicyispursuedinaRicardianfashion(asdefinedbyWoodford (2001)orCochrane(1998)),theaggregatedemandeffectsofdeficit-financedtaxcutsis nil(orverylimited)becauseofRicardianequivalence(Barro(1974)).Inaddition, governmentconsumptionandinvestmentmaybe(good)substitutesforprivatespending, implyingthatincreasesingovernmentspendingmayhavelittleeffectonaggregate demand(i.e.,asmallgovernmentspendingmultiplier(Krugman(1999))).Boththese reasonsmayexplainpartoftheapparentlyweakaggregatedemandeffectsoffiscal stimulusinJapaninthelate1990s(OECD(2000)).Anotherlimitoffiscalpolicymaybe theabilityofthefiscalauthoritytopursueexpansionarymeasuresgiventhelong-run fiscaloutlookandthefeasibilityofraisingfuturerevenuesorcuttingfutureexpenditures. Thisconcernmayhavebeenmoreimportantinlimitingthedegreeoffiscalexpansion pursuedbyJapanrecently(astheratioofgovernmentdebttoGDPexceeded120percent in2000andimplicitpublicpensionliabilitiesarelarge). Giventheimpotenceofsecuritiespurchasesorbond-financedtaxcutswhen facingaliquiditytrap,innovativemonetaryandfiscalpolicyactionsareexaminedinthe model.Monetaryactionstorelaxthegovernment’sbudgetconstraintornon-Ricardian fiscalpolicycanlifttheeconomyfromtheliquiditytrap.Theappealtothefiscaltheory ofthepriceleveliscrucial,asmoneylosesitsspecialcharacter(i.e.,anecessarybut dominatedassetclass)oncethenominalinterestratehitszero.Themonetaryandfiscal authoritiesmustcommittoinflatingaway(loosely,monetizing)someportionof outstandingnominalliabilities.Inessence,theeffectsofmonetaryactionsrepresent somepleasantmonetaristarithmetic–theboostingofinflationthroughthefiscaleffects ofmonetarypolicyemphasizedbySargentandWallace(1981).Itshouldbenotedthat relaxationofthegovernment’sbudgetconstraintthroughmonetaryexpansionisoften mentionedasapossibility(e.g.,Clouseetal(2000),andBernanke(2000)),buttypically isfrowneduponasinappropriate.Suchreasoningisdifficulttocomprehend,asmoney andbondsareperfectsubstitutesinaliquiditytrap;sinceconsumersarewillingto increasetheirholdingsofmoneyinaliquiditytrapandthegovernmentcanlowertax 2 burdensbyincreasingthesupplyofmoneywithoutresourcecosts,itwouldseem appropriateforthegovernmenttoissuemoremoneyandcuttaxes. 4 Twopracticalissuesarisefromtheanalysis.First,themonetaryactionssuggested havenegativeeffectsonthecentralbank’sbalancesheet,reflectingthemonetizationof governmentliabilities.Providingmoneytothetreasurywithoutanaccompanying increaseinassetsonthecentralbank’sbalancesheetimpliesthattheoutstandingstockof moneyexceedstheassetsheldbythecentralbank.Ofcourse,suchabalancesheet deteriorationisnoteconomicallyimportant;acentralbankcouldalwayssimplyprint moremoneywheneveranyonewishedtoexchangetheirmoneyforanasset(more money),withoutanychangeinthestockofmoneyheldbythepublic.However,such lossesarepreventedincertaininstitutionalsetups,mostnotablyinJapan,wheretheBank ofJapanisaprivateentitythatmustremainsolvent.Sinceonlymonetaryactionswith negativeconsequencesforthecentralbank’sbalancesheetallowanescapefromthe liquiditytrap,suchinstitutionalframeworkslimitthepotentialofmonetarypolicy. Inaddition,thetypeofmonetaryexpansiondescribedmayleadtoarealcurrency appreciationintheshortrun(ratherthantherealdepreciationpredictedbyportfolio balancechannels),reflectingthefiscalnatureofthemonetaryaction.Hence,suchpolicy actionscannotbecriticizedonthe“beggar-thy-neighbor”groundsofcallsforcurrency depreciation(e.g.,Stevens(2001),thediscussioninSvensson(2001)andCoenenand Wieland(2003)).Thistheoreticalpredictionhasnotbeenpreviouslydiscussed,and suggestsevenmorestronglythepotentialdesirabilityofthepolicyforJapanintheyears following2001,whenworldaggregatedemandappearstobefalteringandbeggar-thy- neighboractionsmayaggravateadversedevelopmentselsewhereinAsiaorintheUnited States( TheEconomist (2001)). 2.Asimpleeconomy Themodelisofasmall,openeconomy,consistingofarepresentativeconsumeranda government(whichcanbebrokendownintoacentralbankandtreasuryifsucha 4Outsideoftheliquiditytrap,increasesinthemoneysupplyboostthenominalinterestrate(byincreasing inflation)andhencecreatedistortions.However,suchdistortionsareabsentintheliquiditytrap,wherethe nominalinterestrateiszero. 3 breakdownisdesired).Theeconomyconsistsoftwoperiods,period1andperiod2. Domesticoutputisexogenous,andthepricelevelisperfectlyflexible.Hence,the liquiditytrapisasituationwherethemonetaryauthoritycannotinfluencethepricelevel throughopen-marketoperations,ratherthanasituationwherethemonetaryauthority cannotinfluenceoutput.AsinKrugman(1998),addingstickypricesanddemand- determinedoutputlevelswouldtransformtheliquiditytraptoasituationwherethe centralbank’sattemptstoinfluenceoutputarethwarted,therebyinjectingaKeynesian flavorintotheanalysis.However,suchamodificationaddsnoinsightandhenceis ignoredforsimplicity. 2.1Therepresentativeconsumer Therepresentativeconsumerspreferencesoverconsumptionofthedomestically producedgood(c(j),j=1or2)andtheforeigngood(g(j),j=1or2)aregivenby Eq.1 a ln[ c )]1( + 1( − a)ln[ g )]1( + D{a ln( c )2( + 1( − a)ln[ g )]2( ,} where“a”isaparameter(equaltotheexpenditureshareofdomesticgoodsintotal consumptionexpenditure)andDisthediscountrate.(Notethatinwhatfollows, variablesdenotedwithalower-caseletterrefertorealvariables,suchasconsumption,
Recommended publications
  • It's BAAACK! Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap
    IT’S BAAACK! JAPAN’S SLUMP AND THE RETURN OF THE LIQUIDITY TRAP In the early years of macroeconomics as a discipline, the liquidity trap - that awkward condition in which monetary policy loses its grip because the nominal interest rate is essentially zero, in which the quantity of money becomes irrelevant because money and bonds are essentially perfect substitutes - played a central role. Hicks (1937), in introducing both the IS-LM model and the liquidity trap, identified the assumption that monetary policy was ineffective, rather than the assumed downward inflexibility of prices, as the central difference between “Mr. Keynes and the classics”. It has often been pointed out that the Alice-in-Wonderland character of early Keynesianism, with its paradoxes of thrift, widow's cruses, and so on, depended on the explicit or implicit assumption of an accommodative monetary policy; it has less often been pointed out that in the late 1930s and early 1940s it seemed quite natural to assume that money was irrelevant at the margin. After all, at the end of the 30s interest rates were hard up against the zero constraint: the average rate on Treasury bills during 1940 was 0.014 percent. Since then, however, the liquidity trap has steadily receded both as a memory and as a subject of economic research. Partly this is because in the generally inflationary decades after World War II nominal interest rates stayed comfortably above zero, and central banks therefore no longer found themselves “pushing on a string”. Also, the experience of the 30s itself was reinterpreted, most notably by Friedman and Schwartz (1963); emphasizing broad aggregates rather than interest rates or monetary base, they argued in effect that the Depression was caused by monetary contraction, that the Fed could have prevented it, and implicitly that even after the great slump a sufficiently aggressive monetary expansion could have reversed it.
    [Show full text]
  • How to Escape a Liquidity Trap with Interest Rate Rules Fernando Duarte Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, No
    How to Escape a N O . 776 Liquidity Trap with M A Y 2 0 1 6 Interest Rate Rules REVISED JANUARY 2019 Fernando Duarte How to Escape a Liquidity Trap with Interest Rate Rules Fernando Duarte Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 776 May 2016; revised January 2019 JEL classification: E43, E52, E58 Abstract I study how central banks should communicate monetary policy in liquidity trap scenarios in which the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates is binding. Using a standard New Keynesian model, I argue that the key to preventing self-fulfilling deflationary spirals and anchoring expectations is to promise to keep nominal interest rates pegged at zero for a length of time that depends on the state of the economy. I derive necessary and sufficient conditions for this type of state contingent forward guidance to implement the welfare-maximizing equilibrium as a globally determinate (that is, unique) equilibrium. Even though the zero lower bound prevents the Taylor principle from holding, determinacy can be obtained if the central bank sufficiently extends the duration of the zero interest rate peg in response to deflationary or contractionary changes in expectations or outcomes. Fiscal policy is passive, so it plays no role for determinacy. The interest rate rules I consider are easy to communicate, require little institutional change and do not entail any unnecessary social welfare losses. Key words: zero lower bound (ZLB), liquidity trap, new Keynesian model, indeterminacy, monetary policy, Taylor rule, Taylor principle, interest rate rule, forward guidance _________________ Duarte: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (email: [email protected]) The author thanks Sushant Acharya, Tobias Adrian, Christine Breiner, Marco Del Negro, Gauti Eggertsson, Marc Giannoni, Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, Alfonso Irarrazabal, Chris Sims, Rui Yu, and, particularly, Anna Zabai for comments and discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • A Neoclassical Theory of Liquidity Traps
    A Neoclassical Theory of Liquidity Traps Sebastian Di Tella∗ Stanford University August 2017 Abstract I propose a flexible-price model of liquidity traps. Money provides a safe store of value that prevents interest rates from falling during downturns and depresses in- vestment. This is an equilibrium outcome — prices are flexible, markets clear, and inflation is on target — but it’s not efficient. Investment is too high during booms and too low during liquidity traps. The optimal allocation can be implemented with a tax or subsidy on capital and the Friedman rule. 1 Introduction Liquidity traps occur when the role of money as a safe store of value prevents interest rates from falling during downturns and depresses investment. They can be very persistent, and are consistent with stable inflation and large increases in money supply. Liquidity traps are associated with some of the deepest and most persistent slumps in history. Japan has arguably been experiencing one for almost 20 years, and the US and Europe since the 2008 financial crisis. This paper puts forward a flexible-price model of liquidity traps and studies the optimal policy response. The baseline model is a simple AK growth model with log utility over consumption and money and incomplete idiosyncratic risk sharing. Markets are otherwise complete, prices are flexible, and the central bank follows an inflation-targeting policy. During downturns idiosyncratic risk goes up and makes risky capital less attractive. Without money, the real interest rate would fall and investment would remain at the first best level. ∗ I’d like to thank Manuel Amador, Pablo Kurlat, Chris Tonetti, Chad Jones, Adrien Auclert, Arvind Krishnamurthy, Narayana Kocherlakota, Bob Hall, and John Taylor.
    [Show full text]
  • Macro-Economics of Balance-Sheet Problems and the Liquidity Trap
    Contents Summary ........................................................................................................................................................................ 4 1 Introduction ..................................................................................................................................................... 7 2 The IS/MP–AD/AS model ........................................................................................................................ 9 2.1 The IS/MP model ............................................................................................................................................ 9 2.2 Aggregate demand: the AD-curve ........................................................................................................ 13 2.3 Aggregate supply: the AS-curve ............................................................................................................ 16 2.4 The AD/AS model ........................................................................................................................................ 17 3 Economic recovery after a demand shock with balance-sheet problems and at the zero lower bound .................................................................................................................................................. 18 3.1 A demand shock under normal conditions without balance-sheet problems ................... 18 3.2 A demand shock under normal conditions, with balance-sheet problems ......................... 19 3.3
    [Show full text]
  • JAPAN's TRAP Paul Krugman May 1998 Japan's Economic Malaise Is First and Foremost a Problem for Japan Itself. but It Also Poses
    JAPAN'S TRAP Paul Krugman May 1998 Japan's economic malaise is first and foremost a problem for Japan itself. But it also poses problems for others: for troubled Asian economies desperately in need of a locomotive, for Western advocates of free trade whose job is made more difficult by Japanese trade surpluses. Last and surely least - but not negligibly - Japan poses a problem for economists, because this sort of thing isn't supposed to happen. Like most macroeconomists who sometimes step outside the ivory tower, I believe that actual business cycles aren't always real business cycles, that some (most) recessions happen because of a shortfall in aggregate demand. I and most others have tended to assume that such shortfalls can be cured simply by printing more money. Yet Japan now has near-zero short-term interest rates, and the Bank of Japan has lately been expanding its balance sheet at the rate of about 50% per annum - and the economy is still slumping. What's going on? There have, of course, been many attempts to explain how Japan has found itself in this depressed and depressing situation, and the government of Japan has been given a lot of free advice on what to do about it. (A useful summary of the discussion may be found in a set of notes by Nouriel Roubini . An essay by John Makin seems to be heading for the same conclusion as this paper, but sheers off at the last minute). The great majority of these explanations and recommendations, however, are based on loose analysis at best, purely implicit theorizing at worst.
    [Show full text]
  • Congressional Record United States Th of America PROCEEDINGS and DEBATES of the 112 CONGRESS, FIRST SESSION
    E PL UR UM IB N U U S Congressional Record United States th of America PROCEEDINGS AND DEBATES OF THE 112 CONGRESS, FIRST SESSION Vol. 157 WASHINGTON, THURSDAY, FEBRUARY 10, 2011 No. 21 House of Representatives The House met at 10 a.m. and was The Lillian Trasher Orphanage, loudest voice on the field because called to order by the Speaker pro tem- begun in 1911 by an American from that’s the kind of person that she is. pore (Mr. CHAFFETZ). Jacksonville, Florida, is one of the old- She is passionate, she is fierce in her f est and longest-serving charities in the dedication to her friends, and she has world. It currently serves over 600 chil- devoted her entire life to making her DESIGNATION OF SPEAKER PRO dren, along with widows and staff. This community, her State, and her country TEMPORE pillar of the community has been home a better place for all Americans. The SPEAKER pro tempore laid be- to thousands of children who needed Bev recently had a curveball thrown fore the House the following commu- food, shelter, and a family. Orphanage at her when she was diagnosed with nication from the Speaker: graduates serve around the world as amyotrophic lateral sclerosis, also WASHINGTON, DC, bankers, doctors, pastors, teachers, and known as ALS—Lou Gehrig’s Disease. February 10, 2011. even in the U.S. Government. Bev has always taken life head-on, and I hereby appoint the Honorable JASON Despite many challenges over the that’s how she addressed this chal- CHAFFETZ to act as Speaker pro tempore on years, the wonderful staff, now led by lenge, the same way she has lived her this day.
    [Show full text]
  • Does Central Bank Independence Frustrate the Optimal Fiscal-Monetary Policy Mix in A
    Does Central Bank Independence Frustrate the Optimal Fiscal-Monetary Policy Mix in a Liquidity Trap? By Paul McCulley, Chair, GIC Global Society of Fellows and Zoltan Pozsar, Visiting Scholar, GIC Global Society of Fellows Paper to be presented at the Inaugural Meeting of the Global Interdependence Center’s Society of Fellows on March 26, 2012 at the Banque de France, Paris March 26, 2012 Abstract “[T]he role of an independent central bank is different in inflationary and deflationary environments. In the face of inflation, which is often associated with excessive [government borrowing and] monetization of government debt, the virtue of an independence central bank is its ability to say “no” to the government. [In a liquidity trap], however, excessive [government borrowing] and money creation is unlikely to be the problem, and a more cooperative stance on the part of the central bank may be called for. Under the current circumstances [of a liquidity trap], greater cooperation for a time between the [monetary] and the fiscal authorities is in no way inconsistent with the independence of […] central bank[s], any more than cooperation between two independent nations in pursuit of a common objective [or, for that matter, cooperation between central banks and fiscal authorities to facilitate war finance] is consistent with the principle of national sovereignty.” Governor Ben S. Bernanke 1 Section I - Introduction The United States and much of the developed world are in a liquidity trap. However, policymakers still have not embraced this diagnosis which is a problem as solutions to a liquidity trap require specific sets of policies.
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity Traps in a World Economy
    Liquidity Traps in a World Economy Robert Kollmann Université Libre de Bruxelles & CEPR [email protected], www.robertkollmann.com American Economic Association meetings, January 2021 ● Motivation: persistent low interest rates & inflation in advanced economies ● Shock transmission in liquidity trap depends on SOURCE OF LIQUIDITY TRAP & SHOCK PERSISTENCE ● Does low interest rate environment matter for domestic and internat. shock transmission? ● In “expectations-driven” liquidity trap: transmission of persistent shocks is similar to transmission in normal ● Contribution of paper: analysis of times (away from ZLB) : “expectations-driven” liquidity traps, driven by Home TFP ↑⇒Home GDP ↑, Foreign GDP↓ pessimism about future inflation Home real exch. rate depreciates (Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohé & Uribe (2001)) , ⇒ Irrelevance” of “expectations-driven” liquidity trap in OPEN economies ● Opposite transmission in “fundamentals-driven” ● Develop 2-country New Keynesian model with liquidity trap” : (“Topsy-turvy” world) Zero Lower Bound (ZLB) constraint, floating Home TFP ↑⇒Home GDP ↓, Foreign GDP ↑ exchange rate. Combination of ZLB and active Home real exch. Rate appreciates! monetary policy (Taylor principle) leads to multiple equilibria ● Intuition: in expectations-driven liquidity trap, inflation is function of natural real interest rate ● Expectations-driven liquidity traps can be ⇒ muted response of inflation to persistent shocks synchronized or unsynchronized across ⇒ dynamics as under inflation targeting away from ZLB countries: cross-country correlation of liquid. =============================================== traps is indeterminate ►With transitory shocks: big changes in natural real interest rate, to which mon. pol. cannot respond at ZLB ● Expectations-driven liquidity trap model can ⇒ expectations-driven & fundamentals-driven liquidity better explain persistent liquidity traps than traps show similar responses to transitory shocks (very fundamentals-driven liquid.
    [Show full text]
  • The New-Keynesian Liquidity Trap
    The New-Keynesian Liquidity Trap John H. Cochrane Univeristy of Chicago Booth School of Business New Keynesian models: Diagnosis I Consensus NK diagnosis: “Natural” rate r << 0 (?), i = 0, p = 2.5%, i p too high. I Fix Et ct+¥. “Too high” real rate consumption grows too fast, level too low. ! I Why do we not see more p = r? model. ! 40 Consumption 3% trend 2000•2007 New•K eynesian 35 PIH 30 25 20 Percent 15 10 5 0 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 New Keynesian models: Policy I Policy: All the laws of economics change sign at the zero bound. 1. Open mouth operations, forward guidance, commitments work. Further in the future has larger effect today. 2. Expected inflation is good, raises output. 3. Totally wasted government spending, even if financed by taxes, can have arbitrarily high multipliers. 4. Capital destruction, technical regress, hurricanes, broken windows are good. 5. All get stronger as price frictions diminish, with ¥ limit. 6. Though stickiness is the central friction causing our troubles, don’t fix! it! Making prices sticker is good. I And if you don’tagree, you’re(unprintable) I NK model is not Paleo-Keynesian. MPC = 0. Intertemporal substitution. ¥ 1 ct = Et lim ct+T s (it+s rt+s pt+s ) ds T ¥ s=0 ! Z This paper I Write down the model. Confirm NK diagnosis & policy predictions. I Show they come from one, particular, arbitrary equilibrium choice. "Most" (plausible?) equilibria do not have these features. I NK/Taylor choice: Fed has two, independent policy tools: interest rate policy and equilibrium-selection policy.
    [Show full text]
  • Congressional Record United States Th of America PROCEEDINGS and DEBATES of the 112 CONGRESS, FIRST SESSION
    E PL UR UM IB N U U S Congressional Record United States th of America PROCEEDINGS AND DEBATES OF THE 112 CONGRESS, FIRST SESSION SENATE—Thursday, February 10, 2011 The Senate met at 4 p.m. and was Ms. KLOBUCHAR thereupon assumed I want to talk about taking police of- called to order by the Honorable the chair as Acting President pro tem- ficers off the street. In the Repub- SHERROD BROWN, a Senator from the pore. licans’ haste to make as many cuts as State of Ohio. f possible, they have proposed elimi- nating the COPS hiring program. COPS PRAYER RECOGNITION OF THE MAJORITY stands for Community Oriented Polic- LEADER The Chaplain, Dr. Barry C. Black, of- ing Services, and it has helped put fered the following prayer: The ACTING PRESIDENT pro tem- thousands and thousands of police offi- Let us pray. pore. The majority leader is recog- cers and sheriffs on patrol around the Mighty God, thank You for Your nized. country, about 450 of them in Nevada. great compassion that removes our f Under the Republican plan, many could lose those jobs and many more guilt and purifies us from trans- SCHEDULE gressions. As our lawmakers and those who want to join the force will not be who work with them face the chal- Mr. REID. Madam President, fol- able to. The COPS program also helps lenges to liberty, give them light for lowing any leader remarks there will our law enforcement departments af- their path and courage to live for You. be a period of morning business with ford the computers and communica- Lord, enrich them with the durable Senators allowed to speak for up to 10 tions equipment they need to do their satisfaction that comes from doing minutes each.
    [Show full text]
  • Fundamental Driven Liquidity Traps: a Unified Theory of the Great
    Fundamental Driven Liquidity Traps: A Unified Theory of the Great Depression and the Great Recession Gauti B. Eggertsson1 and Sergey K. Egiev1 1Department of Economics, Brown University December 29, 2019 Abstract This paper integrates the New Keynesian literature on the liquidity trap to offer a unified theory of the Great Recession and the Great Depression in the United States. We first give an overview of fast moving forces that can lead to a liquidity trap, such as a banking crisis and debt deleveraging shocks and then turn to long acting forces such as the aging of the population and a rise in inequal- ity. These latter forces are often associated with the idea of secular stagnation. We then analyze a number of monetary and fiscal policy interventions within the standard New Keynesian model as well as in a model in which there is a permanent trap. The paper closes by applying the theory to understand the onset and recovery from the U.S. Great Depression and addressing key questions related to the U.S. Great Recession. — Preliminary, First Draft, Comments Welcome, please address to [email protected] —- 1 Introduction It is sometimes argued that the crisis of 2008, often referred to as the Great Recession (GR), caught the economic profession by a surprise, that this suggested some major embarrassment to the profession, and to the field of macroeconomics in particular. While it is true that the events of the 2008 were not expected by many, lost in this narrative is that prior to the crisis there was a relatively mature literature that studied in some detail the type of events that lead to the crisis.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary and Fiscal Policy in a Liquidity Trap: the Japanese Experience 1999-2004
    Monetary and Fiscal Policy in a Liquidity Trap: The Japanese Experience 1999-2004 Mitsuru Iwamura Takeshi Kudo Tsutomu Watanabe∗ Waseda University Hitotsubashi University Hitotsubashi University First draft: June 6, 2004 This version: January 31, 2005 Abstract We characterize monetary and fiscal policy rules to implement optimal responses to a sub- stantial decline in the natural rate of interest, and compare them with policy decisions made by the Japanese central bank and government in 1999—2004. First, we find that the Bank of Japan’s policy commitment to continuing monetary easing until some prespecified conditions are satisfied lacks history dependence, a key feature of the optimal monetary policy rule. Second, the term structure of the interest rate gap (the spread between the actual real interest rate and its natural rate counterpart) was not downward sloping, indicating that the Bank of Japan’s commitment failed to have sufficient influence on the market’s expectations about the future course of mon- etary policy. Third, we find that the primary surplus in 1999—2002 was higher than predicted by the historical regularity, implying that the Japanese government deviated from the Ricardian rule toward fiscal tightening. These findings suggest that inappropriate conduct of monetary and fiscal policy during this period delayed the timing to escape from the liquidity trap. JEL Classification Numbers:E31;E52;E58;E61;E62 Keywords:Deflation; zero lower bound for interest rates; liquidity trap; history dependent inflation targeting; interest rate gap; Ricardian fiscal policy ∗Correspondence: Tsutomu Watanabe, Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University, Kunitachi, Tokyo 186-8603, Japan. Phone: 81-42-580-8358, fax: 81-42-580-8333, e-mail: [email protected].
    [Show full text]