Dugald Stewart on Education in His Political Economy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Dugald Stewart on Education in His Political Economy Dugald Stewart on Education in His Political Economy TOMOYUKI ARAI Chuo University [email protected] 1. Introduction Dugald Stewart lectured in political economy at Edinburgh University from 1800 to 1810, not only on theoretical economics and its abstract principles but also on the application of political economy to real-world problems. Stewart’s desire to provide education in political economy arose from a genuine interest in the improvement of the British education system. In his view, education was an important field, as shown in Outlines of Moral Philosophy (1793), which summarized his lectures on moral philosophy given at Edinburgh since 1785. There was titled ‘Of the Education of the Lower Orders; and of the Prevention and Punishment of Crimes’ under the heading of ‘political economy’ (Works Ⅷ, 5). This shows that Stewart had intended to lecture on political economy even before he began his series of lectures devoted to it in 1800. Additional evidence in this regard is provided by Stewart’s ‘Plan of Lectures on Political Economy, For Winter 1800–1801’, composed of six sections―‘Population’, ‘National Wealth’, ‘The Poor’, ‘Collective Police’, ‘Preventive Police’, and ‘Education’. Although these topics were reduced to four (‘Population’, ‘Wealth’, ‘Poor Relief’, and ‘Education’) in Stewart’s Lectures on Political Economy, education remained an important topic in his mind at the outset of his lectures on political economy in 1800. Stewart’s lectures on education at Edinburgh University in that period influenced many students, especially the so-called Edinburgh Reviewers (Henry Broughm, Francis Jeffrey, Francis Horner, and Sidney Smith). In this paper, I look mainly at Book 4 of Lectures on Political Economy, ‘Of the Education of the Lower Orders’, in order to bring to light the important fact that Stewart proposed various education and education policy reforms and to look at the details of these proposals. Then, on the basis of this discussion, I will try to describe the character and structure of Stewart’s educational thought overall, and to 1 elaborate the general argument that the approach to political economy education pioneered by Stewart had certain important benefits in early-nineteenth-century Scotland, after the death of Adam Smith. 2. Education for the Lower Class (1) In the initial part of Book 4 of Lectures on Political Economy, ‘Of the Education of the Lower Orders’, is the following passage: “Mr. Smith thinks that if, in our parish schools, instead of the little smattering of Latin which is sometimes taught there, and which is scarce ever of any use to the people, they were instructed in the elementary parts of geometry and mechanics, the literary education of the lower classes would, perhaps, be as complete as it well could” (Works Ⅸ, 327-328). Stewart basically agreed with Smith on this point; further, however, according to Stewart, even if the lower orders were to learn geometry and mechanics, it might contribute to their material security but would not help build up their human character or promote the security of the state. Stewart was more concerned with what he saw as moral corruption and immorality among the lower orders than among the upper class, because in his opinion an uncultivated, uneducated lower class would be more prone to agitation and revolt against the government, leading to the collapse of social order (Works Ⅷ, 54). “…I shall confine my attention to the only view of the subject which is immediately connected with the plan of he foregoing lectures; ――the importance of extending the means of an elementary education, not with a view to the discovery or embellishment of natural genius, but as the best security for the morals and good order of the community” (Works Ⅸ, 341). Stewart compares the education of the lower orders in Scotland with that in England. “…[A]lthough England had obtained the benefits of a regular government at a much earlier period than Scotland, the progress of national improvement was, by no means, so rapid there, or universal. This is particularly striking when we attend to the comparative attainments of the lower orders in the two countries; and it demonstrates, that in the present state of society, the diffusion of knowledge, even when assisted by the art of printing, will not be sufficient to secure the instruction 2 of the lower orders, unless proper arrangements for that purpose are made by the part of Government” (Works Ⅸ, 332). That is, according to Stewart, although England was strikingly more economically developed compared to Scotland, the Scottish approach to the education of the lower orders was superior1. This shows that Stewart was not critical of all aspects of the existing Scottish parochial school system, but he certainly did not see it as perfect, and he stated clearly that the government needed to develop more appropriate institutions for education in the future. In short, Stewart asserted the need for education reform in Britain in his era. He gave considerable attention to the education systems in foreign countries in Europe as well as in the United States, on the basis of various pamphlets and papers. For example, he explains the structure of parochial school in Denmark on the basis of William Coxe’s Travels into Poland, Russia, Sweden, and Denmark (1792). According to Coxe, in Denmark different schools for “boys” and “females” of the lower classes existed, where they learned reading, writing, and arithmetic. “[T]he children, who are unable to bear the expense of a proper education” could attend these schools and pay low tuition fees equivalent to only £6 a year, and the boarders £20. They learned history, geography, arithmetic, religion, and the German, French, and English languages (Works IX, 335-336. Cf. Coxe [1792] 2005. 186-188). Thus, in Denmark, education for women and affordable tuition were already a reality. The advanced Danish education system as described by Coxe had great impact on Stewart’s view of education. He remarks as follows on this topic in the introduction of Lectures on Political Economy (a text which was originally intended instead to be presented in the part third of his planned Dissertation: Metaphysical, Ethical, and Political Philosophy, a work which was ultimately not published until 1855, by William Hamilton in The Collected Works of Dugald Stewart). “This view of education, indeed, (considered in its connexion with intellectual improvement and the advancement of human knowledge,) properly belongs to the Philosophy of the Human Mind; which will be found to be very intimately connected with the most important objects of Political Economy. 1 Concerning the difference of authority and reputation in university between Scotland and England, see Withrington(1999, 9-17),Rothblatt (2003, 226-236). 3 In this respect, as well as in many others, the education of females (to whose care the task of early instruction must be, in a great measure, intrusted) will be found not undeserving of attention” (Works Ⅷ, 55). Stewart goes on to contrast the status of woman in the modern age, asserting that it was much higher than in ancient times (Works Ⅷ, 55-56), when, according to Stewart, they had been wholly overlooked as part of the social system (Works Ⅷ, 55). The reason why education for women had not ever been considered, according to Stewart, is that “systematical writers” had overlooked the natural endowments of the sexes and confounded the provinces and the duties of both sexes together.2 Stewart does not remark in detail on the subject of education for women in every part of the Lectures. But his basic assertion of the need of education for women still deserves attention in his context, since with the notable exception of Mary Wollstonecraft, few or no writers of the era discussed this matter extensively. Besides the case of Denmark, Stewart also considered other education systems in Continental Europe. In particular, in his view, the most remarkable advancement of education, on the basis of “the most enlightened and liberal principles[, had been seen] in some parts of Germany” (Works Ⅸ, 336). For this, Stewart primarily credited Frederick the Great of Prussia, although the matter is not explained in detail in his Lectures3. Stewart also paid close attention to education in America. He shows the school bill called “the hundred” which was proposed by the Committee of the first Virginian Assembly under the New Government of America. According to Stewart, the “hundred” in question was a plan to divide every county in Virginia into small school districts of five or six miles square for teaching reading, writing, and arithmetic to every child for free, and Latin and higher branches of arithmetic to small numbers of scholars. Stewart called this “a very beautiful idea,” because all children had the opportunity of education and because of the progressive 2 “Notwithstanding, however, these circumstances, the education of women has, till very lately, been almost entirely overlooked by systematical writers; and among the few who have treated of it, there has been, in general, a strange disposition to run into extremes. One set of theorist, undervaluing the natural endowments of the other sex, and inattentive to their immense importance in the social system, have adhered even in these times to the confined notions of our forefathers……” (Works Ⅷ, 56). 3 Stewart’s view of education in Germany is something like unclear, as Stewart does not point out Berlin University founded by Wilhelm von Humboldt in 1806 in Lectures. 4 scholarship system. This law, as he pointed out, had only been proposed and not passed by the Virginia assembly, but had nevertheless been greatly influential in the other states after the American Revolution. In those days, as state constitutions were being written and ratified, there was a major focus on equality of opportunity for all the people of education in those documents (Tsuburaku 1975, 58-60).
Recommended publications
  • The Development of the Theory of Money from Adam Smith to David Ricardo Jacob H
    The Development of the Theory of Money from Adam Smith to David Ricardo Jacob H. Hollander Quarterly Journal of Economics, volume 25, (1910-11) pp. 429-470 More than a generation separated the appearance of Adam Smith's "Wealth of Nations" in 1776 from the publication of David Ricardo's "High Price of Bullion" in 1810. Memorable as these years were with events in the industrial life of England, they witnessed but little change in the prevailing body of economic thought. The "Wealth of Nations," despite Hume's lament that the two stately quartos required too much thought and reflection to be popular, reached a tenth edition in 1799.(1) In the political world, Grenville in 1800 could remind Pitt of their common conviction as to "the soundness of Adam Smith's principles of political economy.''(2) In academic circles, Dugald Stewart was Adam Smith's successor in office and in spirit in the University of Edinburgh, attracting from 1800 on a notable group of gifted students to his eloquent exposition of the "Wealth of Nations.''(3) In the intellectual field, young men like Francis Horner, Lord Webb, James Mill, and Thomas Chalmers were supplementing legal and theological studies by critical reading of Adam Smith's text. There was some minor dissent from certain of Adam Smith's conclusions:(4) Dugald Stewart seems to have been less of the docile expositor and more of the independent critic than he would have us believe. James Anderson stood out vigorously for the utility of corn law bounties. Jeremy Bentham filed a cogent brief against the impolicy of usury laws.
    [Show full text]
  • The Development of the Theory of Money from Adam Smith to David Ricardo Jacob H
    The Development of the Theory of Money from Adam Smith to David Ricardo Jacob H. Hollander Quarterly Journal of Economics, volume 25, (1910-11) pp. 429-470 More than a generation separated the appearance of Adam Smith's "Wealth of Nations" in 1776 from the publication of David Ricardo's "High Price of Bullion" in 1810. Memorable as these years were with events in the industrial life of England, they witnessed but little change in the prevailing body of economic thought. The "Wealth of Nations," despite Hume's lament that the two stately quartos required too much thought and reflection to be popular, reached a tenth edition in 1799.(1) In the political world, Grenville in 1800 could remind Pitt of their common conviction as to "the soundness of Adam Smith's principles of political economy.''(2) In academic circles, Dugald Stewart was Adam Smith's successor in office and in spirit in the University of Edinburgh, attracting from 1800 on a notable group of gifted students to his eloquent exposition of the "Wealth of Nations.''(3) In the intellectual field, young men like Francis Horner, Lord Webb, James Mill, and Thomas Chalmers were supplementing legal and theological studies by critical reading of Adam Smith's text. There was some minor dissent from certain of Adam Smith's conclusions:(4) Dugald Stewart seems to have been less of the docile expositor and more of the independent critic than he would have us believe. James Anderson stood out vigorously for the utility of corn law bounties. Jeremy Bentham filed a cogent brief against the impolicy of usury laws.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction
    Notes Introduction 1.Peter Mandler, Aristocratic Government in the Age of Reform: Whigs and Liberals, 1830–1852 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1990), 14. 2.Roy Porter, English Society in the Eighteenth Century (Harmondsworth, England: Penguin Books, 1990), 112. 3. Byron, ‘Don Juan’, Canto 11; John Cannon, ‘New Lamps for Old: the End of Hanoverian England’ in The Whig Ascendancy: Colloquies on Hanoverian England, Cannon, ed. (London: Edward Arnold, 1988), 115. 4.Robert Stewart, Henry Brougham, 1778–1868: His Public Career (London: Bodley Head, 1985), 43–4, 120. 5.Donald Read, The English Provinces c. 1760–1960: A Study in Influence (London: Edward Arnold, 1964). 6.Brougham, ‘Rights and Duties of the People’, Edinburgh Review (November 1812):424, Dror Wahrman, Imagining the Middle Class: The Political Representation of Class in Britain c. 1780–1840 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995), 255. 7. J.C.D. Clark, English Society, 1660–1832: Religion, Ideology and Politics During the Ancien Regime (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000), 513. 8. T.A. Jenkins, The Liberal Ascendancy, 1830–86 (New York: St Martin’s Press, 1994), 19. 9. Jonathan Parry, The Rise and Fall of Liberal Government in Victorian Britain (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1993), 3–4. 10.Walter Bagehot, The English Constitution (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1966), 152. 11. Ibid., 28. 12.Richard Brent, Liberal Anglican Politics: Whiggery Religion and Reform, 1830–1 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1990), 28, 37, 39. 13. James Abercrombie to George Tierney, 1818, Tierney MSS. 14. Horner to Francis Jeffrey, 15 September 1806, Horner Papers 427. 15. Chester H. New, The Life of Henry Brougham to 1830 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1961), 2–3; David Hackett Fisher, Albion’s Seed: Four British Folkways in America (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1989), 647–8.
    [Show full text]
  • Durham E-Theses
    Durham E-Theses The work of Lord Brougham for English education McManners, T. How to cite: McManners, T. (1952) The work of Lord Brougham for English education, Durham theses, Durham University. Available at Durham E-Theses Online: http://etheses.dur.ac.uk/9971/ Use policy The full-text may be used and/or reproduced, and given to third parties in any format or medium, without prior permission or charge, for personal research or study, educational, or not-for-prot purposes provided that: • a full bibliographic reference is made to the original source • a link is made to the metadata record in Durham E-Theses • the full-text is not changed in any way The full-text must not be sold in any format or medium without the formal permission of the copyright holders. Please consult the full Durham E-Theses policy for further details. Academic Support Oce, Durham University, University Oce, Old Elvet, Durham DH1 3HP e-mail: [email protected] Tel: +44 0191 334 6107 http://etheses.dur.ac.uk ABSTRACT. THE Ti?ORK 0$ LORD BROUGHAM JOR ENGLISH EDUCATION. Various influences impelled Henry 3rougham (I778-I86S) along the path of educational reform. His? own early life and careful schooling in Scotland, his sensitivity to conditions, contactwith Continental reformers and the influence of the Utilitarian philos• ophy, all helped to mould his ideas. Brougham's ambition however gave the driving force to belief and educational reform was but one means of achieving greatness. The ambitious young 'lawyer came to London and politics in 1305, entering Parliament in 1610.
    [Show full text]
  • Leonard Horner: a Portrait of an Inspector of Factories
    BERNICE MARTIN LEONARD HORNER: A PORTRAIT OF AN INSPECTOR OF FACTORIES Leonard Horner was the most impressive and influential of the first English factory inspectors. For 26 years from 1833 to 1859 he adminis- tered the Factory Act mainly in the textile district of Lancashire. His work and that of his colleagues in the Factory Department made a success of this major experiment in legislative intervention in industry and despite the gloomy predictions of their early opponents they did not ruin the British economy in the process. The first generation of Inspectors laid the foundation for successive extensions of the Factory Act so that by the end of the 19th century working conditions and hours of labour for women and children were under legal regulation in all the major branches of manufacturing industry. Horner was ac- knowledged by his contemporaries to be the major figure among the early Inspectors; he even had the singular honour of being praised by Marx in Capital. This short biography will concentrate on Horner's work as Inspector of Factories since this is undoubtedly his major achievement. However it will also be concerned with other aspects of his life and interests, both because these have some importance in their own right and also in order to examine the extent to which Horner's life and thought form a coherent whole. Finally, an assessment will be made of Horner's place in social reform and in the development of English economic and social policy in the 19th century. I HORNER'S EARLY LIFE AND CAREER1 Leonard Horner was born in Edinburgh in 1785.
    [Show full text]
  • The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo
    THE WORKS AND CORRESPONDENCE OF DAVID RICARDO volume xi plan of the edition volume I. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation II. Notes on Malthus III. Pamphlets and Papers, 1809–1811 IV. Pamphlets and Papers, 1815–1823 V. Speeches and Evidence VI. Letters, 1810–1815 VII. Letters, 1816–1818 VIII. Letters, 1819–June 1821 IX. Letters, July 1821–1823 X. Biographical Miscellany XI. General Index THE WORKS AND CORRESPONDENCE OF David Ricardo Edited by Piero Sraffa with the Collaboration of M. H. Dobb 8 volume xi General Index liberty fund indianapolis This book is published by Liberty Fund, Inc., a foundation established to encourage study of the ideal of a society of free and responsible individuals. The cuneiform inscription that serves as our logo and as the design motif for our endpapers is the earliest-known written appearance of the word “freedom” (amagi), or “liberty.” It is taken from a clay document written about 2300 b.c. in the Sumerian city-state of Lagash. First published by Cambridge University Press in 1951. ᭧ 1951, 1952, 1955, 1973 by the Royal Economic Society Typographical design ᭧ 2004 by Liberty Fund, Inc. This edition of The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo is published by Liberty Fund, Inc., under license from the Royal Economic Society. 10 09 08 07 06 05 04 p 54321 All rights reserved Printed in the United States of America Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Ricardo, David, 1772–1823. [Works. 2004] The works and correspondence of David Ricardo / edited by Piero Sraffa; with the collaboration of M. H.
    [Show full text]
  • Journal of the Sydney Society for Scottish History
    Journal of the Sydney Society for Scottish History Volume 15 May 2015 SCOTTISH PERIODICAL ENLIGHTENMENT William Christie Australian National University VER twenty years ago now, David Riede suggested that the first O quarter of the nineteenth century, generally referred to as the ‘Romantic Period’, could as easily and should perhaps more accurately be entitled the ‘Age of Reviews’.1 Picking up on Riede’s revisionary suggestion, and because Ian Duncan’s notion of a ‘post- Enlightenment’ by its very name plays down the powerful continuities between the thinkers of the Scottish Enlightenment and some of their literal and metaphorical pupils in the nineteenth,2 I want to suggest calling it the ‘Periodical Enlightenment’. My choice of title is ironic, of course, not to say provocative, given that the Reviews are generally understood to have been deeply antipathetic to Romanticism. If the general reader knows anything at all about the early nineteenth century Reviews they know about their ‘relentless politicization of discourse’, to quote Kim Wheatley, ‘their reliance on (and abuse of) anonymity, their indulgence in so-called “personality” or personal attacks and, last but not least, their sway over public opinion’.3 What interests me in this lecture (and my reason for suggesting we rename the period) is this last: the ‘sway over public opinion’ assumed and enforced by the big Reviews—by the Edinburgh Review (begun in 1802) and the Quarterly Review (1809)—insofar as this sway confirmed their role in the culture of knowledge in early nineteenth-century Britain. My own research concentrates on the Edinburgh Review, on its multi-disciplinary approach to the organization and publication of knowledge and on the way it functioned in the knowledge economy of the period relative to other institutions and enterprises: relative to the universities and academies and lecturing institutions and what historians of science call 1 David G.
    [Show full text]
  • The Classical Economic Stage
    © Copyright, Princeton University Press. No part of this book may be distributed, posted, or reproduced in any form by digital or mechanical means without prior written permission of the publisher. CHAPTER ONE The Classical Economic Stage I. The Period of Classical Economics In any detailed discussion of a particular body of ideas, it is perhaps helpful to begin by indicating to the reader the period during which those ideas were of importance. There can be little doubt that the heyday of Classical economics was during the years 1800–1850. Delineation of the period during which Classical economics developed as a body of thought, came to be the ruling approach to economics, ultimately experienced a measure of stag- nation and decay, and was finally supplanted by the young and vigorous development of neo-Classical economics in the “Marginal Revolution,” is however a good deal less easy. At one end it is usual to date the era of Classical economics as begin- ning in 1776, with the publication of Adam Smith’s mighty Wealth of Nations. Such an approach has a strong prima facie appeal, but closer ex- amination raises doubts about it. On the one hand Classical economics owed a great deal to David Hume in certain critical areas, especially that of monetary theory. The relevant part of Hume’s Essays was published in 1752; and it is therefore doubtful if too much weight can be placed on the year 1776. Indeed the influence of Hume upon Smith cannot be ignored; they were close friends, and Hume was appointed by Smith to be his lit- erary executor.1 In addition the work of Adam Smith himself did not sud- denly spring from nothing in 1776.
    [Show full text]
  • Autograph Letters and Manuscripts of Economists, Philosophers, Statesmen &C
    Autograph letters and manuscripts of economists, philosophers, statesmen &c. Including Richard Cobden, Émilie Du Châtelet, Adam Ferguson, Harold Laski, Thomas Malthus, G. E. Moore, David Ricardo, Moritz Schlick, Adam Smith, Ludwig Wittgenstein, and Christian Wolff Bernard Quaritch Ltd List 2015/4 BERNARD QUARITCH LTD Recent Catalogues: 40 SOUTH AUDLEY STREET, LONDON W1K 2PR 1431 Travel & Exploration, Natural History Tel.: +44 (0)20 7297 4888 Fax: +44 (0)20 7297 4866 1430 Philosophy, Politics, Economics e-mail: [email protected] 1429 Continental Books website: www.quaritch.com 1428 In the scribe’s hand: Islamic manuscripts Bankers: Barclays Bank PLC, 1 Churchill Place, London E14 5HP Recent Lists: Sort code: 20-65-82 Swift code: BARCGB22 Sterling account IBAN: GB98 BARC 206582 10511722 2015/3 From the Library of Cosmo Alexander Gordon Euro account IBAN: GB30 BARC 206582 45447011 2015/2 English Books New Acquisitions Spring 2015 US Dollar account IBAN: GB46 BARC 206582 63992444 2015/1 Money: an Idea transformed by Use VAT number: GB 840 1358 54 Cover image from no. 23. Mastercard, Visa and American Express accepted Items marked with an asterisk (*) are subject to VAT within the EU. Cheques should be made payable to Bernard Quaritch Ltd © Bernard Quaritch Ltd 2015 NOBEL PRIZE-WINNING ECONOMIST * 1. ARROW, Kenneth Joseph (b. 1921), American economist and political theorist. Part of an autograph manuscript, signed ‘Kenneth J. ‘A SORT OF SUPPLEMENTARY CHANCELLOR OF THE Arrow’. [No place, c. 1989]. EXCHEQUER’ (GLADSTONE) Single sheet of US Letter size ruled paper, written on one side only, on * 2. BAGEHOT, Walter (1826-1877), political commentator, alternate lines, in black ink, paginated as number 10, with Arrow’s economist, and journalist.
    [Show full text]
  • The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo
    THE WORKS AND CORRESPONDENCE OF DAVID RICARDO volume vi plan of the edition volume I. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation II. Notes on Malthus III. Pamphlets and Papers, 1809–1811 IV. Pamphlets and Papers, 1815–1823 V. Speeches and Evidence VI. Letters, 1810–1815 VII. Letters, 1816–1818 VIII. Letters, 1819–June 1821 IX. Letters, July 1821–1823 X. Biographical Miscellany XI. General Index THE WORKS AND CORRESPONDENCE OF David Ricardo Edited by Piero Sraffa with the Collaboration of M. H. Dobb 8 volume vi Letters 1810–1815 liberty fund indianapolis This book is published by Liberty Fund, Inc., a foundation established to encourage study of the ideal of a society of free and responsible individuals. The cuneiform inscription that serves as our logo and as the design motif for our endpapers is the earliest-known written appearance of the word “freedom” (amagi), or “liberty.” It is taken from a clay document written about 2300 b.c. in the Sumerian city-state of Lagash. First published by Cambridge University Press in 1951. ᭧ 1951, 1952, 1955, 1973 by the Royal Economic Society Typographical design ᭧ 2004 by Liberty Fund, Inc. This edition of The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo is published by Liberty Fund, Inc., under license from the Royal Economic Society. 10 09 08 07 06 05 04 p 54321 All rights reserved Printed in the United States of America Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Ricardo, David, 1772–1823. [Works. 2004] The works and correspondence of David Ricardo / edited by Piero Sraffa; with the collaboration of M.
    [Show full text]
  • Dugald Stewart on Free Trade of Corn and Poverty in the Early Nineteenth Century Britain TOMOYUKI ARAI
    Dugald Stewart on Free Trade of Corn and Poverty in the Early Nineteenth Century Britain TOMOYUKI ARAI Chuo University, Tokyo Address for 2-3-16 Nagamine, Inagishi, Tokyo 206-0821, Japan; e-mail: [email protected], [email protected] Abstract Dugald Stewart (1753-1828)’s Lectures on Political Economy (1800-–1810), which was the first university course on economics in Britain, offered an attractive curriculum to his students, who included the founders of the Edinburgh Review . It also continued to be widely influential in Britain after his death. His lectures covered the following topics: population, national wealth, poor relief, and education. This paper aims to reinterpret Stewart’s economic thought, which introduced a new perspective on the political economy of the early nineteenth century. First, the paper discusses Stewart’s economic thought on contemporary corn trade. Stewart emphasized the necessity of freeing corn trade, cogently expressing his view on the subject. Second, the paper highlights the significance of his thought on poor relief, especially his proposed short-term remedies, in his political economy. Thus, this paper will show how Stewart’s economic thought was effective during the food crises after 1790s. ⅠⅠⅠ Dugald Stewart Dugald Stewart is known, alongside Thomas Reid, as a member of the moral sense school or as the author of Account of the Life and Writings of Adam Smith which he read to the Royal Society of Edinburgh in 1793. Stewart was an authoritative - 2 - political economist in the early nineteenth century who bridged the gap in political economy between Smith and Ricardo.
    [Show full text]
  • Draft Prepared for Presentation at the Brown University Political
    Draft Prepared for Presentation at the Brown University Political Philosophy Workshop February 1, 2007 The Seductiveness of System Edmund Burke’s Aesthetic Embrace of Adam Smith’s Philosophy Michael L. Frazer Postdoctoral Research Associate, Political Theory Project Department of Political Science, Brown University Associate of the Department of Government, Harvard University [email protected] The contemporary right consists of an alliance between defenders of the free market and defenders of traditional values. There is considerable disagreement as to whether this alliance is merely strategic or whether there is some deeper philosophical affinity between these two seemingly divergent worldviews. In order to help resolve this dispute, it might be helpful to begin with the observation that, in the English-speaking world, both economic libertarians and social conservatives often trace their intellectual heritage to certain eighteenth-century British men of letters. Many economic libertarians embrace Adam Smith as their intellectual founding father, while significant numbers of social conservatives similarly embrace Edmund Burke. One might therefore reasonably hope that scholarship on the relationship between the political philosophies of Adam Smith and Edmund Burke would shed some light on the contemporary alliance of economic libertarians and social conservatives. Unfortunately, there is no more of a scholarly consensus on the relationship between the respective ideas of Smith and Burke than there is on the possible affinity between the worldviews of their latter-day intellectual descendants. Just as there are many who see free- market capitalism and social traditionalism as fundamentally opposed to one another, so too are there many who see Smith and Burke in fundamental opposition.
    [Show full text]