EQUITY OR EFFICIENCY? EXPLAINING PUBLIC OFFICIALS’ VALUES IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES 1

PAPER IN PROGRESS. PLEASE DO NOT CITE

Marcos Fernández-Gutiérrez & Steven Van de Walle

1 The research leading to these results has received funding from the European Union’s Seventh Framework Programme under grant agreement No. 266887 (Project COCOPS), Socio-economic Sciences and Humanities.

Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

EQUITY OR EFFICIENCY? EXPLAINING PUBLIC OFFICIALS’ VALUES IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

Abstract

This paper analyses the value trade-offs leading public servants make in European counties. Top civil servants’ views, attitudes and behaviours exemplify the values public institutions cherish. By studying the values held by top civil servants one can deduct the dominant value approaches of public institutions. Using the 17- country COCOPS population study among central government top civil servants, this paper maps and explains the value trade-offs they make (Hammerschmid et al., 2016). More in particular, the paper analyses the classic equity- efficiency value trade-off (Okun, 1975). The paper will first provide a descriptive picture of top civil servants’ value preferences across 17 European countries. It will then try to explain differences by looking at the context within which these civil servants work. To explain civil servants’ personal position between equity and efficiency, we explore four distinct hypotheses.

Keywords: Public values, efficiency, equity, top civil servant

2 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

PUBLIC SERVICE VALUES: FACTORS EXPLAINING PUBLIC OFFICIALS’ VIEWS ON EQUITY IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

Introduction

Conflicting and incommensurable values have received a lot of attention in philosophy and , but less so in public administration where attention is limited to a fairly small group of scholars interested in public values. Yet, attention for public values appear to be on the rise (Box, 2015), and substantial progress has been made in relation to mapping, categorising and conceptualising public values (DeForest Molina and McKeown, 2012; Van der Wal & Huberts, 2008; Van Wart, 1998). This paper adds to the body of work on public values body by using data from 14 different countries.

Easton famously described politics as the authoritative allocation of values (Easton, 1965). Government has to make choices between conflicting values. These tensions between values can be found everywhere within the public sector, especially when there is allocation and redistribution. The ‘uneasy compromises’ between values are represented in institutional arrangements (Okun: 1975: 1). Public management is about managing contradictions (Greener, 2013; Pollitt and Bouckaert, 2014). Civil servants want to achieve values and objectives that may be incompatible (De Graaf et al., 2014; Andrews and Van de Walle, 2013; Andrews & Entwistle 2010) and thus have to choose in daily administrative practice. This paper analyses the value trade-offs top civil servants make, and more in particular the equity- efficiency trade-off, and the determinants of this trade-off. We follow Molina’s definition of value – ‘as a complex cognitive-emotional preference for some object, quality, or characteristic that serves as either a means to an end (instrumental value) or an end in itself (terminal value).’(Molina, 2015: 50).

The equity-efficiency trade-off

The efficiency-equity trade-off is one the perennial questions in the social sciences. A trade- off refers to situation where one has to balance or choose between two objectives that are opposite or that cannot be had at the same time (Merriam Webster dictionary). If one goes up, the other goes down. In a trade-off situation, two objectives cannot be achieved simultaneously. Examples of the efficiency-equity trade-off can for instance be found in the allocation of landing slots to planes, or in the order of serving clients in an administrative office, where it may be more efficient not to allocate in order of appearance. The issue is also very salient in school reforms, where officials have to find a balance between school efficiency improvements and avoiding social segregation.

3 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

The academic beginnings of the debate on the efficiency-equity trade-off have been attributed by Le Grand (1990) to Barry (1965), who was discussing the evaluation of social outcomes in politics and policy. Barry argues that, if there’s for someone a trade-off between equity and efficiency, this means that ‘If it’s a question of choosing between efficiency and equity, it takes a large potential increase in equity to make him accept a potential reduction in efficiency (and vice versa)’ (Barry, 1965: 7). While different concepts, equity and equality are often used interchangeably. Equality refers to a situation where everyone is given equal resources (here, public services), whereas with equity, the resources are related to need, in order to achieve an equality of outcomes.

Okun’s 1975 ‘Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff’ is probably the best known treatise on the efficiency-equity trade-off. Okun discussed the observation that society often prefers equality-based approaches over market-based efficiency-oriented ones; and that checks on markets are common and sometimes desirable. He argues that there are parts in society where society opts for more equality, thereby compromising efficiency (Okun: 1975: 5). The opposite is not discussed in great length in Okun’s book, because, addressing economists, he assumed economists would be familiar with such market logic already. Markets pursue efficiency ‘But that pursuit of efficiency necessarily created inequalities. And hence society faces a tradeoff between equality and efficiency’ (Okun, 1975: 1). In other words – ‘We can’t have our cake of market efficiency and share it equally’ (Okun:, 1975: 2)

The book is written with distributive policies in mind, and introduced the image of a ‘leaky bucket’. The leaky bucket refers to efficiency losses that occur during redistribution aimed at reducing inequality. These efficiency losses are due to changes in incentives following the redistribution and administrative costs involved in redistribution (Okun: 1975: 92). For Okun, the size of the leak – or how much efficiency loss one is willing to tolerate to increase equality, is a matter of taste. Okun compared a Rawls who would always prefer equality no matter how large the leak, to a Friedman who would give priority to efficiency, and would have a very low tolerance for leaks (Okun, 1975: 92). This article contributes to explaining differences in this taste among key policy makers: Central government top civil servants in 14 European countries.

Okun’s equality/efficiency trade-off has become a classic, but not everyone agrees there is actually a trade-off. Osberg (1995), for instance, refers to the observation that countries with high equality also tend to grow fast, and that hence the trade-off probably does not exist. Le Grand elaborated a convincing argument ‘that the notion of a trade-off is meaningless. For acceptance of this interpretation implies that efficiency can be defined only in relation to the ability of forms of social and economic organization to attain their primary objectives and that therefore efficiency cannot itself be one of those primary objectives. In this sense, if equity is

4 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off one of the objectives it is meaningless to talk of a trade-off (either in value or production) between equity and efficiency. Efficiency is not an objective in the sense that equity is an objective; rather, it is a secondary objective that only acquires meaning with reference to primary objectives such as equity’ (Le Grand, 1990: 560). Trade-offs, he argues, ‘can only occur between [..] primary objectives, of which efficiency is not one’ (199: 566). He (Le Grand, 1990) further argues that when people talk about the equity-efficiency trade-off, they probably don’t mean efficiency in its technical sense, but instead think about economic growth or Pareto-optimality.

Efficiency as a value following the NPM?

Technically, Le Grand is right. Yet, Rutgers and van der Meer (2010) argue that efficiency has always had a more substantive meaning in public administration (mainly up till the 1960s) beyond the mere technical one (as also used in Le Grand’s argument). Especially in recent decades, we would argue that efficiency in the public sector has also become a primary objective of itself. Efficiency improvements have been at the core of the NPM, and the big NPM reforms such as consumerism, agencification, performance management, or competition were all implemented with an aim of improving efficiency (Andrews, 2011: 282). Bozeman similarly posits the primacy of efficiency within the NPM: ‘It seems clear that, according to almost all descriptions of NPM, the driving values are performance and efficiency, while fairness, by any definition, rarely received much emphasis in NPM’ (Bozeman, 2007: 80). In the same book/article, he argues: ‘The values embodied in privatization and NPM […] are efficiency and effectiveness values, not equity, fairness, or communal values’ (Bozeman, 2007: 82). NPM’s focus on efficiency in this way stands in sharp contrast to e.g. the New Public Administration in the 1970s, where social equity was the core value (Box, 2015).

Efficiency is a core administrative value (Andrews & Entwistle, 2013; Rutgers and van der Meer, 2010). The traditional bureaucratic model is characterised by both equity and efficiency: equity as the result of law- and rule based behaviour; and efficiency as a result of specialisation and standardisation. Yet efficiency ‘has come to be associated with the private sector solutions embraced by the New Public Management’ (Andrews & Entwistle, 2013: 247). Van Wart and Berman (1999) see a move towards tougher standard of efficiency, and a wider value change of what is seen as productivity following the introduction of NPM- management tools. Especially following the introduction of the new thinking in public administration, efficiency has become an objective in its own right, rather than a secondary one supporting the achievement of other objectives, such as equity. Beck Jørgensen and Rutgers (2014), following an analysis of historic public sector job adverts, find that, while the importance attached to NPM values has increased substantially over time ‘New

5 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Public Management values do not crowd out other values, rather value intensity increases.’ (2014: 59).

The apparent contradiction between equity and efficiency has been one of the main bases for criticizing the NPM. It has been argued NPM comes at the cost of equity because of its focus on the bottom line, and that therefore safeguards are needed to protect values that are under attack. This has for instance been the case in utilities where public values such as universal service, affordability or continuity has to be legally protected the wake of privatisation or liberalisation (Van de Walle, 2008; De Bruijn & Dicke, 2006).

In Hood’s seminal 1991 paper on the NPM, efficiency (a ‘sigma’ value) and equity (a ‘theta’ value) represent different families of administrative values. NPM is characterised by sigma values, with little regard for equity. The latter, it can be argued (cf. Hood, 1991: 10), can very well be achieved through typical NPM-like programming and target setting. One could also argue the equity-efficiency tension is not inherent to NPM, but that efficiency is a precondition for equity to be possible – first increasing the size of the cake in order to allow for a more equitable of the cake. Indeed, in a recent study we found that NPM- style structural reform is not only positively associated with (perceptions) of improvements in cost and efficiency, but also in equal access to services (Hammerschmid et al., mimeo).

The value trade-offs civil servants make

While public values are receiving increasing attention (Van der Wal et al., 2013), many studies have limited themselves to categorising values or studying the presence of values within organisations. Some scholars have for instance looked at value statements of government organisations (Kernaghan, 2003) or at codes of conduct (Beck Jørgensen and Sørensen, 2013) . There also is an extensive body of research on public administrators’ values and the value conflicts they experience (De Graaf, Huberts, and Smulder, 2014). Yet, not many studies have looked at value preferences beyond those that look at (party-)political preferences of civil servants. Exceptions are mainly to be found in health where the tension between competing objectives such as cost-effectiveness and equity are particularly tangible (Ratcliffe et al., 2009).

Some studies have looked at the position of efficiency as a value for civil servants. Andersen et al., 2012 for instance find a correlation between civil servants’ support for efficient supply with their commitment to the public interest. Efficient delivery is then seen as a way of serving the public interest. In his study on cutbacks Schmidt (2016) found that top civil servants saw frugality as a crucial value in their task as managers, precisely because they are

6 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off dealing with public money. Yet, in a study among state and local administrators, DeForest Molina and McKeown (2012) found that efficiency ranked rather low in importance among a set of values. In a similar vein, Vrangbæk (2009) studied value orientations of public managers in Denmark. He found that while managers listed efficiency as a value, they do not put it very high on their list of important values in their work. He also found that efficiency was seen as less important by managers working in more operational organisations, and more so by those working in more traditional bureaucratic and administrative organisations. The former instead emphasised satisfying user needs. De Graaf and Paanakkker (2015) report on interviews with aldermen and senior administrators to look at conflict between performance and procedural values. They found that respondents mainly found conflict between lawfulness and transparency on the one hand and efficiency and effectiveness on the other. Equality did not feature prominently.

Explaining value preferences

Molina sees public administration values ‘as a contextualized set of attitudes’ (Molina, 2015:49). This means it is important to take the social and administrative context of the administrator into account when explaining the value trade-offs they make. We have earlier referred to the New Public Administration’s attention for social equity as a result of poverty and discrimination in society, and to NPM’s focus on efficiency as the result of inefficiencies and savings and the rise of new public economics. In this paper, we assume that context determines the value trade-offs officials make: their work, their prior experience, their task, the administrative system they work in, the society they are part of. Four hypotheses emanate from this assumption.

H1: Distance hypothesis: Closer distance to recipients of policies and services is related to a higher pro-equity orientation

We assume that proximity to the recipients of policies and services makes a public official more equity-oriented, because proximity means he or she can observe the direct consequences of the choices made on individual people. The context of working at a large distance from the actual recipients may make officials more concerned with the internal organisational objectives, rather than with external recipients. Certain types of public officials are closer to recipients. First, it is assumed that top managers are further removed from the operational reality as compared to heads of unit or normal employees. Second, we also assume that if a public official is working for a smaller organisation, he or she will be closer to the actual recipients. Thirdly, we also assume that officials working for agencies will have a higher pro-

7 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off equity orientation, because they are closer to users. This is in line with earlier findings by Vrangbæk (2009) who found that (Danish) managers working in operational organisations tended to find satisfying user needs more important than efficiency. Efficiency was mainly seen as important in more administrative parts of government. Beck Jørgensen (2006) finds that Danish agency-level respondents attach considerable lower importance to efficiency than do respondents in departments, and higher importance for equal opportunities and user needs. Both findings go against the expectations of agencies as carriers of NPM values, such as efficiency. Van Thiel and Van der Wal (2010) find that Dutch agencies value NPM-related values, such as profitability higher than ministries. Andersen et al. (2012) on the other hand, do not find a significant difference between the score on efficient supply as a value for respondents working in authorities (ministries and equivalent organisations) and agencies in the Danish public sector. Neither is there a difference between service provision vs regulatory/administration oriented-organisations

H2: Public sector hypothesis: the more a public official is influenced by neoliberal/npm reform ideas, the more pro-efficiency oriented they will be

The second hypothesis is that the habitus of a public official shapes his or her value preferences, and that public officials’ values have been impacted by the NPM (Maesschalck, 2004). More specifically, we assume that exposure to a private sector environment instils officials with a stronger preferences for efficiency. Frederickson (2005) described the crucial difference between the public and private sector as a different trade-off between efficiency and fairness. Whereas for the former, fairness is the main value, efficiency is the leading value for the private sector. Public-private differences have attracted a fair deal of attention in the public values literature, especially following an influx of mangers in the public sector with private sector experiences – so called sector switchers (De Graaf et al., 2008; Boardman et al., 2010). Still, there is discussion whether differences in values are actually that important between the sectors (see Van der Wal, 2008). Van der Wal et al. (2008) show that there are indeed differences in the values public and private managers find important, yet their empirical work shows that both groups attach equal importance to efficiency as a value driving their work (2008: 475). Exposure to the private sector can happen in different ways: prior work experience in the private sector, or having enjoyed a business-oriented education. Long tenure in the public sector is then an indicator of having been exposed to the public sector habitus.

8 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

H3. Country administrative culture hypothesis: Public officials in Scandinavian countries are more pro-equity oriented, Eastern European countries are more pro-efficiency oriented

A third hypothesis looks into the assumption that it is not just an official’s organisation or private background that shapes his or her value preferences, but rather the broader administrative culture within which they work. Some administrative cultures have for instance a more legalistic outlook, which could mean efficiency features less prominently. There have been many attempts at defining clusters of administrative cultures, yet these tend not to be conclusive on some countries in our dataset, and especially in relation to central European countries, they tend to lump all countries together in a single category. Or they put Ireland in the same category as the UK. Also, since our dataset only covers 14 countries, some administrative culture categories were represented by just one single country. For this reason, we decided to only use a simple categorisation of administrative culture, with the Scandinavian countries belonging to the equity group, and the Eastern European countries to the efficiency group because of their strong support for market values (REF).

H4. Popular preferences hypothesis: Public officials in countries where population is more left-wing are more pro-equity oriented

A final hypothesis assumes that public officials are responsive to their environment and make choices that reflect the make-up of the population they are serving. This means that they will be more equity-oriented in countries where the population if more politically left wing, and more efficiency oriented where it is more right wing.

Data

The analysis uses the COCOPS Top Public Executive Survey, a population survey of top public sector executives in European countries. Data for the UK were not used due to a low overall response rate and high item non-response for the dependent variable. We decided to also leave out the Serbian data. All other countries were kept, but a robustness test was performed by deleting one country and repeating the estimations. After deleting cases with high item non –response on crucial values, the final dataset consist of 4238 respondents in 14 countries

9 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Table 1. Composition of the final sample, by country % of the total Response rate Final sample sample (valid) Austria 438 10.30% 31.13% Denmark 130 3.10% 17.15% Estonia 279 6.60% 30.56% France 499 11.80% 14.66% Germany 413 9.70% 21.08% Hungary 214 5.00% 23.16% Ireland 320 7.60% 32.66% Italy 146 3.40% 15.04% Lithuania 357 8.40% 32.51% Netherlands 180 4.20% 26.86% Norway 308 7.30% 25.73% Portugal 244 5.80% 23.51% Spain 254 6.00% 15.09% Sweden 456 10.80% 35.27% TOTAL 4,238 100% 23.17%

Variables

The dependent variable is public officials’ position on an equity-efficiency scale. “Public services often need to balance different priorities. Where would you place your own position? (from 1, “equity”, to 7 “efficiency”). Descriptive findings are presented in table 3. They show that on average, officials tend towards equity.

Table 2. Dependent variable, average values by individual characteristics, post-related characteristics and country

Average s.d. Equity-efficiency position 3.55 1.62 Sex Male 3.59 1.61 Female 3.48 1.62 Age <46 3.69 1.63 46-55 3.52 1.61 >55 3.48 1.6 Education MA 3.56 1.62 PhD 3.41 1.59 Field of education Law 3.51 1.62 Business / Economics 3.76 1.6

10 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Other social sc. / humanities 3.49 1.61 Seniority in the public sect. < 5 years 3.88 1.68 5-10 years 3.69 1.68 10-20 years 3.62 1.6 > 20 years 3.45 1.59 Experience in the private sector 1 year or more 3.57 1.61 Position Level1 3.68 1.6 Level2 3.58 1.6 Level3 3.47 1.64 Type of organization Government 3.64 1.66 Agency 3.47 1.56 Area General gov. & Foreign affairs 3.67 1.61 Finance & Economic affairs 3.72 1.64 Infrastr., Transport & 3.55 1.57 Environm. Defence, justice & pub. Order 3.61 1.68 Employment 3.67 1.49 Health & Soc. Protection 3.38 1.57 Education & recreation 3.29 1.59 Size < 50 3.49 1.7 50-500 3.5 1.59 > 500 3.63 1.63 Country Austria 3.15 1.71 Denmark 3.44 1.28 Estonia 4.22 1.56 France 3.54 1.87 Germany 3.32 1.48 Hungary 4.43 1.31 Ireland 3.86 1.56 Italy 3.91 1.55 Lithuania 2.98 1.6 Norway 4.18 1.38 Netherlands 3.4 1.33 Portugal 3.89 1.51 Spain 3.79 1.68 Sweden 3.06 1.41

11 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Independent variables:

I. Individual-related  Gender. Females vs males  Age. <46, 46-55, >55 (reference)  Educational qualification MA vs rest; PhD vs rest  Subject of education: law, economics/business and social sciences, vs the rest  Seniority in the public sector. <5, 5-10, 10-20, >20 (reference).  Experience in the private sector. >1year vs rest. II. Service/post-related  Kind of position 2nd level and 3rd level, vs 1st level (reference)  Type of organization: agency, vs government  Policy area: general government and foreign affairs; finance and economic affairs; infrastructure and environment; defense and justice; employment; health and social protection (separated from employment); education and recreation; other  Size of the organization: <50, 50-500, >500 (reference) III. Country-related  Typification/classification of countries according to administrative cultures (Hammerschmid et al). Scandinavian, Transition (Eastern) and Southern, vs Continental and Anglo-Saxon (Ireland) as reference category  Average political placement (from 0, left to 10, right), ESS

Controls variables

Studies on administrative culture assume the existence of a dominant administrative culture within a country that sets its administration and civil servants apart from those in other countries. Our approach does not negate this possibility, but also recognises the existence of firewalls (Thacher and Rein, 2004) within an administrative system. This means that different parts of the system are (made) responsible for the realisation of different value sets. One could for instance assume different value trade-offs in redistributive vs. distributive parts of the public sector. For this reason, we add policy sector control.

The advent of the NPM meant that results replaced due process as the main purpose of public organisations (Tait, 1997). We thus assume that older public officials with long tenure had their formative years before the advent of NPM, and will be less likely to put result ahead of due process. The model controls for this through age and length of tenure.

We use OLS regression with standard errors clustered at the country level (for correcting country heterogeneity –clusters-). Four different models are tested. The first includes

12 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

individual factors only. The second adds variables related to the respondents position and organisation. Model three adds country dummies, and model four adds the country’s group membership and political placement. Missing values are eliminated when estimating, meaning that the number depends on the model. Robustness checks, for testing country representativity are pending in this version

Findings

Table 3. Estimates on the effects of individual characteristics, post-related characteristics and country factors on public official’s equity/efficiency views

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Constant 3.522 (0.117)*** 3.953 (0.170)*** 3.800 (0.086)*** -3.568 (1.040)*** INDIVIDUAL CHARACT. Sex Male Female -0.134 (0.094) -0.055 (0.086) -0.022 (0.084) -0.054 (0.081) Age <46 0.048 (0.139) 0.031 (0.137) -0.093 (0.112) -0.042 (0.112) 46-55 -0.009 (0.092) -0.009 (0.087) -0.007 (0.074) -0.004 (0.073) >55 Education MA -0.096 (0.095) -0.120 (0.080) -0.015 (0.050) -0.029 (0.041) PhD -0.213 (0.070)** -0.185 (0.060)*** 0.092 (0.059) 0.147 (0.043)*** Field of education Law 0.043 (0.119) -0.073 (0.106) -0.080 (0.075) -0.035 (0.076) Business / Economics 0.256 (0.074)*** 0.188 (0.068)** 0.152 (0.062)** 0.142 (0.058)** Other social sc. / humanit. -0.001 (0.083) -0.017 (0.070) -0.040 (0.056) -0.032 (0.053) Seniority in the public sect. < 5 years 0.382 (0.090)*** 0.407 (0.093)*** 0.234 (0.087)** 0.140 (0.103) 5-10 years 0.233 (0.120)* 0.299 (0.115)** 0.194 (0.106)* 0.178 (0.105) 10-20 years 0.148 (0.113) 0.181 (0.110) 0.145 (0.085) 0.119 (0.088) > 20 years Exper. in the private sector 1 year or more -0.012 (0.080) 0.018 (0.077) 0.046 (0.061) 0.070 (0.067) POST/ORGANIZATION CHAR. Position Level1 Level2 -0.176 (0.125) -0.185 (0.083)** -0.203 (0.078)** Level3 -0.343 (0.132)** -0.263 (0.081)*** -0.294 (0.066)***

13 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Type of organization Government Agency -0.241 (0.125)* -0.098 (0.076) -0.159 (0.077)* Area General gov. & Foreign aff. 0.074 (0.090) 0.069 (0.055) 0.076 (0.055) Finance & Economic affairs 0.050 (0.074) 0.012 (0.073) -0.006 (0.079) Infr., Transp. & Environm. -0.007 (0.059) -0.018 (0.053) 0.022 (0.057) Defence, justice & pub. ord. 0.053 (0.089) 0.026 (0.076) 0.011 (0.073) Employment 0.183 (0.096)* 0.230 (0.087)** 0.285 (0.093)*** Health & Soc. Protection -0.195 (0.049)*** -0.188 (0.042)*** -0.209 (0.043)*** Education & recreation -0.247 (0.079)*** -0.200 (0.065)*** -0.201 (0.060)*** Size < 50 -0.106 (0.127) 0.020 (0.098) -0.067 (0.101) 50-500 -0.160 (0.067)** -0.121 (0.045)** -0.169 (0.045)*** > 500 COUNTRY FACTORS Country Austria -0.380 (0.034)*** Denmark -0.146 (0.067)* Estonia 0.644 (0.059)*** France Germany -0.366 (0.054)*** Hungary 0.797 (0.042)***

Ireland 0.283 (0.040)*** Italy 0.295 (0.034)*** Lithuania -0.552 (0.064)*** Netherlands 0.557 (0.038)*** Norway -0.072 (0.047) Portugal 0.259 (0.083)*** Spain 0.236 (0.026)*** Sweden -0.516 (0.073)*** Country model Scandinavian -1.009 (0.124)*** Continental Eur. Southern Eur. 0.628 (0.155)*** Transition -0.184 (0.178) Political placement Political plac. Left (0)-Right (10) 1.498 (0.213)*** N 4,083 3,926 3,926 3,926

14 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Standard errors in parenthesis. Statistical significance at 1% (***), 5% (**), 10% (*)

- Model 1. Individual characteristics (only)

 Females, no effect  Age, no effect  Education, PhD more pro-equity  Field of education: o Economics/business, more pro-efficiency o Rest, no effect  Seniority: less seniority, more pro-efficiency  Experience in the private sector, no effect

- Model 2. Individual characteristics + post/organizational characteristics

 Individual characteristics: no changes with respect to model 1, same effects are significant (and quite similar size of these effects)  Level: lower level (level 3), more pro-equity  Agencies, more pro-equity (than ministries)  Area: o Most of them, non-significant effects o Employment, more pro-efficiency o Health&social protection and Education, more pro-equity  Size: medium size organizations (50-500 employees), more pro-equity (but not the smallest)

- Model 3. Individual characteristics + post/organizational characteristics + country dummies

Model 4. Individual characteristics + post/organizational characteristics + country models + political placement

 Individual and post/organizational characteristics, with respect to model 1 and 2 o Education PhD, non-significant. This effect disappears when controlling for country effects. Thus this effect were associated to country specifics, and is not a not cross-country effect . In model 4, a positive effect appears (?)

15 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

o Agency, non-significant. This effect disappears when controlling for country effects. Thus this effect were associated to country specifics, and is not a cross-country effect . In model 4, the effect appears again. So there is something in the country level not considered in model 4 explaining this effect o Field of education economics/business, lower levels (hierarchical position), area (employment vs rest and health and social protection vs rest and education vs rest), and medium size: still significant, and similar magnitude than before. These effects are cross-country (I mean, general effects in spite of the country). . Similar effects in model 4 o Seniority in the public sector (lower seniority vs rest). Still significant, but lower magnitude of the effect. The effect is partly country specific and partly general. . In model 4, not significant enough o The variables that were non significant in models 1 and 2 are non significant in model 3 (only level 2 becomes significant due to lower standard error) . Same in model 4

Model 3  Countries (with respect to France, reference) o Hungary, Estonia, Netherlands, Italy, Ireland, Portugal, Spain (in this order), more pro-efficiency o Lithuania, Sweden, Austria, Germany, Denmark (in this order), more pro- equity o Norway, non significant difference

- Model 4. Individual characteristics + post/organizational characteristics + country model + country political placement + country controls

Objective: to try to operationalize the previously detected country differences

 Countries (with respect to Continental European+Ireland, reference): o Country model: Scandinavian, more pro-equity; Southern European, more pro-efficiency; Transition, non-significant o Political placement: countries more oriented to right, (much) more pro- efficiency. Explains very well differences intra-groups of countries (models)

16 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Discussion and conclusion

- H1: Distance hypothesis: Closer distance to recipients of policies and services is related to a higher pro-equity orientation

 Hierarchical level: yes  Agency: yes, but disappears when introducing country dummies (so this is not a general effect but a country specific effect)  Size of organization: not for the smallest, yes for those intermediate vs the largest 

- H2: Public sector hypothesis: the more a public official is influenced by neoliberal/npm reform ideas, the more pro-efficiency oriented they will be

 Seniority: yes. Partly a general effect, but basically a country specific effect  Business/economic education: yes  Private sector experience: no  Sector: yes, i.e. health & social protection and education vs the rest

- H3: Country administrative culture hypothesis: Public officials in Scandinavian countries are more pro-equity oriented, Eastern European countries are more pro-efficiency oriented

 Scandinavian countries, yes, more pro-equity  Transition, no, non-significant  Also, Southern more pro-efficiency

- H4: Popular preferences hypothesis: Public officials in countries where population is more left-wing are more pro-equity oriented yes, more left-wing population, more pro-equity civil servants; more right-wing, more pro- efficiency

Limitations

-coverage of Eastern Europe

17 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

- abstract approach to the trade-off – no context. The trade-off made could be different in specific sectors, or when related to specific dilemma;

- single item measurement of dependent variable

- we cannot really interpret the agency effect: is this an agency effect, or is it the result of task-specificity?

- we only look at the trade-off – this is just their statement, but do not study how they cope with this trade-off or value conflict (Van der Wal et al., 2011)

References

Andersen, L. B., Jørgensen, T. B., Kjeldsen, A. M., Pedersen, L. H., & Vrangbæk, K. (2012). Public value dimensions: Developing and testing a multi-dimensional classification. International Journal of Public Administration, 35(11), 715-728.

Andrews, R. (2011). NPM and the Search for Efficiency. In Christensen, T./Laegreid, P.(Hg.): The Ashgate Research Companion to New Public Management, Farnham, 281-294.

Andrews, R., & Entwistle, T. (2010). Does cross-sectoral partnership deliver? An empirical exploration of public service effectiveness, efficiency, and equity. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 20, 679-701.

Andrews, R. & Entwistle, T. (2013) Four Faces of Public Service Efficiency, Public Management Review, 15:2, 246-264

Barry, B. (1965). Political Argument. University of California Press.

Beck Jørgensen, T., & Rutgers, M.R. (2014). Tracing public values change: A historical study of civil service job advertisements. Contemporary Readings in Law and Social Justice, 6(2), 2014, pp. 59-80,

Beck Jørgensen, T. (2006). Public values, their nature, stability and change. The case of Denmark. Public Administration Quarterly, 365-398.

Beck Jørgensen, T., & Sørensen, D. (2013). Codes of good governance: National or global values? Public Integrity, 15(1), 71-96.

Boardman, C., Bozeman, B., & Ponomariov, B. (2010). Private sector imprinting: An examination of the impacts of private sector job experience on public manager's work attitudes. Public Administration Review, 70(1), 50-59.

18 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Box, R.C. (2015). Public service values. Abingdon: Routledge

Bozeman, B. (2007). Public values and public interest: Counterbalancing economic individualism. Georgetown University Press.

Bruijn, H. D., & Dicke, W. (2006). Strategies for safeguarding public values in liberalized utility sectors. Public administration, 84(3), 717-735.

Rutgers, M. R. and van der Meer, H. (2010) The Origins and Restriction of Efficiency in Public Administration: Regaining Efficiency as the Core Value of Public Administration. Administration & Society, 42:7 pp755–9.

De Graaf, G., & Paanakker, H. (2014). Good Governance Performance Values and Procedural Values in Conflict. The American Review of Public Administration, 0275074014529361.

De Graaf, G., & van Der Wal, Z. (2008). On value differences experienced by sector switchers. Administration & Society, 40(1), 79-103.

De Graaf, G., Huberts, L., & Smulders, R. (2014). Coping with public value conflicts. Administration & Society, 0095399714532273.

DeForest Molina, A. & McKeown, C.L. (2012). The Heart of the Profession: Understanding Public Service Values. Journal of Public Affairs Education, Vol. 18, No. 2 (SPRING 2012), pp. 375-396

Easton, D. (1965). A Framework for Political Analysis. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

Frederickson, H. G. (2005). Public ethics and the new managerialism: An axiomatic theory. In H. G. Frederickson & R. K. Ghere (Eds.), Ethics in public management (pp. 165- 183). London: M.E. Sharpe.

Greener, I. (2013). Public management. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan

Hammerschmid, G., Meyer, R. E., & Demmke, C. (2007). Public Administration Modernization: Common Reform Trends or Different Paths and National Understandings in the EU Countries. Cultural Aspects of Public Management Reform (Research in Public Policy Analysis and Management, Volume 16) Emerald Group Publishing Limited, 16, 145-169.

Hammerschmid, G., Van de Walle, S., Andrews, R. & Bezes, P. (eds)(2016). Public administration reforms in Europe. The view from the top. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

Hood, C. (1991). A public management for all seasons?. Public administration, 69(1), 3-19.

19 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Kernaghan, K. (2003). Integrating values into public service: The values statement as centerpiece. Public administration review, 63(6), 711-719.

Le Grand, J. (1990). Equity versus efficiency: the elusive trade-off. Ethics, 100(3), 554-568.

Maesschalck, J. (2004). The impact of new public management reforms on public servants’ ethics: Towards a theory. Public Administration, 82(2), 465-489.

Molina, A.D. (2015). The Virtues of Administration: Values and the Practice of Public Service. Administrative Theory & Praxis, 37: 49-69

Okun, A. M. (2015). Equality and efficiency: The big tradeoff. Brookings Institution Press.

Osberg, L. (1995). The equity/efficiency trade-off in retrospect. Canadian Business Economics, 3(3), 5-19.

Ratcliffe, J., Bekker, H. L., Dolan, P., & Edlin, R. (2009). Examining the attitudes and preferences of health care decision-makers in relation to access, equity and cost- effectiveness: a discrete choice experiment. Health Policy, 90(1), 45-57.

Tait, J. (1997). A strong foundation: report of the task force on public service values and ethics (the summary). Canadian Public Administration, 40(1), 1-22.

Thacher, D., & Rein, R. (2004). Managing value conflict in public policy. Governance, 17, 457-486.

Van de Walle, S. (2008). ‘What services are public? What aspects of performance are to be ranked? The case of “services of general interest”’. International Public Management Journal, 11(3): 256-274

Van der Wal, Z. & Huberts, L. (2008). Value solidity in government and business: Results of an empirical study on public and private sector values. American Review of Public Administration, 38, 264–285.

Van der Wal, Z., De Graaf, G., & Lasthuizen, K. (2008). What’s valued most? Similarities and differences between the organizational values of the public and private sector. Public administration, 86(2), 465-482.

Van der Wal, Z., Nabatchi, T., & De Graaf, G. (2013). From galaxies to universe: A cross- disciplinary review and analysis of public values publications from 1969 to 2012. The American Review of Public Administration, 0275074013488822.

Van der Wal, Z, de Graaf, G. & Lawton, A. (2011) Competing Values in Public Management: Introduction to the Symposium Issue, Public Management Review, 13:3, 331-341

Van Wart, M. (1998). Changing public sector values. New York: Garland

20 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Van Wart, M., & Berman, E. (1999). Contemporary public sector productivity values: Narrower scope, tougher standards and new rules of the game. Public Productivity and Management Review, 22, 326-347.

Vrangbaek, K. (2009). Public sector values in Denmark: A survey analysis. Intl Journal of Public Administration, 32(6), 508-535.

21 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Annex

Composition of the sample, by individual characteristics and post-related characteristics

Dimension Variable % N

INDIVIDUAL CHARACTERISTICS

Sex 4,148

Male 63.5% 2,634

Female 36.5% 1,514

Age 4,224

<46 28.7% 1,213

46-55 40.6% 1,714

>55 30.7% 1,297

Education 4,238

MA 60.1% 2,547

PhD 17.4% 738

Field of education 4,238

Law 25.9% 1,099

Business / Economics 25.4% 1,075

Other social sc. / humanities 29.6% 1,255

Seniority in the public sect. 4,177

< 5 years 7.2% 302

5-10 years 9.6% 399

10-20 years 30.2% 1,262

> 20 years 53.0% 2,214

Experience in the private sector 4,238

1 year or more 46.3% 1,964

POST/ORGANIZATION CHARACTERISTICS

Position 4,112

Level1 22.4% 921

22 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Level2 42.9% 1,765

Level3 34.7% 1,426

Type of organization 4,238

Government 50.5% 2,139

Agency 49.5% 2,099

Area 4,238

General gov. & Foreign affairs 19.8% 840

Finance & Economic affairs 18.6% 788

Infrastr., Transport & Environm. 15.9% 675

Defence, justice & pub. Order 14.9% 630

Employment 11.3% 477

Health & Soc. Protection 18.4% 781

Education & recreation 13.6% 576

Size 4,195

< 50 9.4% 394

50-500 45.7% 1,918

> 500 44.9% 1,883

23 Public officials’ equity-efficiency trade-off

Statistical annex. Independent variables at the country level

Country model Political (Hammerschmid et al., placement(0 –left - Country 2007) to 10 –right-)

Austria Continental European 4,74

Denmark Scandinavian 5,33

Estonia Transition 5,46

France Continental European 4,95

Germany Continental European 4,61

Hungary Transition 5,40

Ireland Anglo-Saxon 5,13

Italy Southern European 4,76

Lithuania Transition 4,93

Netherlands Continental European 5,41

Norway Scandinavian 5,64

Portugal Southern European 4,90

Spain Southern European 4,51

Sweden Scandinavian 5,33

24