Population Aging and Economic Growth in China

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Population Aging and Economic Growth in China CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by Research Papers in Economics PROGRAM ON THE GLOBAL DEMOGRAPHY OF AGING Working Paper Series Population Aging and Economic Growth in China Judith Banister, David E. Bloom, and Larry Rosenberg March 2010 PGDA Working Paper No. 53 http://www.hsph.harvard.edu/pgda/working.htm The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and not necessarily those of the Harvard Initiative for Global Health. The Program on the Global Demography of Aging receives funding from the National Institute on Aging, Grant No. 1 P30 AG024409-06. Population Aging and Economic Growth in China Judith Banister, David E. Bloom, and Larry Rosenberg March 2010 Executive Summary According to current UN projections, the population of the world age 60 or older will be 2 billion by 2050. With populations aging in nearly all countries, there has been widespread concern about the possible effects on economic growth and on the ability of countries to provide support for their elderly populations. In particular, because the elderly are in general less economically productive than younger people, a preponderance of old-age individuals would seem to suggest that (a) economic growth will be slower than in the past, and (b) relatively smaller working-age cohorts of the future will be burdened by the need to care for, and pay for the support of, the elderly population. These concerns have found resonance in China, where more than 30% of the population is expected to be age 60 or older in 2050. In part as a consequence of China’s process of population aging to date, the ratio of individuals age 15-64 to those younger and older, which grew rapidly during the last few economic boom decades, has reached its peak and is slated to decline rapidly in coming decades. Because a labor force that is large in size relative to the dependent population is plausibly crucial to rapid economic growth, the decline of this ratio could conceivably herald economic difficulties. The roots of population aging in China are the same as elsewhere: a low fertility rate, rising life expectancy, and the cumulative effect of past changes in birth and death rates. In China, obviously, the decline in the fertility rate, brought about in significant measure by the one-child policy and government efforts leading up to its adoption, has been a central factor in the changing age structure of the Chinese population. Greater longevity has also obviously been a key factor in population aging. If an older population is in fact cause for concern about the future of the Chinese economy, it would be prudent to identify, as soon as possible, measures that could serve to counteract any negative economic effects of population aging. Numerous countries have identified policies that might mitigate the potential economic problems associated with population aging. These policies seek to raise the age of retirement, spur higher savings, facilitate work for those caring for children, increase the labor force participation of women, liberalize immigration, and give more incentives for education. China could indeed begin to change the legal age of retirement, for those to whom this applies. It is unlikely to seek a higher savings rate, since its savings are already very high, and there is reason to think that increasing domestic consumption, rather than savings, will be a necessary policy measure in the coming years. However, China could attempt to redirect some of the household, societal, and private sector savings toward secure instruments to fund future retirements. Although education receives strong emphasis in Chinese families, and educational attainment, particularly in the cities, has risen rapidly, there are still large swaths of the population where even secondary education is not guaranteed and technical training is unusual. Improving the education and skill levels of Chinese workers could make the economy more productive and more able to compensate for the impending decline in the share of working-age people. In the short run, increasing the skills that the labor force brings to the production of goods and services is a central means for further raising productivity, which is the key factor underlying rising incomes. Strengthening education is the primary means of improving such skills. In the long run, the most promising avenue for China to avoid the possible consequences of population aging is to mobilize the portion of its potential workforce that is dormant or poorly utilized. Consideration of the possibility of adding to China's workforce when many millions are already unemployed or underemployed may be counterintuitive, but it is this very reserve labor force that can lay to rest concerns that China will not have enough workers in the future to preserve the country's impressive growth in GDP and in GDP per capita. In the cities, a higher proportion of women were employed in the past than now, and many women would like to work who cannot presently find jobs. Many people in cities are looking for work and will be available to fill most potential labor shortages as soon as they loom. In addition, the hundreds of millions of agricultural workers are not nearly as productive as those working in industry and services. China has benefited enormously by a large shift of workers out of agriculture, but there is scope for increasing this shift if the mechanization of agriculture is increased or if controls on internal migration are reduced. In an economy full of increasingly well-off consumers and that benefits from extraordinary demand for its exports, the forces of supply and demand will tend to raise wages in sectors where labor is in greater demand. Such increases will tend to draw more people into the workforce. In addition, the mix of goods and services that are produced will be affected by supply and demand. If hundreds of millions of elderly need something, the economy will produce it, unless it is restrained from doing so. Since the evolution of needs will not be sudden, there is every reason to believe that needs will be satisfied. The specter of shortages, whether of labor, goods, or services, has little basis. As the population ages, it will of course be necessary to devote more resources to the care and health of the elderly. And as China proceeds in its epidemiological transition toward an even greater preponderance of noncommunicable diseases, it will benefit by adopting programs that aim to diminish behaviors that lead to debilitating chronic conditions. Pension coverage is another arena in which governmental action may benefit the elderly. Rural areas are particularly bereft of this key element of social protection. China will face numerous choices in how to construct a financially viable pension system, and it will benefit from studying the experiences of other countries. At present, and for the foreseeable future, China, like many ii of its neighbors, benefits from a very strong system of family responsibility through which the elderly can count on extensive support. Population policies are also important. An easing of the one-child policy would allow for a gradual increase in the relative size of the working-age population, as compared with the elderly population. In addition, such easing might be effective in helping to reverse the extremely highly skewed ratio of males to females in the Chinese population – a circumstance that is based on selective prenatal abortions and the neglect or worse of girl babies, and that prevents millions of men from marrying and leaves them without the support of spouse or grown children or grandchildren in their old age. Current government efforts to spur economic development in the non-coastal provinces may also be important in avoiding any economic problems stemming from population aging. If the working population of the interior provinces is mobilized to be more productive, the Chinese economy as a whole will benefit, and regional economies will be better situated to provide care to the elderly. China's economic growth rate is expected to gradually slow down in the future, in comparison to the breakneck pace of economic development from 1978 to today. But population aging will not be the only, or even the major, cause. One of the most important reasons for this expectation is that nearly all countries, as they develop, experience a significant slowing in economic growth; other things equal, rapid growth is typically fastest at lower levels of income. China has made considerable gains, and its economic growth is likely to moderate as the country moves toward a higher level of income. The bottom line is that population aging is unlikely to cause significant economic problems for China. Its highly productive economy is awash with skilled workers and with those seeking to join the labor force. There is little prospect of a lack of workers leading to a marked slowing of growth in GDP or GDP per capita. To the extent that older workers are retiring, there are more than enough working-age people to fill their shoes and to support the daily needs of China's elderly population. Nevertheless, policy reforms – in education, health, pensions, labor policy, and internal migration – could make China's economic future all the more secure. iii Population Aging and Economic Growth in China Judith Banister, David E. Bloom, and Larry Rosenberg March 2010 Introduction Population aging is taking place in most countries of the world. During the next few decades, the share of global population ages 60 and older is likely to rise to historically unprecedented levels (see Figure 1).1 The 680 million people in this age group make up 11 percent of world population, up from 8 percent in 1950.
Recommended publications
  • Study and Comparison of Elderly Care System in Germany and China
    Study and Comparison of Elderly Care System in Germany and China Jingyan Li University of Bremen STUDY AND COMPARISON OF ELDERLY CARE SYSTEMIN GERMANYAND CHINA by Jingyan Li in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Public Health at University of Bremen. Supervisor: Prof. Dr. Stefan Görres Co-Supervisor: Prof. Dr. Henning Schmidt-Semisch Date of doctoral colloquium: 28.08.2019 ACKNOWLEDGMENT First of all, I am grateful to my supervisor, Prof. Dr. Stefan Görres, who has always trusted and supported me during the composition of this thesis. I would like to give my sincere gratitude for his patience, motivation, and immense knowledge. I have been extremely lucky and could not have imagined having a better advisor and mentor for my Ph.D study. My special thanks also direct to the co-supervisor of my thesis: Prof. Dr. Henning Schmidt-Semisch. Without his visionary guidance and steering, valuable comments and discussions, generous support and inspiration, this thesis would not be accomplished. I would like to give my gratitude to my colleague Christiane Degering-Machirus in IPP for her considerate assistance and help. Besides, my sincere thanks also goes to the col- leagues Nils Harenberg, Christin Ellermann, Rosa Mazzola and Fadua El Bouazzaoui for their insightful comments and encouragement. IPP is such a great institute where my sci- entific thinking and attitudes were fostered. Last but not least, I would like thank my family, my husband Lei for his continued sup- port and encouragement, my father Liang, my mother Shulan and my lovely daughters Leonie and Fenja.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impacts of the Universal Two-Child Policy on China's Population
    China Pop. & Dev. Studies (2017) 1 (1 ): 1 - 18 1 The Impacts of the Universal Two-Child Policy on China's Population Zhenwu ZHAI1 , Long LI2 and Jiaju CHEN2 Abstract: The universal two-child policy, implemented in October, 2015, is considered to be the most significant adjustment in the history of China' s family planning program. Using data from the 2014 national population sampling survey, this paper employs a population group-component calculation and projection method to compute the number of target population in 2016 and then to estimate the number of extra births that are likely to result from implementation of the universal two-child policy. The results show that the total number of extra births is estimated to be approximately 17. 2 million in the years 2017 - 2021, with the number of extra births per year ranging from approximately 1. 6 to 4. 7 million. This will lead to a dramatic shift in China's TFR from an estimated 1. 6 in 2016 to one approaching the replacement level, and then dropping to a projected 1. 7. With the universal two-child policy in place, China' s total population will grow to about 1. 45 billion around 2028 and then gradually begin shrioking. The labor force will become larger under the universal two-child policy than it would if the stricter birth control policy were maintained, with an estimated 50 million additional people aged 15 - 59 in 2050. With implementation of China's new fertility policy, an estimated 34% of the population will be over 60 years of age in 2050, almost three percentage points lower than the level if the former fertility policy were continued.
    [Show full text]
  • China's Long March to Retirement Reform
    China’s Long March to Retirement Reform The Graying of the Middle Kingdom Revisited by Richard Jackson Keisuke Nakashima & Neil Howe wit h contributions by Jiangong Zhou China’s Long March to Retirement Reform TABLE OF CONTENTS Foreword 1 Introduction 2 Chapter 1: The Dimensions of China’s Aging Challenge 7 China’s Demographic Transformation 8 China’s Looming Retirement Crisis 10 The Broader Economic Outlook 15 Chapter 2: The Evolution of China’s Retirement System 19 From Iron Rice Bowl to Empty Accounts 19 Liaoning and Beyond 22 The Unfinished Agenda 25 Chapter 3: A New Direction for Retirement Reform 27 Building the Floor of Protection 27 Increasing Funded Retirement Savings 28 Designing a National Personal Accounts System 30 The Advantages of Funding 35 Reform and China’s Capital Markets 37 Conclusion: China at a Crossroads 42 A Note on Data and Sources 44 A Key to Chart Source Citations 46 Acknowledgments 47 About the Authors 48 About CSIS and The Prudential Foundation 49 Foreword The year 2008 began in China amid celebratory preparation for the Beijing Olympics. The world watched in awe as the Chinese coordinated and choreographed a breathtaking spectacle that captured the hopes and aspirations of this remarkable country. As it turns out, China could not celebrate its achievement for long. Before year’s end, China found itself in an economic crisis precipitated by the global recession. No one who knows China doubts that it will successfully weather today’s global economic storm. Yet having said that, there is indeed cause for concern about China’s economic future.
    [Show full text]
  • The One-Child Policy and Reproductive Justice: Son Preference, Sex Selection, Violence and Demography
    1 The One-Child Policy and Reproductive Justice: Son Preference, Sex Selection, Violence and Demography Isabel Pastoor St. Catherine University [email protected] Faculty sponsor: Dr. Kristine Lamm West 2 Introduction The year 1980 began with an open letter from the Communist Party of China announcing a new planned fertility policy, commonly known as the One-Child Policy (hereafter the OCP). An extreme culmination of coercive family planning policies of the 1970s, the Party, led by Deng Xiaoping, wrote that the OCP would address “problems in such areas as feeding the entire people, clothing them, housing them, providing adequate transportation, education, public health care, and employment.” (Nie, 2014) From 1980 to 2016, China embarked on a family planning campaign unprecedented in scale, brutality of enforcement, and demographic consequences. Government imposed restrictions on fertility inherently violate reproductive rights. In this paper, I examine the effects of the One-Child Policy on reproductive justice1, including how it exacerbated existing issues of son preference, sex selection, and violence against women and girls, and stripped women of their reproductive rights through forced abortion. I provide policy recommendations to address the demographic and economic consequences of the OCP, and to eliminate son preference, sex selection, and government control of women’s reproduction. Background The OCP was not China’s first attempt to reign in an overblown population. Mao Zedong’s overzealous pro-natality during the Great Leap Forward was dampened slightly in 1962, when the Chinese government announced its new position in favor of “birth planning” (Zhang, 2017). However, a few years later, family planning was labelled “rightist” under the Cultural Revolution (Zhang, 2017).
    [Show full text]
  • China's One Child Policy
    6/26/2019 China’s One Child Policy - Childhood Studies - Oxford Bibliographies China’s One Child Policy Martin K. Whyte LAST MODIFIED: 26 JUNE 2019 DOI: 10.1093/OBO/9780199791231-0221 Introduction For centuries, China has had the world’s largest population, although it will soon lose that title to India. When Mao Zedong and his colleagues seized national power in 1949, they were not sure how many Chinese there were (the first modern census was not conducted until 1953), and Mao initially argued that having a large and rapidly increasing population was a blessing for China, rather than a curse. However, the challenges of managing such a large and poor country soon changed the official view, and during some intervals in the 1950s and 1960s, China carried out voluntary family planning campaigns to try to reduce the birth rate. However, those campaigns were largely ineffective, with the only notable decline in fertility during those decades produced by the Great Leap Forward–induced mass famine of 1959–1961, not family planning efforts. As of 1970 the projected number of babies the average Chinese mother would have in her lifetime (termed the total fertility rate [TFR]) was still close to six. (China’s cities, where less than 20 percent of the population lived at the time, is an exception to these generalizations, with the 1960s family planning campaign playing some role in reducing the urban TFR in 1970 to 3.2.) Early in the 1970s, when Mao was still in charge (he died in 1976), China made a dramatic shift from voluntary family planning to mandatory birth limits under the slogan, “later (marriage ages), longer (birth intervals), and fewer” (births—no more than two babies for urban families and three for rural families).
    [Show full text]
  • Global Aging and the Future of Emerging Markets About CSIS
    Global Aging and the Future of Emerging Markets About CSIS In an era of ever-changing global opportunities and challenges, the Center for Stra- tegic and International Studies (CSIS) provides strategic insights and practical policy solutions to decision makers. Since its founding in 1962, CSIS has grown to become one of the world’s preeminent public policy institutions, with more than 220 full-time staff and a large network of affiliated scholars. A bipartisan, nonprofit organization headquartered in Washington, DC, CSIS maintains research programs on each of the world’s regions, as well as on the transnational challenges that know no boundary, from energy and climate policy to demographic change, global development, and economic integration. Former U.S. senator Sam Nunn became chairman of the CSIS Board of Trustees in 1999, and John J. Hamre has led CSIS as its president and chief executive officer since 2000. The CSIS Global Aging Initiative (GAI) explores the fiscal, economic, social, and geopolitical implications of population aging. GAI pursues an ambitious educational agenda, undertaking cutting-edge research projects, publish- ing high-profile reports, and organizing international conferences that bring together world leaders to discuss common problems and explore common solutions. About Everest Capital Founded in 1990, Everest Capital is an investment management firm dedicated to global, emerging and frontier markets investing. Its clients include some of the world’s leading corporate and public pension funds, university endowments, charitable foun- dations and high net worth families. Everest Capital invests using a multi-asset class approach, focusing on equity and debt securities as well as commodities and curren- cies in markets worldwide.
    [Show full text]
  • Sitetrends – War for Talent 2017
    SITETRENDS WAR FOR TALENT WHERE THE WORKFORCE & JOBS LIVE JULY 2017 3 INTRODUCTION 4 WAR FOR TALENT 5 DEFINING GENERATIONS 6 UNITED STATES DOMESTIC PERSPECTIVES 10 UNITED STATES PERSPECTIVES IN LEADING MARKETS 16 GLOBAL PERSPECTIVES 17 GLOBAL POPULATIONS 21 GLOBAL WORKFORCE 22 GLOBAL EMPLOYMENT 24 GLOBAL UNEMPLOYMENT 25 ABOUT H&A CONTENTS INTRODUCTION The “War for Talent” is a phrase commonly used to describe competition among businesses for quality and affordable labor. First used in the 1990s, the phrase became relevant as the United States shifted its economic focus from the Baby Boomer generation to Generation X, and as business leaders increasingly became aware of the link between talent attraction and competitiveness. Although this initial shift was characterized by the demographic change which accompanied the transition away from the larger Boomer population (who had long defined the consumer economy), the challenge associated with attracting the qualified and affordable labor necessary to sustain the consumer economy persists, even as the smaller Generation X now begins to give way to an even larger generation – the Millennials. Twenty years have passed since the phrase War for Talent was coined, and with the passage of time, perspective has provided additional insight. The workforce has changed; people aren’t retiring with the same firm where they began their careers—a trend that has certainly accelerated over the past decade. BUSINESS CHANGED Brick and mortar retail is in decline while online purchasing is giving rise to warehouse development. Fresh outlooks are needed to transition to a new normal. Certain international trends also parallel and influence the quest for talent.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impacts of Ending China's One-Child Policy
    The Impacts of Ending China’s One-Child Policy On October 29, 2015, China scrapped its one-child policy, allowing all couples to have two children for the first time since strict family planning rules were introduced more than three decades ago. Despite the optimistic responses of some demographers and citizens on Chinese state media[1], the shift to the new two-child policy may disappoint those who expect the policy to lead to balanced population development and mitigation of China’s rapidly aging population. China’s population increased by around 400 million from 1949 to 1976, influenced by the promotion of population growth during Chairman Mao Zedong’s era.[2] The Chinese government introduced its one-child policy in 1979, based on the conviction that strict population containment would prove essential to economic reforms aimed at improving standards of living.[3] Setting the goal of curtailing population growth to 1.2 billion by the year 2000, the National Population and Family Planning Commission was responsible for the implementation and regulation of population growth. The detailed implementation of the one-child policy varied at different times and places in China. Family-planning committees at provincial and county levels devised their own local one-child policy implementation plans. For urban residents and government employees, the one-child policy was strictly enforced with very few exceptions to allow more than one child per family. Exceptions included families in which the first child had a disability or both parents worked in high-risk occupations (such as mining) or were themselves from one-child families (in some areas).[4] In certain rural areas, a second child was actually allowed when the first child was a girl, reflecting cultural preference for male heirs.
    [Show full text]
  • The One-Child Policyâ•Žs Socio-Demographic Impact: Current
    University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Wharton Research Scholars Wharton Undergraduate Research 4-1-2004 The One-Child Policy’s Socio-Demographic Impact: Current Trends and Alternative Policy Projections Emily C. Chiu University of Pennsylvania Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.upenn.edu/wharton_research_scholars Part of the Business Commons, and the Public Affairs, Public Policy and Public Administration Commons Chiu, Emily C., "The One-Child Policy’s Socio-Demographic Impact: Current Trends and Alternative Policy Projections" (2004). Wharton Research Scholars. 4. https://repository.upenn.edu/wharton_research_scholars/4 This paper is posted at ScholarlyCommons. https://repository.upenn.edu/wharton_research_scholars/4 For more information, please contact [email protected]. The One-Child Policy’s Socio-Demographic Impact: Current Trends and Alternative Policy Projections Disciplines Business | Public Affairs, Public Policy and Public Administration This journal article is available at ScholarlyCommons: https://repository.upenn.edu/wharton_research_scholars/4 The One-Child Policy’s Socio-Demographic Impact: Current Trends and Alternative Policy Projections By – Emily C. Chiu Advisor – Professor Mark Pauly Wharton Undergraduate Research Scholars WH-299-301 April 2004 Table of Contents I. Introduction II. Prior Literature III. Overview: As-Is Forecasts for China’s Population (a) Declining Fertility Rates i. Table 1: Total Fertility Rates Under Different Policy Periods in China ii. Figure 1: Decline in China’s TFR, 1990–2050 (b) Huge Population Base: Population Yet to Peak i. Figure 2: China’s Total Midyear Population, 1950–2050 ii. Figure 3: Changing Life Expectancy and Total Fertility Rate in China IV. Problems Implied by Status Quo Forecasts (a) Rapidly Aging Population, Shrinking Youth Cohorts i.
    [Show full text]