On the Relationship Between the VCG Mechanism and Market Clearing

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

On the Relationship Between the VCG Mechanism and Market Clearing On the Relationship between the VCG Mechanism and Market Clearing Takashi Tanaka1 Na Li2 Kenko Uchida3 Abstract— We consider a social cost minimization problem well. First, it may not be easy to guarantee the existence with equality and inequality constraints in which a central co- of supply function equilibria in realistic electricity markets. ordinator allocates infinitely divisible goods to self-interested N As demonstrated by [13], a pure Nash equilibrium may fail firms under information asymmetry. We consider the Vickrey- Clarke-Groves (VCG) mechanism and study its connection to an to exist even in a relatively simple supply function bidding alternative mechanism based on market clearing-price. Under model. Second, even if the supply function equilibria are the considered set up, we show that the VCG payments are known to exist, it could be a difficult task for the firms to find equal to the path integrals of the vector field of the market them efficiently [14]. Finally, unlike the mechanism design clearing prices, indicating a close relationship between the approach (discussed next), the efficiency loss is inevitable. VCG mechanism and the “clearing-price” mechanism. We then discuss its implications for the electricity market design and The mechanism design is an alternative approach to- also exploit this connection to analyze the budget balance of wards the market power mitigation. For instance, the refer- the VCG mechanism. ences [15]–[18] consider applications of the Vickrey-Clarke- Groves (VCG) mechanism [2, Ch. 23] to several market I. INTRODUCTION design problems in power system operations. The VCG Market power monitoring and mitigation are essential mechanism provides an attractive market model since it aspects of today’s electricity market operations [1]. The attains zero efficiency loss and incentive compatibility (and efficiency loss due to market manipulations by strategic firms often individual rationality [19]). It is also attractive since are not only predicted in theory [2, Ch. 12], but also doc- the existence of equilibria is guaranteed (truth-telling is an umented as real incidents [3]. While the current practice of equilibrium) and it can be trivially found by the participants. market power monitoring relies on relatively simple metrics However, a major shortcoming of the VCG mechanism is (e.g., Herfindahl–Hirschman Index [4]), further deregulation the lack of budget balance [8], which is a prominent reason and emergence of new markets (e.g., ISO-aggregator and why it is rarely used in practice. The VCG mechanism has aggregator-prosumer interfaces) necessitate advanced market other drawbacks such as vulnerability to coalitions, high power analysis [5] and appropriate market design. computational complexity, and lack of privacy [19]. The efficiency loss in oligopolistic electricity markets has For a successful electricity market design in the future, been actively studied in recent literature. Among others, a an integrated discussion on these different approaches are popular venue of research (e.g., [6]–[9]) is based on the sup- desired in the common framework, so that their pros and cons ply function bidding model by Klemperer and Meyer [10], are systematically understood. Therefore, in this paper, we in which the market clears according to the producers’ (resp. discuss different market mechanisms, namely the “clearing- consumers’) submitted supply (resp. demand) functions. In price” mechanism (the underlying mechanism for the supply [10], it is observed that if there is no demand uncertainty function bidding model) and the VCG mechanism, in a and arbitrary supply function bidding is allowed, numerous common set up. As a common set up, we consider a general multiplicity of equilibria emerges. Johari and Tsitsiklis [8] social cost minimization problem with equality and inequal- observed that “as the strategic flexibility granted to firms ity constraints. Our goal is to provide a unified view on increase, their temptation to misdeclare their cost increases as these seemingly different market mechanisms, which would well,” and considered a simple (scalar-parametrized) supply hopefully be valuable in the future studies on electricity function model with N participants and showed that the market design. price of anarchy (efficiency loss) is upper bounded by The contribution of this paper is two-fold. First, we show 1 + 1=(N − 2). In [11], it is observed that the worst case a connection between the VCG mechanism and the clearing- efficiency loss depends on the transmission network topology price mechanism by proving that the VCG payment is equal when there exist transmission constraints. The efficiency loss to the path integral of the vector fields of market clearing under transmission constraints is further studied in [12] under prices under the considered set up (Theorem 2). It also a slightly different supply function bidding model. follows from this observation that tax values calculated by While the market analysis via the supply function bidding the clearing-price mechanism and the VCG mechanism are model has been fruitful, there are several limitations as similar when individual participants’ market power is negli- 1Department of Aerospace Engineering and Engineering Mechanics, Uni- gible. This result indicates a close connection between the versity of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX, USA. [email protected]. VCG and the clearing-price mechanisms. Second, in order 2School of Engineering and Applied Sciences, Harvard University, Cam- to address the budget balance issue of the VCG mechanism, bridge, MA, USA. [email protected]. 3School of Ad- vanced Science and Engineering, Waseda University, Tokyo, Japan. we apply the above observation to analyze the worst case [email protected]. budget loss in the VCG mechanism. With some simplified ∗ assumptions, we outline how the budget loss can be analyzed The net cost for the i-th firm is Ci = fi(~xi ) + πi. An using the main result of this paper. auction mechanism is characterized by a particular choice This paper is formulated as follows. In Section II, a of a decision rule and a payment rule. general social cost minimization problem to be considered We say that an auction mechanism is (dominant strategy) ~ is formulated. The clearing-price mechanism and the VCG incentive compatible if for each firm truth-telling (fi = fi) mechanism are described in Section III. The main technical is an optimal strategy to minimize his/her net cost regardless result (path integral characterization of the VCG mechanism) of the other agents’ reporting strategy. is presented in Section IV. The budget loss of the VCG B. Cost function bidding vs. supply function bidding mechanism is studied in Section V. The cost function bidding model described above is II. PROBLEM FORMULATION closely related to the supply function bidding models [10]. Suppose that there exist N participating firms indexed by In a simple case where a production firm i is producing a i = 1; 2; :::; N and a single auctioneer. Consider a social single commodity (e.g., electricity), a supply function si(p) cost minimization problem with equality and inequality describes the desired level of production as a function of constraints: price p at which the product can be exchanged in the market. N X Mathematically, a production cost function fi(xi) and a P : min f(x) fi(xi) (1a) x , i=1 supply function si(p) are related by si(p) = argmaxxi pxi − XN f (x ): For consuming firms, there is a similar relationship s.t. g(x) , gi(xi) ≤ 0 (1b) i i i=1 between utility functions and demand functions. From this XN h(x) hi(xi) = 0: (1c) relationship (c.f., Legendre transformation), it can be seen , i=1 that a cost function bidding model is equivalent to supply For each i = 1; 2; :::; N, xi can be interpreted as production function bidding model under mild assumptions (e.g., con- by the i-th firm, or as consumption if it is negative. The 2 vexity of fi). For instance, for a > 0, fi(xi) = ax if ni i function fi : R ! R is interpreted as a production cost if 1 and only if si(p) = 2a p. Thus, assuming a linear supply the firm i is a producer, or as a negated utility function if function is equivalent to assuming a quadratic cost function. the firm is a consumer. The aggregation f(x) is referred to Alternatively, suppose that Fi is the set of non-decreasing, as the social cost function (negated social welfare function). continuously differentiable, and strongly convex functions ni k ni l Functions gi : ! and hi : ! are interpreted 0 R R R R from [0; 1) to [0; 1) such that fi(0) = 0 and f (0) = 0. as the i-th firm’s contribution to the global equality/inequality i Then fi 2 Fi if and only if si 2 Si, where Si is the set of constraints such as the power flow balance constraints, line non-decreasing continuous function from [0; 1) to [0; 1) flow limit constraints, local capacity constraints. Constraints such that si(0) = 0. For the rest of this paper, we focus on (1b) and (1c) are imposed entry-wise. the cost function bidding model only. Remark 1: We remark here that in the problem setting (1), we only consider separable objective function and con- III. CLEARING-PRICE AND VCG MECHANISMS straints function. This is usually true for electricity market, In this section, we formally introduce the clearing-price especially when DC power flow model is used where all the mechanism and the VCG mechanism for the social cost constraints are in a linear form [20]. minimization problem (1). We assume that functions gi and hi for each i = 1; 2; :::; N A. The clearing-price mechanism are publicly known. However, the function fi 2 Fi is assumed to be private, i.e., known to the i-th firm only. The The clearing-price mechanism is characterized by the family Fi of functions are assumed to be known a priori.
Recommended publications
  • A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Economics
    Copyright is owned by the Author of the thesis. Permission is given for a copy to be downloaded by an individual for the purpose of research and private study only. The thesis may not be reproduced elsewhere without the permission of the Author. A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Econol11ics: Making Economics Accessible to Students A thesis presented in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics at Massey University Palmerston North, New Zealand. Leanne Marie Smith July 2000 Abstract Paul A. Samuelson is the founder of the modem introductory economics textbook. His textbook Economics has become a classic, and the yardstick of introductory economics textbooks. What is said to distinguish economics from the other social sciences is the development of a textbook tradition. The textbook presents the fundamental paradigms of the discipline, these gradually evolve over time as puzzles emerge, and solutions are found or suggested. The textbook is central to the dissemination of the principles of a discipline. Economics has, and does contribute to the education of students, and advances economic literacy and understanding in society. It provided a common economic language for students. Systematic analysis and research into introductory textbooks is relatively recent. The contribution that textbooks play in portraying a discipline and its evolution has been undervalued and under-researched. Specifically, applying bibliographical and textual analysis to textbook writing in economics, examining a single introductory economics textbook and its successive editions through time is new. When it is considered that an economics textbook is more than a disseminator of information, but a physical object with specific content, presented in a particular way, it changes the way a researcher looks at that textbook.
    [Show full text]
  • The Price Mechanism and Resource Allocation
    The Price Mechanism and Resource Allocation AS Economics Presentation 2005 Markets • A market is the place where buyers and sellers meet to exchange a product. Markets require: – Consumers i.e. buyers – Producers or firms i.e. sellers – Goods or services to trade (a recognizable output) • Examples of markets include: – Housing market: home owners and potential buyers – Labour market: employers and workers – Stock market: share owners and potential buyers – Foreign exchange market: trading currencies Sub Markets – Market Segmentation • The market for most goods can be segmented – broken down into sub markets • The market for houses – (i) sub markets for terraced, semi-detached and detached homes – (ii) the market for rented properties and owner occupied housing • The market for cars is made up of sub markets for family saloon cars, hatchbacks and high performance sports cars • The travel industry is heavily segmented Functions of the Price Mechanism • The price mechanism is the means by which decisions of consumers and businesses interact to determine the allocation of resources between different goods and services • (1) The signaling function – If prices are rising because of stronger demand from consumers, this is a signal to suppliers to expand output to meet the higher demand – When demand is strong, higher market prices act as an incentive to raise output (production) because the supplier stands to make a higher profit • (2) The rationing function – Prices serve to ration scarce resources when demand in a market outstrips supply – When there is a shortage of a product in the market, the price will rise and thus deter some consumers from purchasing the product Adam Smith and the ‘Invisible Hand’ • The 18th Century economist Adam Smith – one of the founding fathers of modern economics, described how the invisible or hidden hand of the market operated in a competitive market through the pursuit of self-interest to allocate resources in society’s best interest • This remains the central view of all free-market economists, i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination † 470 Determination by Pol Antràs and Robert W
    American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2012, 102(3): 470–476 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.3.470 Contents † Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination † 470 Determination By Pol Antràs and Robert W. Staiger* I. Perfect Competition 471 The terms-of-trade theory of trade agree- from subsequently manipulating their domes- ments holds that governments are attracted to tic policy choices to undercut the market access trade agreements as a means of escape from a implications of their tariff commitments, can II. Imperfect Competition 472 terms-of-trade–driven prisoner’s dilemma see bring governments to the efficiency frontier.1 Bagwell and Staiger 1999 . One of the terms-( In this paper, we show that the nature of inter- of-trade theory’s most striking) predictions is national price determination can have important III. Matching 474 about the treatment of behind-the-border pol- effects on this prediction of the terms-of-trade icy measures in trade agreements. According theory. In particular, while the terms-of-trade to this prediction, in the noncooperative Nash theory adopts the view that international prices REFERENCES 476 equilibrium from which countries would begin are fully disciplined by market clearing condi- in the absence of a trade agreement, tariffs are tions, we show here that support for shallow set inefficiently high but behind-the-border poli- integration is overturned, and instead a need for cies are set at efficient levels. Hence, even in the “deep” integration is suggested—wherein direct context of a complex policy environment there negotiations occur over both border and behind- is no need for member governments of a trade the-border policies—if international prices are agreement to negotiate directly over the lev- determined through bargaining.
    [Show full text]
  • Pricing Public Goods for Private Sale
    Proceedings Article Pricing Public Goods for Private Sale MICHAL FELDMAN, Hebrew University and Harvard University DAVID KEMPE, University of Southern California BRENDAN LUCIER, Microsoft Research RENATO PAES LEME, Microsoft Research We consider the pricing problem faced by a seller who assigns a price to a good that confers its benefits not only to its buyers, but also to other individuals around them. For example, a snow-blower is potentially useful not only to the household that buys it, but also to others on the same street. Given that the seller is constrained to selling such a (locally) public good via individual private sales, how should he set his prices given the distribution of values held by the agents? We study this problem as a two-stage game. In the first stage, the seller chooses and announces a price for the product. In the second stage, the agents (each having a private value for the good) decide simultaneously whether or not they will buy the product. In the resulting game, which can exhibit a multiplicity of equilibria, agents must strategize about whether they will themselves purchase the good to receive its benefits. In the case of a fully public good (where all agents benefit whenever any agent purchases), we describe a pricing mechanism that is approximately revenue-optimal (up to a constant factor) when values are drawn from a regular distribution. We then study settings in which the good is only “locally” public: agents are arranged in a network and share benefits only with their neighbors. We describe a pricing method that approximately maximizes revenue, in the worst case over equilibria of agent behavior, for any d-regular network.
    [Show full text]
  • Multi-Unit Bilateral Trade Matthias Gerstgrasser,1 Paul W
    The Thirty-Third AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (AAAI-19) Multi-Unit Bilateral Trade Matthias Gerstgrasser,1 Paul W. Goldberg,2 Bart de Keijzer,3 Philip Lazos,4 Alexander Skopalik5 1,2,4Department of Computer Science, University of Oxford 3School of Computer Science and Electronic Engineering, University of Essex 5Department of Applied Mathematics, University of Twente fmatthias.gerstgrasser, paul.goldberg, fi[email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Abstract term “satisfactory” can be tailored to the specific market un- der consideration, but nonetheless, in economic theory vari- We characterise the set of dominant strategy incentive com- ous universal properties have been identified and agreed on patible (DSIC), strongly budget balanced (SBB), and ex-post individually rational (IR) mechanisms for the multi-unit bilat- as important. The following three are the most fundamental eral trade setting. In such a setting there is a single buyer and ones: a single seller who holds a finite number k of identical items. • Incentive Compatibility ((DS)IC): It must be a dominant The mechanism has to decide how many units of the item are strategy for the agents (buyers and sellers) to behave truth- transferred from the seller to the buyer and how much money fully, hence not “lie” about their valuations for the items is transferred from the buyer to the seller. We consider two in the market. This enables the market mechanism to classes of valuation functions for the buyer and seller: Valua- tions that are increasing in the number of units in possession, make an informed decision about the trades to be made.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Calculation and the Limits of Organization
    Economic Calculation and the Limits of Organization Peter G. Klein conomists have become increasingly frustrated with the text- book model of the firm. The "firm" of intermediate microeco- Enomics is a production function, a mysterious "black box" whose insides are off-limits to respectable economic theory (relegated instead to the lesser disciplines of management, organization theory, industrial psychology, and the like). Though useful in certain contexts, the textbook model has proven unable to account for a variety of real- world business practices: vertical and lateral integration, geographic and product-line diversification, franchising, long-term commercial contract- ing, transfer pricing, research joint ventures, and many others. As an al- ternative to viewing the firm as a production function, economists are turning to a new body ofliterature that views the firm as anorganization, itself worthy of economic analysis. This emerging literature is the best- developed part of what has come to be called the "new institutional eco- nomics."' The new perspective has deeply enhanced and enriched our un- derstanding of firms and other organizations, such that we can no longer agree with Ronald Coase's 1988 statement that "[wlhy firms exist, what determines the number of firms, what determines what firms do . are not questions of interest to most economists" (Coase 1988a, p. 5).The new theory is not without its critics; Richard Nelson (1991), for example, ob- jects that the new institutional economics tends to downplay discretion- ary differences among firms. Still, the new institutional economics-in particular, agency theory and transaction cost economics-has been *Peter G. Klein is assistant professor of economics at the University of Georgia.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Failure in Context: Introduction Alain Marciano and Steven G
    Market Failure in Context: Introduction Alain Marciano and Steven G. Medema Market failure, conceived of as the failure of the market to bring about results that are in the best interests of society as a whole, has a long lin- eage in the history of writings on matters economic. As Steven G. Medema has shown in The Hesitant Hand, much of the history of economics can be read as a discussion of whether, and the extent to which, the self- interested actions of private agents, channeled through the market, will redound to the larger social interest. For much of this history, the answers given were negative, and it was assumed that the corrective hand of the state was needed as a constant and consistent regulating force. Thus we find Plato and Aristotle arguing for a wide range of legal restrictions to guard against macroeconomic (to use the modern term) instability; Aqui- nas making the case for rules that promote a measure of Christian justice in economic affairs; mercantilist writers lobbying for restrictions on vari- ous forms of trade (and support for others), as well as for regulations on Correspondence may be addressed to Alain Marciano, University of Montpellier, Department of Economics, Rue Raymond Dugrand, CS 79606, F-34960 Montpellier, France (e-mail: alain [email protected]); and to Steven G. Medema, Department of Economics, University of Colorado Denver, CB 181, PO Box 173364, Denver, CO 80217-3364 (e-mail: steven.medema @ucdenver.edu). The editors wish to thank Paul Dudenhefer for his diligent shepherding of this project from conference to published volume.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cost of Price: Why and How to Get Beyond Intellectual Property Internalism Amy Kapczynski
    The Cost of Price: Why and How to Get Beyond Intellectual Property Internalism Amy Kapczynski ABSTRACT The field of intellectual property (IP) law today is focused, as the name itself advertises, UCLA LAW REVIEW UCLA LAW on one particular institutional approach to scientific and cultural production: IP. When legal scholars explain this focus, they typically do so with reference to the virtues of price. Because price gives us a decentralized way to link social welfare to the production of information, IP is alleged to be more efficient than other approaches. The dominant mode of IP scholarship begins here and then addresses questions internal to IP law— for example, how broad or narrow should exceptions to IP rights be? But the internalism that characterizes the field of IP cannot, as I show, be justified by the value of efficiency. Economics offers us no a priori reason to assume that IP is more efficient than other possible approaches, most prominently government procurement and commons-based production. If we take the invitation that economists offer us to think external to IP, we also gain new insights about the implications of values other than efficiency for the choice between different institutional approaches to scientific and cultural production. We see, as I argue, that using price to guide scientific and cultural production—which is to say, using IP—may have costs not only for efficiency, but also for distributive justice and informational privacy. The IP approach is in tension with the value of distributive justice because reliance upon price may yield not only unjust distribution of existing information resources but also unjust production of future information resources.
    [Show full text]
  • The Price Mechanism and the Invisible Hand 3
    Exclusive Hyun Kim Jung Hoon Hong Daiki Kim Meejoo Song Wooseung Sohn 1 I. INTRODUCTION In our presentation, there are four main subjects that we will be explaining today. Those subjects are: 1. Private goods and the Free Market System. 2.The Price Mechanism and the Invisible Hand 3. Public goods and the market failure 4. Public hand and the government failure. Before we go into the details, let me briefly give you the overview. First we have to approach these questions by asking ourselves… What do we mean by Exclusive? Of course, the word exclusive can be heard on a regular basis. For example, an exclusive interview with Professor Kim. Then what does the word exclusive mean? According to the dictionary, the word “exclusive” is defined as “not divided or shared with others” So how is this relevant to what we are studying? How is it connected to the rights? You might ask… There were discussions as to what “exclusiveness” meant. In my perspective, there are spiritual and material interests that are protected by the laws. Since, these interests are protected, as the characteristic of the rights, the interest become exclusive when it becomes a right. In having an exclusive right would mean that a person could enjoy the right at his or her wish. Therefore, we felt that there was a close link to the free market system and the right. Well, let’s go back to the last week’s lecture. If you can remember, Sun-young gave us a splendid presentation on the bourgeoisie last week.
    [Show full text]
  • Martin L. Weitzman: Prices Vs. Quantities
    Prices vs. Quantities12 MARTIN L. WEITZMAN Massachusetts Institute of Technology I. INTRODUCTION The setting for the problem under consideration is a large economic organization or system which in some cases is best thought of as the entire economy. Within this large economic organization resources are allocated by some combination of commands and prices (the exact mixture is inessential) or even by some other unspecified mechanism. The following question arises. For one particular isolated economic variable that needs to be regulated,3 what is the best way to implement control for the benefit of the organization as a whole? Is it better to directly administer the activity under scrutiny or to fix transfer prices and rely on self-interested profit or utility maximization to achieve the same ends in decentralized fashion? This issue is taken as the prototype problem of central control which is studied in the present paper. There are a great many specific examples which fit nicely into such a framework. One of current interest is the question of whether it would be better to control certain forms of pollution by setting emission standards or by charging the appropriate pollution taxes. When quantities are employed as planning instruments, the basic operating rules from the centre take the form of quotas, targets, or commands to produce a certain level of output. With prices as instruments, the rules specify either explicitly or implicitly that profits are to be maximized at the given parametric prices. Now a basic theme of resource allocation theory emphasizes the close connection between these two modes of control.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rate at Which a Simple Market Converges to Efficiency As the Number of Traders Increases: an Asymptotic Result for Optimal Trading Mechanisms*
    JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC THEORY 48, 304332 (1989 ) The Rate at Which a Simple Market Converges to Efficiency as the Number of Traders Increases: An Asymptotic Result for Optimal Trading Mechanisms* THOMAS A. GRESIK John M. Olin School of Business. Washington Universiiy. SI. Louis. Missouri 63130 AND MARK A. SATTERTHWAITE Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois 60208 Received January 9, 1987; revised July 19, 1988 Private information in an independent, private-values market provides incentives to traders to manipulate equilibrium prices strategically. This strategic behavior precludes ex post efficient market performance. Increasing the number of traders improves the efficiency of some trading mechanisms by enabling them to better utilize the private information traders’ bids and offers reveal. This paper shows that the expected inefficiency of optimally designed mechanisms, relative to ex post efficient allocations, decreases almost quadratically as the number of traders increases. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: 026, 022. ( 1989 Academic Press. Inc 1. INTRODUCTION Private information prevents achievement of ex post efficiency within a small, private goods market. A trading mechanism’s efficiency may improve as the number of traders increases because more traders may enable it to * The participants of the Economic Theory Workshop at the University of Chicago helped this research materially by discovering a serious error in an early version of this work. We give special thanks to Larry Jones, Ken Judd. Ehud Kalai, Isaac Melijkson. Roger Myerson, and Roger Koenker for their help. This material is based upon work supported by the National Science Foundation under Grants SOC-7907542 and SES-8520247, the Center for Advanced Study in Managerial Economics and Decision Sciences at the Kellogg School, and the Health Care Financing Administration through a grant to Northwestern’s Center for Health Services and Policy Research.
    [Show full text]
  • Auction Vs. Posted-Price: Market Mechanism, Lender Behaviors, and Transaction Outcomes in Online Crowdfunding
    Auction vs. Posted-Price: Market Mechanism, Lender Behaviors, and Transaction Outcomes in Online Crowdfunding Zaiyan Wei and Mingfeng Lin1 December 2013 Abstract We study the effect of different market mechanisms, specifically auctions and posted- prices, on participant behaviors and transaction outcomes in an online personal loan market. We develop a game theoretic model to generate empirically testable predictions, then exploit a regime change on a peer-to-peer lending site, Prosper.com, to test them. We find that under posted-prices, loans are funded with higher probability, but only at higher initial and contract interest rates, and are more likely to default. While market-based auctions may be slow in dis- covering the correct price, “expert”-based posted-price selling may yield unintended, negative welfare consequences. Keywords: Multiunit-auctions, Posted-prices, Crowdfunding, Peer-to-peer (P2P) lending, Ob- servational learning. JEL Classification: D44, L11, L86, G20 1Zaiyan Wei: Department of Economics, University of Arizona (Email: [email protected]). Mingfeng Lin: Department of Management Information Systems, University of Arizona (Email: [email protected]). The authors contribute equally in this research. We thank Keisuke Hirano, Christopher Lamoureux, Chris Parker, Stan- ley Reynolds, Siva Viswanathan, John Wooders, Mo Xiao, and numerous seminar participants for helpful comments and suggestions. All errors remain our own. 1 Introduction Auctions have long been a dominant market mechanism in electronic commerce. A prominent example is eBay.com, one of the earliest and most successful examples of e-commerce, where auctions are extensively used to match buyers and sellers through a competitive process. Auctions are also widely used in online business-to-business (B2B) procurements and many other contexts (Lucking-Reiley(2000), Bajari and Hortac¸su(2004), The Economist(2000)).
    [Show full text]