Chartists, Fundamentalists, and Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Author(S): Jeffrey A

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Chartists, Fundamentalists, and Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Author(S): Jeffrey A American Economic Association Chartists, Fundamentalists, and Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Author(s): Jeffrey A. Frankel and Kenneth A. Froot Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 80, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Second Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1990), pp. 181-185 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2006566 Accessed: 15-06-2016 19:28 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic Review This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Wed, 15 Jun 2016 19:28:57 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms THE RATIONALITY OF THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATEt Chartists, Fundamentalists, and Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market By JEFFREY A. FRANKEL AND KENNETH A. FROOT* The overshooting theory of exchange rates Index, Mwrch 19710X 10 160 seems ideally designed to explain some im- portant aspects of the movement of the dol- 8 lar in recent years. Over the period 1981-84, 140 for example, when real interest rates in the 6 United States rose above those of its trading 120 partners (presumably due to shifts in the monetary/fiscal policy mix), the dollar ap- 2 preciated strongly. It was the higher rates of 100 + - return that made U.S. assets more attractive 0 - to international investors and caused the Lm -T R*W Al80 dollar to appreciate. The overshooting the- 2 ~i ory would say that, as of 1984 for example, 4 t60 1 1 ii E t l i iiiiitiii6 the value of the dollar was so far above its 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 long-run equilibrium that expectations of fu- FIGURE 1. ture depreciation were sufficient to offset the THE DOLLAR AND REAL INTEREST RATES higher nominal interest rate in the minds of international investors. Figure 1 shows the Source: Peter Hooper and Catherine Mann, Federal correlation of the real interest differential Reserve Board. with the real value of the dollar, since ex- Notes: Quarterly data. The CPI-adjusted dollar is a weighted-average index of the exchange value of the qhange rates began to float in 1973. dollar against the currencies of the foreign G-10 coun- tries plus Switzerland, where nominal exchange rates I. Bubble Episodes are multiplied by relative levels of CPIs. Weights are proportional to each foreign country's share in world At times, the path of the dollar has de- exports plus imports from 1978 through 1983. The long-term real interest differential is the U.S. rate minus parted from what would be expected on the the weighted average of foreign-country rates. basis of macroeconomic fundamentals. The most dramatic episode is the period from June 1984 to February 1985. The dollar ap- preciated another 20 percent over this inter- able factors that are suggested in standard val, even though the real interest differential macroeconomic models (money growth rates, had already begun to fall. The other observ- real growth rates, the trade deficit) at this time were also moving in the wrong direc- tion to explain the dollar rise. tDiscussants: Michael Gavin, Columbia University; It is now widely accepted that standard Karen K. Lewis, New York University; Kenneth D. observable macroeconomic variables are not West, University of Wisconsin-Madison. capable of explaining, much less predicting *Department of Economics, University of California, ex ante, the majority of short-term changes Berkeley, CA 94720, and Graduate School of Business, in the exchange rate. But economists divide Harvard University, Boston MA 02163, respectively. We thank MMS International for data, and Lu Cordova into two camps on what this means. One and Joseph Mullally for valuable research assistance. view is that the unexplained short-term 181 This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Wed, 15 Jun 2016 19:28:57 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 182 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1990 changes must be rational revisions in the heterogeneous expectations. For one thing, market's perception of the equilibrium ex- surveys of the forecasts of participants in the change rate due to shifts in "tastes and foreign exchange market show wide disper- technologies," even if the shifts are not ob- sion at any point in time. One, conducted by servable to macroeconomists in the form of the Financial Report (affiliated with the standard measurable fundamentals. A major Economist), reports a high-low range of 6- difficulty with this interpretation is that it is month forecasts that averages 15.2 percent. difficult to believe that there could have been Data in a survey conducted by MMS Inter- an increase in the world demand for U.S. national show a dispersion of opinion (as goods (or in U.S. productivity) sufficient to measured by the standard deviation across increase the equilibrium real exchange rate respondents) at the 1-month horizon that by more than 20 percent over a 9-month averaged 2.2 percent for the yen/dollar rate. period, and that such a shift would then be The dispersion was slightly higher for the reversed over the subsequent 9 months. mark, pound, and Swiss franc rates. This brings us to the second view: that the appreciation may have been an example of a II. Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market speculative bubble-that it was not deter- mined by fundamentals, but rather was the The tremendous volume of foreign ex- outcome of self-confirming market expecta- change trading is another piece of evidence tions. The dollar in 1985 "overshot the over- that reinforces the idea of heterogeneous ex- shooting equilibrium." Some have suggested pectations, since it takes differences among that the appreciation of 1988-89, on a market participants to explain why they smaller scale, may also have been of this trade. The Federal Reserve Bank of New nature. York has released its 3-yearly count of trans- There exist elegant theories of rational actions in the U.S. foreign exchange market. speculative bubbles, in which all participants It showed that in April 1989, foreign ex- know the correct model. Some observers have change trading (adjusted for double-count- suggested that 1984-85 may be best de- ing) totaled $128.9 billion a day, an increase scribed as a bubble that was not character- of 120 percent from March 1986. Simultane- ized by rational expectations.' We have sug- ous counts in London and Tokyo reported gested earlier that such episodes may best be $187 billion and $115 billion a day, respec- described by models of bubbles in which tively. Thus the worldwide total is over $430 market participants do not agree on the billion of foreign exchange trading a day. model for forecasting the exchange rate (see Interestingly, the banks in the New York our forthcoming paper). Federal Reserve Bank census reported that While the conventional approach in the only 4.9 percent of their trading was with a literature, theoretical as well as empirical, is nonfinancial firm, and the nonbanks only 4.4 to assume that there is such a thing as " the" percent; in other words, 95 percent of the market expectation of the future exchange trading takes place among the banks and rate, there is evidence that investors have other financial firms, rather than with cus- tomers such as importers and exporters. Clearly, trading among themselves is a major 1Paul Krugman (1985) was one of the first to suggest economic activity for banks. that the market did not appear to realize the extent to What is the importance of trading volume which the appreciation of the dollar was not sustain- (beyond motivating the importance of het- able. Charles Engel and James Hamilton (forthcoming) find that long-term swings are a general characteristic of erogeneous expectations)? There are three exchange rates, and that they are not adequately re- possible hypotheses, with regard to implica- flected in the forward market. Such findings of pre- tions for movements in the market price. dictable excess returns are standardly interpreted as risk 1) The higher the liquidity or "depth" of the premiums. But evidence from survey data on expecta- tions of market participants suggests that the prediction markets, the more efficiently is news regard- errors of the forward market are not due to risk premi- ing economic fundamentals processed and ums (see our 1989 paper). the smaller is "unnecessary volatility" in the This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Wed, 15 Jun 2016 19:28:57 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms VOL. 80 NO. 2 RA TIONALITY OF THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE RA TE 183 exchange rate. 2) The foreign exchange mar- 111. The Rising Importance of Chartists ket is already perfectly efficient, so that trad- ing volume is irrelevant to price movements We now turn to the question of how the and therefore uninteresting. 3) Much trading existence of different forecasting techniques is based on "noise" rather than "news," and might lead to "excess volatility." It has long leads to excessive volatility. been remarked that if there exist traders who Choosing convincingly among these three tend to forecast by extrapolating recent hypotheses may be too large a task to ac- trends (i.e., who have "bandwagon expecta- complish here.
Recommended publications
  • Securitization of Mortgage Debt, Asset Prices and International Risk Sharing
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Hoffmann, Mathias; Nitschka, Thomas Working Paper Securitization of mortgage debt, asset prices and international risk sharing CESifo Working Paper, No. 2527 Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Hoffmann, Mathias; Nitschka, Thomas (2009) : Securitization of mortgage debt, asset prices and international risk sharing, CESifo Working Paper, No. 2527, Center for Economic Studies and ifo Institute (CESifo), Munich This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/26572 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Securitization of Mortgage Debt, Asset Prices and International Risk Sharing MATHIAS HOFFMANN THOMAS NITSCHKA CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Globalization: Culprit, Survivor Or Casualty of the Great Crisis?
    Financial Globalization Culprit, Survivor or Casualty of the Great Crisis? A publication of the Yale Center for the Study of Globalization Financial Globalization Culprit, Survivor or Casualty of the Great Crisis? A publication of the Yale Center for the Study of Globalization From the proceedings of a conference by the same name, held on November 12 and 13, 2009 Yale University New Haven, Connecticut Financial Globalization: Culprit, Survivor or Casualty of the Great Crisis? A Yale Center for the Study of Globalization eBook Yale Center for the Study of Globalization Betts House 393 Prospect Street New Haven, CT 06511 USA Tel: (203) 432-1900 Email: [email protected] Web: www.ycsg.yale.edu ©Yale Center for the Study of Globalization, 2010 The papers contained in this book are based on presentations from the conference Financial Globalization: Culprit, Survivor or Casualty of the Great Crisis?, organized by the Yale Center for the Study of Globalization at Yale University in New Haven, Connecticut on November 12 and 13, 2009. The conference was made possible by generous support from the Ford Foundation. Yale Center for the Study of Globalization The Yale Center for the Study of Globalization (YCSG) was established in 2001 to enhance understanding of this fundamental process and to promote exchanges of information and ideas about globalization between Yale and the policy world. The Center is devoted to examining the impact of our increasingly integrated world on individuals, communities, and nations. Globalization presents challenges and opportunities. The Center’s purpose is to support the creation and dissemination of ideas for seizing the opportunities and overcoming the challenges.
    [Show full text]
  • Combined Optimization of Portfolio and Risk Exposure of an Insurance Company
    Combined Optimization of Portfolio and Risk Exposure of an Insurance Company Daniel O. Cajueiro and Takashi Yoneyama Department of Systems and Control Aeronautics Institute of Technology Centro T´ecnicoAeroespacial S˜aoJos´edos Campos, SP 12228-900 Brazil Abstract This paper presents a model for an insurance company that controls its risk and is allowed to invest in a financial market with just two assets - a risk free asset and a stock. The financial reserve of this company is modelled as an Ito process with positive drift and constant diffusion coefficient. While the diffusion coefficient can be interpreted as the risk exposure, the drift can be understood as the potential profit. The new feature of this paper is to consider that the potential profit of this company depends on the dynamical state of the economy. Thus, in order to take into account the state of the economy, the drift process is modelled as a continuous time Markov chain. The aim is to maximize the reserve of an insurance company whose manager is risk averse. The optimal control problem is formulated and the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation is solved to yield the solution. 1 Introduction Since the seminal papers due to Merton [26], [27], the optimal stochastic control methods have been among the most useful recent techniques to deal with problems in economics and finance. This is due to the fact that many economical and financial problems present the necessity of taking decisions based on an objective performance criterion and in the presence of uncertainty. In this context, this paper presents a model for an insurance company that controls its risk and is allowed to invest in a financial market with just two assets as in the Black-Scholes market [4] – a risk free asset and a stock.
    [Show full text]
  • The Quants Made Several Interrelated Errors
    Chapter Three The Failure of the Quants Chapter 3. Failure of the Quants Abstract: The Quants made several interrelated errors. They based the expected house price upon the current price and drift, and assumed that the distribution of capital gains is unchanging. The Quants ignored publicly available information in forming expectations. The ultimate determinant of the values of CDO’s was the ability of the mortgagors to service their debts. It was public information that the mortgages were of most dubious value, no due diligence was performed in the ratings and the debt/income of the mortgagors was rising. Hence it was improbable that the distribution of house prices would remain constant. Systemic risk was ignored by the Quants who just focused upon current prices. Ratings of the tranches were not based upon the quality of the underlying mortgages. They were all in the same bundle. The rating depended upon who got paid first in the stack of loans. The key question was how to rate and price the tranches. The issue concerned the correlation of the tranches. If a pool of loans started experiencing difficulties, and a certain percent of them defaulted, what would be the impact upon each tranche? The “apples in the basket model” made one prediction. Another very different one is “the slice of bread in the loaf” model. This chapter considers the role of the “Quants” in the crisis. The financial system is an intermediary between savers and investors. Mathematics is essential to price securities traded by savers, intermediaries and investors, and to adjust risk to the preferences of savers and investors.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of Varying Information in the Residential Mortgage-Backed Securities Market
    The Impact of Varying Information in the Residential Mortgage-Backed Securities Market Research Report August 2019 About the Centre for Economic Analysis About This Report The Canadian Centre for Economic Analysis The design and method of research, as well as (CANCEA) is a socio-economic research and data the content of this study, were determined firm. CANCEA provides objective, independent solely by CANCEA. and evidence-based analysis and is dedicated to a comprehensive, collaborative, and quantitative Statistics Canada data and relevant literature understanding of the short- and long-term risks were used to inform the computer simulation models used to produce the results of this and returns behind market changes, policy decisions and economic behaviour. report. CANCEA uses modern techniques in data science, Forecasts and research often involve numerous including agent-based modelling, for assumptions and data sources and are subject econometric analysis, risk management to inherent risks and uncertainties. This assessments, demographic forecasts and information is not intended as specific epidemiology. CANCEA’s work includes market investment, accounting, legal, or tax advice. analysis, policy evaluation and risk management, business model optimization, cost-effectiveness and rate of return analysis, macroeconomic analysis, insurance risk evaluation, land use and infrastructure planning, logistics, and labour market analysis. CANCEA also provides comprehensive Canadian data services. At the centre of CANCEA’s analytical capabilities is an agent-based platform called Prosperity at Risk® that is an extensive, data-driven model of 56,000 locations across Canada. Given the systems focus behind all of CANCEA’s work, CANCEA has a one-model approach to its analysis which allows various disciplines and stakeholders to be incorporated into a single analysis.
    [Show full text]
  • The Chartist Imaginary
    The Chartist Imaginary The Chartist Imaginary Literary Form in Working-Class Political Theory and Practice Margaret A. Loose THE OHIO STATE UNIVERSITY PREss COLUMBus Copyright © 2014 by The Ohio State University. All rights reserved. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Loose, Margaret A., 1967– The Chartist imaginary : literary form in working-class political theory and practice / Margaret A. Loose. pages cm Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-0-8142-1266-0 (cloth : alk. paper) — ISBN 0-8142-1266-2 (cloth : alk. paper) — ISBN 978-0-8142-9370-6 (cd) — ISBN 0-8142-9370-0 (cd) 1. Politics and literature—Great Britain—History—19th century. 2. Chartism. 3. English litera- ture—19th century—History and criticism. 4. Literature and society—Great Britain—History— 19th century. 5. English literature—Women authors—History and criticism. 6. Working class writings, English—History and criticism. 7. Political poetry, English—History and criticism. 8. Working class in literature. I. Title. PR468.C43L66 2014 820.9'007—dc23 2014013225 Cover design by Thao Thai Text design by Juliet Williams Type set in Adobe Minion Pro Printed by Thomson-Shore, Inc. The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of the American Na- tional Standard for Information Sciences—Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials. ANSI Z39.48–1992. 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 • contents • List of Illustrations vii Acknowledgments ix Introduction: Chartism and the Politics of Form 1 1 Ernest Jones and the Poetics of Internationalism 12
    [Show full text]
  • Market Metaphors 1
    Market Metaphors 1 Running head: STOCK MARKET METAPHORS Metaphor in Stock Market Commentary: Consequences and Preconditions of Agentic Descriptions of Price Trends Michael W. Morris Columbia University Oliver J. Sheldon Cornell University Daniel R. Ames Columbia University Maia J. Young University of California, Los Angeles Correspondence address: Michael W. Morris, 3022 Broadway, 718 Uris Hall NY, NY 10027-6902 [email protected] (ph) 212 854 2296 Market Metaphors 2 Abstract We investigated the consequences and preconditions of two types of metaphors in stock market commentary. Agent metaphors describe price trends as actions of an animate, self- propelled actor, whereas object metaphors describe them as movements of an inanimate object caused by external physical forces. Study 1 examined the consequences of commentary for lay investors’ judgments. Agent metaphors, compared with object metaphors and non-metaphoric descriptions, caused investors to expect price trend continuance. The remaining studies examined preconditions, the features of a trend that cause commentators to use agent versus object metaphors. We hypothesized that the rate of agentic metaphors would depend on the trend direction (upday vs downday) and steadiness (steady vs unsteady). Two archival studies tracked the metaphoric content in end-of-day CNBC commentary as function of daily price trajectories. As predicted, agent metaphors were more likely for uptrends than downtrends and especially so when the trends were relatively steady. This held for both bull (Study 2) and bear market periods (Study 3). Study 4 replicated these findings in a laboratory study where participants took the role of a stock market commentator. We discuss implications of these findings for the literatures on metaphoric cognition and financial judgment.
    [Show full text]
  • Evidence on the Contrarian Trading in Foreign Exchange Markets
    Economic Modelling 26 (2009) 1420–1431 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Economic Modelling journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecmod Evidence on the contrarian trading in foreign exchange markets Jer-Yuh Wan a,⁎, Chung-Wei Kao b a Department of Economics, Tamkang University, Tamsui, Taipei County, 25137, Taiwan b Department of Public Finance and Taxation, Takming University of Science and Technology, Neihu, Taipei, 11451, Taiwan article info abstract Article history: This paper investigates the existence and price impacts of contrarian behavior in the foreign exchange Accepted 20 July 2009 markets. By utilizing a nonlinear behavioral model where the chartists and fundamentalists coexist, evidence obtained from two sample periods significantly supports the existence of contrarian trading in the British JEL classification: pound, the Japanese yen and the German mark markets. The contrarian trading can only partially offset the E58 price impacts of trend-followers, therefore the price impact of the chartists as a whole is destabilizing. The F31 ability that the contrarians can counterbalance the extrapolation of the trend-followers differs across G15 markets. Traders in the BP market have the highest tendency to contrarian strategy, which in turn Keywords: contributes to the least deviations of the BP exchange rates departing from its PPP fundamentals. The Exchange rates fundamentalists' confidence in trade fades during large misalignments, which make the mean reversion Contrarian strategy function of the fundamentalists weak under the circumstances. We find the magnitudes of interventions will Heterogeneous agents be affected by the price impacts of contrarians and their abilities on market stabilization. Nonlinearity © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
    [Show full text]
  • Chartists and Fundamentalists in Emerging Currency Markets
    Chartists and Fundamentalists in Emerging Currency Markets Gerben J. de Zwart Robeco Quantitative Strategies Coolsingel 120, Rotterdam NL-3011 AG, The Netherlands [email protected] Thijs D. Markwat Econometric Institute and Erasmus Research Institute of Management [email protected] Laurens A. P. Swinkels Robeco Quantitative Strategies and Erasmus Research Institute of Management [email protected] Dick van Dijk Econometric Institute Erasmus University Rotterdam [email protected] This version: January 2007 1 Chartists and Fundamentalists in Emerging Currency Markets ABSTRACT The mainstream of literature on emerging currency markets focuses on the crisis early warning signals models. The rise of floating exchange rate regimes in the emerging markets since the late nineties warrants a different study. For six different floating emerging market currencies we provide new evidence on the economic and statistical significance of foreign exchange rate prediction by using purchasing power parity and real interest rate strategies, over the 1995-2006 period. We also document that technical trading strategies generate economically and statistically significant returns, even after the inclusion of the costs entailing the bid-ask spread as well as the, non-negligible, interest rate differential. The most important contribution of this paper is that we find empirical evidence that investment weights based on 12 month past performance of fundamentalist and chartist strategies economically and statistically improve the risk-adjusted performance over naive combinations of fundamentalists and chartists. Hence, these results provide empirical evidence supporting heterogeneous agents models that assume that not all traders are acting the same all the time. All these results are robust over an additional, but shorter, sample of nine floating emerging markets currencies.
    [Show full text]
  • Views from the Sovereign Bond Market
    THE JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC HISTORY VOLUME 75 March 2015 NUMBER 1 How Did Britain Democratize? Views from the Sovereign Bond Market AdityA dAsguptA And dAniel ZiblAtt To assess competing theories of democratization, we analyze British sovereign bond market responses to the 1832, 1867, and 1884 Reform Acts, and to two failed Chartist agitations for reform. Analyses of high-frequency 3 percent consol yield data and were preceded by increases in perceived political risk, comparable to democratizing episodes in other countries. Second, both democratic reform and repression were followed by yield declines. Third, the source of political risk in Britain was both characterization of British democratization as exceptionally risk-free. he process of democratization in Britain—in particular the franchise Texpansions legislated in the 1832, 1867, and 1884 Reform Acts—has attracted intensive scholarly attention.1 One long-standing view, rooted The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 75, No. 1 (March 2015). © The Economic History Association. All rights reserved. doi: Aditya Dasgupta is Ph.D. candidate, Department of Government, Harvard University, 1737 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA, 02138. E-mail: [email protected]. Daniel Ziblatt is Professor of Government, Department of Government, Harvard University, 27 Kirkland Street, Cambridge, MA, 02138. E-mail: [email protected]. sharing data. All errors are our own. 1 in Europe largely in the nineteenth century, with some precursors earlier, along three main dimensions: (1) the expansion and equalization of the right to vote (e.g., suffrage reform), (2) outcomes, and (3) the institutionalization of civil liberties (e.g., freedom of the press, freedom of association, etc.) to protect against arbitrary rule.
    [Show full text]
  • Fundamentalist/Chartist” Heterogeneous Agents
    Wealth Share Analysis with “Fundamentalist/Chartist” Heterogeneous Agents Hai-Chuan Xu1,2, Wei Zhang1,2, Xiong Xiong1,2*, Wei-Xing Zhou3,4,5 1Collage of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin, 300072, China; 2China Center for Social Computing and Analytics, Tianjin University, Tianjin, 300072, China 3School of Business, East China University of Science and Technology, Shanghai, 200237, China 4Department of Mathematics, East China University of Science and Technology, Shanghai, 200237, China 5Research Center for Econophysics, East China University of Science and Technology, Shanghai, 200237, China Abstract:We build a multi-assets heterogeneous agents model with fundamentalists and chartists, who make investment decisions by maximizing the constant relative risk aversion utility function. We verify that the model can reproduce the main stylized facts in real markets, such as fat-tailed return distribution, long-term memory in volatility, and so on. Based on the calibrated model, we study the impacts of the key strategies’ parameters on investors’ wealth shares. We find that, as chartists’ exponential moving average periods increase, their wealth shares also show an increasing trend. This means that higher memory length can help to improve their wealth shares. This effect saturates when the exponential moving average periods are sufficiently long. On the other hand, the mean reversion parameter has no obvious impacts on wealth shares of either type of traders. It suggests that, no matter fundamentalists take moderate strategy or aggressive strategy on the mistake of stock prices, it will has no different impact on their wealth shares in the long run. 1. Introduction Compared with traditional economic modeling, agent-based modeling is more flexible in terms of characterizing the individual heterogeneity and population dynamics.
    [Show full text]
  • The Chartist Actual Cash Account Access Code Status As of 04/18/19 Current 4449 Stock No
    rating 49 Y Celeb ears THEP.O. Box 758,CHARTIST Seal Beach, California 90740 Published Editors: Dan Sullivan & Steve Mais Since 1969 April 18, 2019 THE CHARTIST ACTUAL CASH ACCOUNT ACCESS CODE STATUS AS OF 04/18/19 CURRENT 4449 STOCK NO. OF PURCHASE PURCHASE CURRENT GAIN PERCENT STOCK SYMBOL SHARES DATE PRICE PRICE (LOSS) CHANGED ALLSTATE CORPORATION ALL 52 9/7/12 38.51 96.70 3,026 151.1 AMAZON COM INC AMZN 8 9/7/12 256.77 1861.69 12,839 625.0 SPDR DOW JONES DIA 371 6/3/16 177.98 265.51 32,474 49.2 EBAY INC EBAY 41 9/7/12 19.28 35.98 685 86.6 EQUINIX INC NEW EQIX 10 9/7/12 201.22 446.44 2,452 121.9 HOME DEPOT INC HD 36 9/7/12 57.44 205.71 5,338 258.1 ISHARES RUSSELL 2000 IWM 1,271 1/10/19 142.15 155.61 17,108 9.5 SPDR S&P MIDCAP 400 ETF MDY 454 2/21/19 350.23 355.87 2,561 1.6 PAYPAL PYPL 41 9/7/12 29.81 107.36 3,180 260.1 SPDR S&P 500 SPY 627 6/3/16 210.32 289.99 49,953 37.9 SUNTRUST BANKS INC STI 75 9/7/12 27.62 63.51 2,692 129.9 T J X COS INC TJX 88 9/7/12 22.99 55.13 2,828 139.8 CURRENT STOCK VALUE $687,012.00 MONEY MARKET FUNDS $664,667.00 TOTAL COST $551,852.00 TOTAL PROFITS $135,160.00 Above are all the open positions in the Chartist long-term managed account.
    [Show full text]