<<

Hastings Communications and Journal

Volume 17 | Number 1 Article 1

1-1-1994 Freedom of Expression and the 1992 Cable Act: An Introduction Eli M. Noam

Carolyn Cutler

Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/ hastings_comm_ent_law_journal Part of the Communications Law Commons, Entertainment, Arts, and Sports Law Commons, and the Intellectual Law Commons

Recommended Citation Eli M. Noam and Carolyn Cutler, Freedom of Expression and the 1992 Cable Act: An Introduction, 17 Hastings Comm. & Ent. L.J. 1 (1994). Available at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_comm_ent_law_journal/vol17/iss1/1

This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Hastings Communications and Entertainment Law Journal by an authorized editor of UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Freedom of Expression and the 1992 Cable Act: An Introduction

ELI M. NOAM* and CAROLYN CUTLER**

Table of Contents I. The 1992 Cable A ct ...... II. Th e Issues ...... III. Common Carriage as a Free Speech Remedy? ......

* Professor of Finance and Economics, and Director, Columbia Institute for Tele- Information, Graduate School of Business, Columbia University. A.B. 1970, A.M. 1972, J.D. 1975, Ph.D. Economics 1975, Harvard University. ** Research Affiliate, Columbia Institute for Tele-Information, and Director, Instruc- tional Technology, New York School for the Deaf. B.A. 1981, M.A. Communications 1992, University of Texas. HASTINGS COMM/ENT L.J. [Vol. 17:1

Introduction

On October 5, 1992, Congress passed the Cable Con- sumer Protection and Competition Act1 (1992 Cable Act) by overrid- ing a presidential veto, the only such occurrence during President Bush's term of office. This followed years of vigorous battles among warring interest groups, contending legislators, and crusading advo- cacy groups. Yet the clamor of political battle was not matched by a constitutional debate. With economics and politics the main topics, freedom of speech was a side show. Today, with a bit of distance, with electronic media converging, and with the information superhighway a Washington buzzword, one can resume the questioning. Is it constitutional under the First Amendment to create that restrict a communications me- dium such as cable television? Looking at the 1992 Cable Act, one can identify numerous free speech issues, including the following: " Is there a constitutional asymmetry in the treatment of various communications media? " In what ways does new communications technology affect free speech rights? " Is it constitutional to mandate preferential access to a physical transmission conduit by some content providers? Can one differ- entiate between commercial and non-profit voices? * What is the relationship between common carriage (mandated non-discriminatory access) and free speech? " Can owners of one medium be precluded from owning another? " Is it constitutional to mandate the licensing of one firm's program content by competing firms? * Can a conduit be liable for content transmitted by it under legal requirement? " Can a multichannel conduit be required to segregate certain pro- grams onto designated channels? " Is it constitutional to require broadcasters to have their programs distributed by cable operators without permission or compensation? * Is it constitutional to make the presence of effective competition a condition for free speech? " Can one require cable operators to prohibit certain programs from access channels, to segregate adult programs onto a single channel, and to make the liable for them?

1. Pub. L. No. 102-385, 106 Stat. 1460 (codified as amended at scattered sections of 47 U.S.C.) [hereinafter 1992 Cable Act]. 2. 138 CONG. REC. S16,676 (daily ed. Oct. 5, 1992). 1994] THE 1992 CABLE ACr

To address these questions, the Columbia Institute for Tele-Infor- mation (CITI) convened a group of noted scholars, each with a per- spective of the 1992 Cable Act, and each an expert on speech, communications law, or media economics. Their work was then dis- cussed by noted practitioners, officials, and scholars. CITI is a nonprofit research center at Columbia University. It seeks to analyze and discuss issues of communications, economics, law, and policy. CITI does not engage in consulting or proprietary studies and takes seriously its independence from interest groups. The project was funded by the following: CITI's general funds; the Freedom Forum Foundation (formerly the Gannett Foundation, with a major stake in the Gannett Company, the owner of newspapers, broadcast stations, and businesses); and Dr. Leonard Tow, Chairman and CEO of the cable and firms Cen- tury Communications Corporation and Citizens Utilities, together with his cable industry associates from the Entrepreneurs' Club. As agreed from the outset, none of these parties other than CITI played any role in the selection of the topics or authors. The authors span a wide range of perspectives and conclusions. They were not selected to represent any particular point of view, but rather because of their outstanding reputations in the scholarship of speech and communications. Regardless of the authors' views on any part of the 1992 Cable Act, the reader will find these articles provocative.

I The 1992 Cable Act

The Cable Television Consumers Protection and Competition Act is a response to the industry conditions that were encouraged by an earlier major piece of , the Cable Television Communica- tion Policy Act of 1984.1 That law, passed at the height of the Reagan years with bi-partisan support and shepherded through Congress by the Telecommunications Subcommittee Chairman, Congressman (soon Senator) Timothy Wirth of Colorado, substantially deregulated the cable industry from price controls by local governments and largely eliminated the threat of non-renewal of a franchise. Freed from restrictions, the cable television industry developed after 1984 even faster than before. It increased channel capacity (to an average

3. 47 U.S.C. §§ 521-559 (1984). HASTINGS COMM/ENT L.J. [Vol. 17:1 of thirty-seven in 19934), program diversity (there are over one hun- dred satellite service channels5), reach (passing over ninety percent of households), and customer base (sixty-three percent of television households6). Yet cable television's very success also bore the seeds of its subsequent reregulation. Cable's attractiveness raised demand for it, while the high cost of upgrade and the debt repayment of ex- pansion put pressure on the supply side. With only limited multichan- nel competition, cable rates increased-according to Congress, three times as fast as inflation. At the same time, the quality of service led to many consumer complaints, but local governments across the coun- try lacked regulatory powers to remedy the situation. On the content side, cable's high penetration gave the cable in- dustry increasing gatekeeper power over access to a viewer by a pro- gram provider. They had the power to pick and choose program channels and exclude those posing a threat to their own affiliated pro- gram channels. Furthermore, they could deny popular program chan- nels to competing delivery media such as direct satellite broadcasters, microwave "wireless cable" operators, telephone companies, and al- ternative cable systems. With over-the-air broadcasting channels re- ceived increasingly over the cable wire and reception antennas dismantled, television broadcasters were worried about not being car- ried over cable or being placed on unfavorable spots on the dial. As a consequence of these various concerns, a broad-based coali- tion of consumer groups, broadcasters, municipalities, and other po- tential competitive media formed and campaigned for reregulation. Allied with the cable industry were the Hollywood studios, the White House, and some deregulation-minded legislators. In 1990, a regulatory bill passed the House but failed in the Sen- ate. In 1991, the FCC, under Congressional pressure, adopted a stricter definition of "effective competition." But for Congress it was a matter of too little, too late. Soon, new bills were introduced by Representative Edward Markey and Senators Ernest Hollings, Daniel Inouye, and John Danforth. At that point, the cable television industry could possibly have averted large-scale by supporting a real opening of mul- tichannel television to much greater competition, substituting market forces for regulation. But the cable industry, confident that a presi-

4. SUSAN TYLER EASTMAN, BROADCAST/CABLE PROGRAMMING: STRATEGIES AND PRACTICES 246 (4th ed. 1993). 5. Id. at 247. 6. A.C. NIELSEN Co., NIELSEN REPORT ON TELEVISION (Feb. 1994), cited in NA- TIONAL CABLE TELEVISION ASS'N, CABLE TELEVISION DEVELOPMENTS (Apr. 1994). 1994] THE 1992 CABLE ACT dential veto would hold, as thirty-five previous Bush vetoes had, op- posed both regulation and greater competition. It lost when rural and moderate Republicans broke rank with President Bush and voted for a regulatory bill. The vote was 74-25 in the Senate 7 and 308-114 in the House.8 The sprawling new Act's major provisions sought, among others: " To reimpose rate regulation by local governments on "basic tier" cable service where a cable system is not subject to effective competition; " To allow broadcasters to demand payment by cable television op- erators for "retransmission consent;" " To adopt "must-carry" requirements, i.e. access rights of broad- casters to the cable network without compensation; * To require program channel suppliers affiliated with cable compa- nies to programming to competing distribution media; * To require cable companies, depending upon system capacity and concentration, to carry leased commercial access channels (sub- ject to regulated rates and substitutable for minority and educa- tional programming) and public access channels; " To prohibit a cable operator from owning a satellite master an- tenna television service or a multichannel multipoint distribution service in the same franchise area; and * To require leased and public access programs of an "adult" nature to be segregated on a separate channel, available only to those who request it in writing, with cable companies subject to poten- tial liability for the programs.

H The Issues A major provision of the 1992 Cable Act is the "must-carry" obli- gation under which cable operators are required to carry the over-the- air broadcast signals available in their area. Within an hour of its en- actment, the Turner Broadcasting Corporation challenged the provi- sion in .9 Within twenty-two months, the Supreme Court handed down a decision.1 ° The Court's shaky 5-4 decision gave neither side a solid win. There were five separate opinions, and the majority included the retir- ing Blackmun. Significantly, the must-carry provision re- mained in place with the Court finding the rules to be content-neutral

7. 138 CONG. REC S16,676 (daily ed. Oct. 5, 1992). 8. 138 CONG. REC Hl1,487-88 (daily ed. Oct. 5, 1992). 9. Turner Broadcasting Sys., Inc. v. FCC, No. 92-2247 (D.D.C. filed Oct. 5, 1992). 10. Turner Broadcasting Sys., Inc. v. FCC, 114 S. Ct. 2445 (1994), vacating and re- manding 819 F. Supp. 32 (D.D.C. 1993), reh'g denied, 115 S. Ct. 30 (1994). HASTINGS COMM/ENT L.J. [Vol. 17:1 and requiring an intermediate level of scrutiny." But the Court re- manded the factual issue of harm to the broadcasters to the lower . 2 The majority opinion, written by Justice Kennedy, concluded that the must-carry rules were justified but that the lower court had not adequately shown that broadcasting was "in genuine jeopardy and in need of the protections afforded by must-carry," and, even with such a showing, that must-carry "does not burden substantially more speech than is necessary to further the government's legitimate inter- ests."' 3 The majority found the law justified because of the "special characteristics of the cable medium: the bottleneck monopoly power exercised by cable operators and the dangers this power poses to the viability of broadcast television." 4 In a dissenting opinion, Justice O'Connor, joined by Scalia, Thomas, and Ginsburg, argued that the rules were clearly content-based and thus called for a strict scrutiny test of compelling state interest and no less drastic means. "[Mly con- clusion that must-carry rules are content-based leads me to conclude that they are an impermissible restraint on the cable operators' edito- rial discretion as well as on the cable programmers' speech.' 5 More generally, eight of the concurred that cable operators should have greater First Amendment rights than those of broadcasters but not the same First Amendment protection as the print media. Analyzing the must-carry question, Burt Neuborne, Professor of Law at New York University and former Legal Director of the Ameri- can Civil Liberties Union, argues in his article that one must uncouple the constitutional issues of the actual speech from the conduit me- dium, even if one is supportive of the vertical integration. He points to the "symbiotic relationship" between speech and amplifying tech- nologies that increase its potential audience. He concludes that the conduit can be regulated as a technical entity, while the standard for regulation of content is much higher. The opposite conclusion is reached by Roger Pilon, Senior Fellow and Director, Center for Constitutional Studies at the Cato Institute. Pilon views the Court's fundamental flaw to be its basic method of constitutional analysis-the application of a multilevel system of scru- tiny. "[T]he chances of a law being found constitutional are almost a direct function of the level of judicial scrutiny the law receives- 'strict,' 'intermediate,' 'relaxed,' or 'minimal'." Such "scrutiny the-

11. Id. at 2469. 12. Id. at 2472. 13. Id. at 2468, 2470-72. 14. Id. at 2468. 15. Id. at 2479 (O'Connor, J., dissenting). 1994] THE 1992 CABLE Acr ory," Pilon argues, has no basis in the original design of the . A third position-must-carry, but for public broadcasters only- is advanced by Donald Hawthorne and Monroe Price of the Cardozo School of Law. They believe that a must~carry requirement for com- mercial broadcasters is constitutionally invalid because there is no meaningful content basis to give them preferential access to cable over their competitors. On the other hand, the authors argue for the constitutionality of mandated access of non-commercial stations, be- cause their content and meets congressional objectives. Another question raised by the 1992 Cable Act is whether the owners of one medium can be precluded from controlling another. The 1992 Cable Act bars a cable operator from owning alternative video delivery systems (such as satellite master antenna systems or microwave "wireless cable") in the same franchise area. Edwin Baker, Professor of Law at the University of Pennsylvania Law School, addresses the cross-ownership rule and its First Amendment basis. He argues in favor of structural regulation to establish a diver- sity of information from antagonistic sources. To him, a telephone- cable merger would create an undesirable monopoly with market and political power. In a similar vein, Professor Cass Sunstein of the Chicago Law School argues against First Amendment absolutism: "What seems to be government regulation of speech might, in some circumstances, promote free speech ...what seems to be free speech in markets might, on reflection, amount to an abridgement of free speech." A communication distribution network, where it is a natural monopoly, could be regulated as a . To support this position, Sunstein presents a provocative paradigm that he calls a "New Deal for Speech." He reasons that when the government grants exclusive property rights in the form of licensing broadcasters, for example, a broadcaster becomes an agent of the government. The broadcaster's subsequent act of denying access to a programmer becomes, by associ- ation, a governmental act. Therefore, the speaker (programmer) can seek First Amendment protection against the restriction of its speech. Sunstein suggests that a strict reading of the First Amendment permits government to grant exclusive ownership rights to communication networks only with the condition of common carriage. Looking at the issue of a cable operator's liability for indecent programming over its leased and public access channels, Professor Fred Schauer of the Kennedy School of Government at Harvard takes first issue with the frequent assertion that rights entail responsibilities. HASTINGS COMM/ENT L.J. [Vol. 17:1

He finds the cable operators' lost immunity to be largely symbolic in nature because media producers and conduits have historically been largely protected from liability for indecent, defamatory, and mislead- ing programming. He points to the more important issue associated with a shifting of the cable industry's role in leased channels from that of a passive quasi-common carrier to one with editorial control over leased and public access channels. Schauer has a word of caution to the cable industry as it follows the editorial model of control over in- decent programming. He suggests that a more advantageous position for the cable industry would be to follow the telephone model by de- fining itself as a common carrier of leased and public access channels. Establishing the basic principles of cable regulation is one thing; implementing them is quite another. From a constitutional perspec- tive, how did the FCC put Congress' mandates into effect? While this is an ongoing process, some early conclusions are possible. Professor Michael Meyerson of the University of Baltimore School of Law looks at the FCC's handling of indecent programming and home-shopping on cable. He finds that the FCC's holding the indecency restrictions constitutionally valid while discounting earlier court cases was without merit and misleading. "The FCC's analysis ... reveals such an over- eagerness to restrict constitutionally protected speech as to call into question the degree to which the Commission was sympathetic to the constitutional concerns its rules raised." But he is also sympathetic to the FCC's dilemma: "As a creature of Congress, an agency is prohib- ited from second-guessing its creator. It is Dr. Frankenstein, not his monster, who gets the last word." Congress, deeply distrustful of the deregulation-minded FCC of the Reagan and Bush years, left the FCC with little discretion. For example, in the absence of "effective competition," the 1992 Cable Act required the FCC to develop a methodology, under a tight dead- line, to regulate rates for basic cable service. As it turns out, a Demo- cratic FCC was soon at work, creating "benchmarks" against which actual price increases were measured. How well did the FCC do its job? The case of benchmarks is one instance in which the FCC's im- plementation of the 1992 Cable Act can be subjected to a quantitative analysis. Stanley Besen, author of the FCC's major 1980 Network In- quiry Study,16 and John Woodbury, both of Charles River Associates, analyze the FCC's statistical methodology to estimate the benchmark rates-first determined at ten percent, and then, with a new chairman

16. FCC, NETWORK INQUIRY SPECIAL STAFF, NEW TELEVISION NETWORKS: ENTRY, , OWNERSHIP AND REGULATION (1980). 19941 THE 1992 CABLE Acr and new methodology, seventeen percent-and conclude that it was seriously flawed.17 One of the most sensitive free speech issues is the right not to speak. In the cable context, it is the right of owners of a program to use it as they see fit. Yet the 1992 Cable Act includes a "must-license" requirement according to which a cable-affiliated program provider must make its programs available to other multichannel program dis- tributors under non-discriminatory terms. Professor Wendy Gordon and Anne Gowen of Boston University School of Law analyze this issue. They conclude that while those limitations on vendors' prop- erty rights may be questioned, they are in line with current practice in statutory intellectual as well as in -made and property law. Many of these themes are picked up in a central symposium arti- cle by Robert Corn-Revere, of Hogan & Hartson, and a former legal assistant to long-time FCC Commissioner James Quello, who served as Acting Chairman during several of the FCC's 1992 Cable Act im- plementation proceedings. Corn-Revere traces the evolution of speech regulation in various media and describes how we are on the verge of a major shift in First Amendment doctrine in the emerging Multimedia Age. This has legislators, regulators, and courts in a box as they try to maintain the three regulatory models of print, tele- phone, and broadcast in an environment of converging technology. He argues for a return to the core values of the First Amendment, which he calls the "traditionalist perspective." The traditionalist ap- proach assumes that different media may use a variety of technologi- cal means of distribution, but it treats these and other distinguishing characteristics as tools of analysis, not as catalysts for a separate con- stitutional standard.

III Common Carriage as a Free Speech Remedy? The authors provide fascinating reading. Some of them clearly know more about than about cable television, but even that distance can be helpful to those too close to the subject mat- ter of media. Their conclusions are varied. Some, like Sunstein, advo- cate considerable regulation in order to protect diverse speech and other values. Others, like Corn-Revere, view that approach as pre- cisely the problem. No summary can synthesize these divergent per-

17. Part of their analysis was originally developed on behalf of the cable firm Tele- Com'munications Inc. (TCI) for submission to the FCC. HASTINGS COMM/ENT L.J. [Vol. 17:1 spectives without overgeneralizing or trivializing. One issue, however, merits additional discussion-common carriage. It is advocated by several of the authors as the solution to assure free speech. Yet their recommendations on the exact nature of such common carriage re- main vague, more in the nature of handwaving than of legal or policy analysis. Given the weight of the common carriage position, at least in the intellectual community, though less in Washington, D.C., it mer- its further discussion. Precursors to common carriage go back to the Roman Empire and to the legal obligations of shipowners, innkeepers, and stable- keepers. In England, early placed certain duties on busi- nesses which were considered "public callings." Common or public occupations included those of bakers, brewers, cab drivers, ferrymen, innkeepers, millers, smiths, surgeons, tailors, and wharfingers. 18 "Common" in that context meant "open to serving the general public." The concept of common carriage crossed the Atlantic and be- came part of the American legal system. Common carriage was broadly applied to railroads and later other transportation as well as telecommunications media. In 1901 the Supreme Court held that at common law-i.e., even without a specific -a telegraph com- pany is a common carrier and owes a duty of non-discrimination. 19 Broadcasters (with the brief exception of an AT&T proposal in the 1920s to serve as a general broadcast service provider under a common carriage obligation) were never common carriers. Cable television, too, was never treated as a common carrier, being viewed at first as essentially a passive antenna system. Cable television com- panies, in providing most of their traditional services, are not consid- ered common carriers.20 The 1992 Cable Act did not change that, though "must-carry" requirements for over-the-air broadcasters, as well as public and leased channels, created some access rights. In the early 1970s, the White House's new Office of Telecommu- nications Policy proposed a common carrier status; however, the idea never got very far. More recently, regulatory proceedings into the na- ture of common carriage for video services were undertaken by the New York Public Service Commission,21 and by the Federal Commu-

18. See CHARLES PHILLIPS, JR., THE REGULATION OF PUBLIC UTILITIES: THEORY AND PRACTICE 83 (2d ed. 1984). 19. Western Union Tel. Co. v. Call Publishing Co., 181 U.S. 92, 98 (1901). 20. 47 U.S.C. § 541(d) (1984). 21. New York State Public Service Commission, Opinion and Order Adopting Regula- tions Concerning Common Carriage, No. 89-C-099 (1990). Proceedings initiated by one of the authors when he served as a Public Service Commissioner for New York State. 19941 THE 1992 CABLE ACT

nications Commission proceeding on video dialtone.22 Recent legisla- tive initiatives23 as well as the Clinton Administration's proposal of a new regulatory category for switched interactive digital broadband (Title VII)24 have pursued the common carrier theme. In 1994, the Clinton Administration proposed the enactment of a new regulatory category (Title VII of the 1934 Communications Act) under which providers of switched interactive digital broadband serv- ices could elect to be regulated under a new system rather than the old.25 This new system would require interconnection, universal ser- vice, payments to local governments, and "open access," a term not specified other than that it would apply to "anyone, including end users and information service providers to transmit information, in- cluding voice, data, and video programming, on a non-discriminatory basis."26 It comes close to common carriage, without using the term. Yet all these policy proceedings are conducted in a partial-equi- librium setting. They fail to take fully into account the system-wide dynamics of interaction, in this case between common carriers and carriers. Those authors in this symposium advocating com- mon carriage fall into the same trap of not recognizing the impact of competition on common carriage. The institution of common carriage, historically the foundation of the way telecommunications are delivered, will not survive in the long term. To clarify, "common carriers" (the misnomer often used to re- fer to telephone companies) will continue to exist, but the status under which they operate-offering service on a non-discriminatory basis, neutral as to use and user-will not.27 This conclusion is reached reluctantly. Common carriage, after all, is of substantial social value. It extends free speech principles to privately-owned carriers. It is an that promotes diver- sity of content services, reduces market forces, promotes interconnec-

22. In re Telephone Company-Cable Television Cross-Ownership Rules, Second Re- port and Order, Recommendation to Congress, and Second Further Notice of Proposed in CC Docket No. 87-266, 7 FCC Rcd. 5781 (1992). 23. National Communications Competition and Information InfrastructureAct of 1993: Hearings on H.R. 3636 Before the Subcomm. on 'Telecommunications and Finance of the House of Representatives Comm. on Energy and Commerce, 103d Cong., 1st Sess. (1993); S. REP. No. 1086, 103d Cong., 1st Sess. (1993); S. REP. No. 1822, 103d Cong., 2d Sess. (1994). 24. Clinton Administration White Paper on Communications Act Reform 5 (issued Jan. 27, 1994), reprinted in 18 DAILY REP. FOR EXECUTIVES (BNA), at M1 (Jan. 28, 1994). 25. Id. 26. Id. 27. For details of the analysis, see Eli Noam, Beyond Liberalization II: The Impending Doom of Common Carriage,TELECOMMUNICATIONS POLICY, Aug. 1994, at 435. HASTINGS COMM/ENT L.J. [Vol. 17:1 tion, encourages competition, assists the universality of infrastructure services, reduces transaction cost, and limits liability. Following the late Ithiel de Sola Pool, the noted MIT political scientist of media, it is often observed that telephone companies oper- ate on common carriage, private publishers follow free speech princi- ples, and broadcasters and cable companies operate on some not entirely free basis since they are licensed and regulated.28 But what happens when the walls separating these realms crumble? The problem for common carriage is not other competing com- mon carriers but private contract carriers without the need to serve everybody on equal terms. In head-to-head competition between a common carrier and a private contract carrier, the former is at an in- herent disadvantage. The reasons are as follows: " A common carrier cannot use differentiated pricing in the same way that a private contract carrier can, due to its non-discrimina- tion obligation and because it cannot prevent arbitrage; " A common carrier must provide service to a contract carrier, but not vice-versa. It must provide its competition with its own low- cost segments, but has no access to those of a rival; " A contract carrier can pick customers and avoid high-risk customers; " A contract carrier can manage the competition among its custom- ers and benefit from it. The conclusion is, therefore, that a contract carrier will be eco- nomically more profitable than a common carrier, essentially because it has more flexibility in setting pricing, service conditions, and choice of customer. It is not likely that the common carriers will simply sit by as their competitors prevail. They will also make a differentiation according to customers, partly based on the argument of "meeting competition." The de-averaging of prices would become standard, and negotiated rates would spread. Any non-trivial differentiation means that some potential users or uses can be excluded. The Clinton Administration's 1994 proposal of Title VII regula- tion was mindful of the asymmetry in regulation between common and private carriers and of the importance of common carriage's open access. It proposed a unified treatment for new switched interactive digital broadband services, but the voluntary nature of this regulation makes this approach meaningless. Contract carriers are unlikely to

28. ITHIEL DE SOLA POOL, TECHNOLOGIES OF FREEDOM (1983). See also ITHIEL DE SOLA POOL, TECHNOLOGIES WITHOUT BOUNDARIES (Eli Noam ed., 1990). 19941 THE 1992 CABLE ACT assume voluntarily the obligations of open access, plus universal ser- vice, mandatory interconnection, and local franchise fees. Could the problem of common carriage's instability under com- petition be resolved by making everyone a common carrier? That would eliminate any competitive disadvantage .relative to private car- riage. It would also radically transform all media, because where would one draw the line? Wherever it is, those inside it would be at a disadvantage to those outside. To be consistent, one would have to include broadcasters, private telephone networks, and even enhanced services! It is incorrect to believe-as many do-that one could sim- ply limit common carriage to the transmission conduit and separate it from "upper level" services. The same pressure of private carriage, in a competitive market, would emerge through resale of transmission service and through systems integration. Their advantage is that, given competition, they pay to transmission carriers a price based only on the latter's short-term marginal costs and can pass this low cost on to their customers. As a result of these advantages, resellers and inte- grators may well emerge in the future as service providers superior to common carriers themselves, even though they use the latter's under- lying transmission facilities. Where two principles-common carriage and private contract carriage-are fundamentally in conflict, it is natural to seek some rec- onciliation. But what can that be? There are several possibilities for a hybrid system. None of them is likely to work for long. We have al- ready shown that if some competitors are common carriers while others are contract carriers, common carriage would lose out. An- other possibility would be to have an "internal hybridization" within carriers themselves. Here, too, the advantages to a firm that resorts to contract carriage will continue to assert themselves, and thus will invariably lead to a process of "creeping self-privatization."29 The conclusion of the analysis is that common carriage will erode in time and that a hybrid co-existence will not be stable. This is not to say that the common carriers qua carriers will become extinct; many of them will remain significant players, but they will conduct their business as contract carriers. Common carriage as such will disappear. This will not happen overnight, of course. Intermediate

29. Still another approach would be common carrier rights of way. A contract carrer would not have to operate as a common carrier, but if it chose to interconnect with or access other networks by taking advantage of common carrier access rights, then it would be required to offer such rights reciprocally on part of its capacity upstream. This system ensures a coexistence of common and private carriage in a static but not dynamic world. Eli Noam, The Superstructure of Infrastructure: Principlesfor a Future Without a Public Network, 13 COMMUNICATIONS & STRATEGIES 109 (1994). HASTINGS COMM/ENT L.J. [Vol. 17:1 can buy several decades of transition time. The basic dynamics, how- ever, will eventually assert themselves. If common carriage is on its way out, what are the implications? In most areas where common carriage is held to be important, market competition would serve as well-in the reduction of market power, promotion of infrastructure, and limited liability. On the other hand, competition is less likely to result in optimal solutions in interconnec- tion and free speech access. A diverse carrier system would have room for a large number of voices. However, the diversity of such voices might be narrower, because private carriers might not want to be identified with certain types of uses and users. Competition will not necessarily resolve this problem since all carriers will be under similar pressures. Take as an example birth control information by a hotline of an abortion clinic. Faced with negative and pres- sure, service providers with discretion in the choice of customer may drop the service as a business decision. It is, of course, likely that "alternative" carriers and systems integrators will emerge to serve such uses. Yet this solves only part of the problem. The need for the various systems to access each other, and for information to travel over numerous interconnected carriers, means that the content restric- tiveness of any one of the participants would require everyone else to institute content and usage tests before they can hand over or accept traffic, or they must agree to the most restrictive principles. Informa- tion travels across numerous subnetworks until it reaches its destina- tion, and one cannot easily tell one bit apart from another bit. If each of these networks and systems integrators sets its own rules about which information is carried and which is not, information would not flow easily or cheaply. The juxtaposition of positive and negatives may give the impres- sion that a policy choice exists. But as has been argued above, once the basic choice has been made, correctly and unavoidably, in favor of competitive and non-compartmentalized transmission media and up- per level services, the eventual unravelling of common carriage is also inevitable. This suggests that new policy instruments will have to be found to deal with the negative effect on information diversity and flow. One way to do so is by replacing the principle of common carriage with a new principle, that of third-party neutral interconnection. A carrier can elect to be private by running its own self-contained infrastructure and having full control over its content, use, and access. But if it inter- connects into other networks and accepts transmission traffic from them, it cannot pick some bits over other bits. While a private carrier 1994] THE 1992 CABLE Acr 15 can be selective in its direct customers, whether they are end-users or content providers, it cannot selectively transmit traffic passed on to it by another interconnected carrier by the latter's own customers, based on content, uses, or usage. This does not require interconnection or transmission on equal terms, as in the case of common carriage, but it establishes the possibility of arbitrage if differentiated pricing occurs. All of common carriage's goals of free-flow, low transaction cost, and no liability goals can thus be preserved, within a competitive system. This new system, and others that will no doubt be proposed, is part of the deregulatory and post-deregulatory agenda. Nostalgia for the tools appropriate to a past media system is no substitute. When the 1992 Cable Act will be reformed-as it inevitably will be-it is necessary to have alternative constructs. One must measure them with a fundamental yardstick, freedom of expression.