Post-Wage Politics and the Rise of Community Capitalism

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Post-Wage Politics and the Rise of Community Capitalism WES0010.1177/0950017018755663Work, employment and societyvan Dyk 755663research-article2018 Article Work, Employment and Society 2018, Vol. 32(3) 528 –545 Post-Wage Politics and © The Author(s) 2018 Reprints and permissions: the Rise of Community sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav https://doi.org/10.1177/0950017018755663DOI: 10.1177/0950017018755663 Capitalism journals.sagepub.com/home/wes Silke van Dyk Friedrich-Schiller-University Jena, Germany Abstract This article discusses new patterns of precariarization and informalization beyond waged labour. Against a backdrop of multiple social changes, there is a new era of social reproduction based on the interplay between a politics of post-waged work and a politics of community, involving activities outside the realms of market, state and family. Whereas the implications of family- based care work have long been highlighted, the community-based political economy of the ‘post- wage regime’ has yet to be analysed. Taking Germany as an example, the article describes how the state is actively involved in promoting and exploiting post-waged work. At the same time, community projects and grassroots activities contribute to the social reproduction of livelihoods, often becoming an active part of the precarious post-wage regime. The question is raised whether or not these interweaving developments herald a new era of community capitalism. Keywords community, conviviality, post-wage politics, precarity, resistance, social reproduction, volunteering Introduction Much has been written about precarious work and job insecurity, with particular atten- tion being paid to the deregulation of waged labour. This article shifts the focus beyond precarious paid employment to look at the governance and practice of non-waged work that contributes to maintaining the public infrastructure and securing livelihoods. There is currently a growing interest in and promotion of voluntary work, neighbourly help, sharing economies, active ageing, multi-generational co-housing projects as caring com- munities, prosumer activities and open-source projects. The argument put forward is Corresponding author: Silke van Dyk, Institute of Sociology, Friedrich-Schiller-University of Jena, Carl-Zeiß-Straße 2, 07743 Jena, Germany. Email: [email protected] van Dyk 529 that, although these activities are highly heterogeneous and seemingly unconnected, they are nonetheless pillars of a new post-waged work regime that ‘tops up’ and in some cases even replaces paid employment. This regime is fuelled by a new politics of community that offers values such as conviviality and voluntariness rather than monetary value in the form of wages. The prevailing view is that community spirit and voluntary activity are noble pursuits; meanwhile, the potential precariousness and the informality of these activities is quietly ignored – as is their systemic role in late modern capitalism. To be sure, neither the importance of non-waged work nor the recourse to community- based ideas is entirely new. However, major socio-economic changes are bringing about a qualitatively new form of precarious post-wage regime. Taking up the Marxist-feminist argument that ‘capital’s lifeblood is unpaid work’, Dowling and Harvie (2014: 882) argue that we are witnessing ‘the attempt to extend the realm of unpaid work that can be appropriated’ (Dowling and Harvie, 2014: 882); yet this realm is itself being restructured by social, technological and demographic forces. Whereas (women’s) care work has increasingly come under critical scrutiny as an unwaged social resource (Daly and Lewis, 2000; Federici, 2012), the political economy of the post-waged work regime beyond private households has yet to be analysed. To explore these issues, this article offers a conceptual framework that brings together apparently unconnected phenomena. It posits the idea that the growing importance of post-waged work is fuelled by the bewildering multiplicity of activities involved and that the common factor underlying these activities is a new politics of community. Contrary to popular debates about the decline of wage labour and the rise of postcapitalism (Mason, 2015; Rifkin, 2014), it is argued that the post-wage regime does not transcend capitalism but instead provides a new basis for value extraction, appropriation and exploitation. Is there a new era of community capitalism on the horizon?1 The argument is developed in several stages.2 First, the socio-economic processes of transformation mentioned above are outlined briefly in order to indicate how they con- tribute to the post-wage regime. This is followed, second, by some general remarks on the appeal of the community concept. Third, the concept of post-waged work is clarified and explicated using examples of post-wage policies from the German context. Fourth, the diverse roots of the nascent post-wage regime are discussed: alongside a state-led politics of post-waged work, there is also a growing grassroots post-wage movement ‘from below’. The article argues that the affirmation of community connects the diverse actors with one another and might be a reason why the problematic implications of post- waged work tend to be overlooked. The article concludes by considering whether com- munity capitalism might develop into a future hegemonic project. Social transformations leading to the rise of post-wage politics Without a doubt, fundamental changes to the welfare state in most industrialized coun- tries are a key to understanding the growing importance of post-waged work. Although country-specific in practice, these changes generally involve a ‘decentralization of social policy’ (Möhle, 2001: 271), a ‘return of social insecurity’ (Castel, 2009: 21) and an ‘imperative to participate’ (Bröckling, 2005: 22). The existence of a social ‘safety net’ 530 Work, Employment and Society 32(3) based on citizens’ rights and a ‘no questions asked’ approach is no longer taken for granted. There has been a transition from state-led provision to greater self-reliance and from collective to individual risk management. The politics of activation and retrench- ment is accompanied by an underfunding of public social infrastructure (Gornig et al., 2015: 1023) along with a state-led deregulation of labour relations, resulting in the rise of precarious work (Castel and Dörre, 2009). There is a wealth of literature on welfare state change based on activation and auster- ity that links these shifts to the revival of informal, community-building mutual support and voluntary work as a gap filler (e.g. Lessenich, 2008; Milligan and Conradson, 2011; Muehlebach, 2012). However, the heterogeneity of post-waged work is rarely addressed, and many authors identify welfare state retrenchment as the driving force behind com- munity governance. Current social transformations are far more multi-layered than this suggests, though. For one thing, fundamental changes are underway in gender relations, with more and more women entering the labour market. As a result, the amount of time available to them to serve as a full-time, unpaid ‘secret resource of social policy’ (Beck- Gernsheim, 1991: 66, author’s translation) is significantly reduced; as empirical research shows, men do not step in to fill the gap (Koppetsch and Speck, 2015). However, the true extent of the crisis of social reproduction (Jürgens, 2010) only comes to light if demographic changes are addressed concurrently. Of course, the wide- spread notion of an ‘old age crisis’ (World Bank, 1994) is problematic, since it suggests a naturalized crisis rooted in old age itself and not in the socio-economic conditions of the ageing society. However, in Germany, for example, about 3.4 million elderly people are dependent on care while there is an estimated shortfall of 500,000 professional care workers (Haubner, 2017; Prognos, 2012). Even considering such dramatic changes, the picture of the emerging post-wage regime is still not complete: current post-wage prac- tices are further fuelled by technological change, first and foremost by digitization and new virtual networks and communities. The ‘internet of things’ (Rifkin, 2014) increas- ingly connects everything and everyone, relying on diverse forms of non-waged activi- ties. Users establish self-help and counselling networks, they act as prosumers and share information to improve goods and services, they offer music, cars and flats on internet platforms, and they share knowledge. Although there is disagreement over which of these activities should count as labour and which as social interaction (Terranova, 2000), Srnicek convincingly identifies data as the raw material of the digitized economy ‘and the activities of users [as] the natural source of this raw material’ (Srnicek, 2017: 40, emphasis in original).3 Finally, and importantly, the economic crises from 2008 onwards are proving to be a threat to the hegemony of neoliberal capitalism, creating a new context for the political economy of post-waged work and community politics. These multiple crises, accompa- nied by ‘the alchemy of austerity’ (Clarke and Newman, 2012: 299), have aggravated social inequalities and divisions. Even though Crouch (2011) rightly identified ‘the strange non-death of neoliberalism’ immediately after the crisis erupted and even though there is ample evidence of the ongoing influence of neoliberal ideas and politics (Bischoff and Steinitz, 2016: 67f.; Schmidt and Thatcher, 2013), the system’s hegemony has come to be contested. Social protests around the world (Sitrin
Recommended publications
  • The Community As Entrepreneurial Firm: Common Property Capitalism in Mexican Forest Communities Creates Jobs, Competes in Global Markets, and Conserves Biodiversity
    The Community as Entrepreneurial Firm: Common Property Capitalism in Mexican Forest Communities Creates Jobs, Competes in Global Markets, and Conserves Biodiversity Professor David Barton Bray This article was published previously by Americas Quarterly on February 15, 2010 The Community as an Entrepreneurial Firm 2 Imagine a business with a 384-member board of directors that governs using organizational principles predating the rise of modern capitalism. Imagine as well that this business has a 20-member executive committee that includes the town mechanic and newspaper vendor, and whose monthly meetings can last three days. The business also changes its CEO and other officers every three years, regardless of whether they have done a good job. Sound impractical? In fact, such an enterprise has transformed hundreds of poor Mexican Zapotec indigenous farmers into owners of a multi-million dollar diversified forest industry. A sign posted at the entrance to the enterprise offices sums up its character succinctly: “In this community private property does not exist. The buying and selling of communal lands is prohibited,” The Forest, Agriculture, and Services Communal Enterprise” of Ixtlán de Juarez, a forest community in the Sierra Norte of Oaxaca, an hour north of the city of Oaxaca, evolved from traditional forms of governance developed by the Zapotec ancestors of the people of Ixtlán that were later reinforced with agrarian governance structures mandated by the Mexican government. The structures were designed to run community affairs, not businesses. Nevertheless, Ixtlán, along with many other forest communities in that region of Mexico, have successfully fused communal democratic traditions with the principles of competitive market enterprises to achieve economic equity.
    [Show full text]
  • Black Economic Development As a Strategy for Community Development
    BLACK ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AS A STRATEGY FOR COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT by SUSAN STARZYNSKI YOUNG B.A., Chatham College (1962) M.A., Syracuse University (1964) SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF CITY PLANNING at the MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY September, 1969 . Signature of Author .... .... *... .. .. .. Department of Urban Studies and Planning Certified by thsis Supervisor I Accepted by . P a .. ... DepartmentaloChairman, Committee on Graduate Students Room 14-0551 77 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02139 Ph: 617.253.2800 MITLib ries Email: [email protected] Document Services http://Iibraries.mit.edu/docs DISCLAIM ER Page has been ommitted due to a pagination error by the author. ( Page 16 ) 2. ABSTRACT Title: Black Economic Development as a Strategy for Community Development Author: Susan Starzynski Young Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning in partial fulfillment of the requirement for the degree of Master of City Planning. Discussion on the current attempts to increase black economic development reveal widely divergent views on the direction the development is expected to take. One view holds that it will lead to a separatist black economy, while another holds that it will produce greater integration. It is anti- cipated both that traditional capitalistic structures and communal structures will be the dominant form of organization. It predicts that development will be large scale and dominated by large corporations and also that it will be insignificant and petty. The future of black communities will, in part, be shaped by the direction economic development takes, especially as goals being established by ghetto political leaders could either be fostered or destroyed by the path economic development takes.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 27 Sociology 621 April 30, 2008 What Is Socialism?
    Lecture 27 Sociology 621 April 30, 2008 What is Socialism? I. What Do Socialists Want? Socialists have traditionally criticized capitalism for the ways in which it violates five central values: 1. Equality: Capitalism generates morally intolerable levels of inequality of material conditions of people. This is especially offensive in its impact on children, but more broadly the levels of material deprivation in a world of affluence generated by capitalism violates a wide range of principles of egalitarian justice held by socialists. 2. Democracy: Capitalism thwarts democracy. By placing the basic economic resources and conditions of investment in hands of private individuals, the capacity of the democratic polity to make decisions about the fate of the community is significantly undermined. 3. Autonomy: Capitalism robs most people of meaningful control over much of their work lives. There is a deep meaning-deficit in most people’s lives because they are pawns in other people’s projects. Capitalism does not merely generate inequality and poverty through exploitation, it generates alienation as well. 4. Community: Capitalism undermines a sense of solidarity among people. As G.A. Cohen has argued, the forms of competition and conflict built into capitalism drive economic activities primarily on the basis of two motives -- greed and fear. Instead of social interaction in economic life being normatively organized around the principle of helping others, it is organized primarily around motive of taking advantage of the weakness of others for one's own gain. This underwrites a culture of selfish individualism and atomism. 5. Efficiency/rationality: This may seem quite odd, but traditionally socialists have criticized capitalism because it was irrational, wasteful and ultimately inefficient.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Food Insecurity in East Asia
    Rice, politics and power: the political economy of food insecurity in East Asia Paul Belesky Master of International Studies (International Relations) The University of Queensland A thesis submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy The University of Queensland, 2016 School of Political Science and International Studies School of Social Science Abstract This thesis has three main objectives: (1) to provide a critical political economy study of the complex interplay between rice, politics and power in East Asia; (2) to make a contribution to understanding the evolution of the regional and global food system through an historically-contextualised exploration of the political economy of rice in the East Asian region; and (3) to make a contribution towards an alternative analytical framework for the political economy of food insecurity in the region. This study focuses on the agricultural commodity of rice as a prism through which to examine and explore the complex and multidimensional nature of food insecurity in the region, with rice providing a lens through which to explore social relations and relations of power that underpin the political economy of food and agriculture. This study has identified a gap in literature in relation to a contemporary analysis of the political economy of rice, with a second gap appearing in relation to the evolution of the global food system from an East Asian perspective. This thesis aims to make a contribution towards addressing these gaps in literature. With these objectives in mind, this thesis responds
    [Show full text]
  • Technobureaucratic Capitalism
    Luiz Carlos Bresser-Pereira TECHNOBUREAUCRATIC CAPITALISM São Paulo, 1990 2004 Introductory Note This book began with the translation, by Marcia Van Dyke, of my book A Sociedade Estatal e a Tecnoburocracia (São Paulo, Editora Brasiliense, 1981). A first version of it was submitted in 1983 to Cambridge University Press. After several months, the editor showed interest in the publication of the book, provided that I introduced major changes. Yet, in the meantime, I was called to political life, and was unable to make the required changes. In December 1987 I returned to academic life, and, after some time, reworked the originals, introducing the initial discussion of the state, and revising several parts, so as to become an integrated book instead of a collection of essays. This 1990 version was sent back to Cambridge University Press, but at that time they had lost the interest. This version was completed in mid 1990, when the collapse of Soviet Union was under way. It already acknowledged the breakdown of communism, but the disinterest of the publishing house let clear to me that more changes were required if I really wanted to publish the book in English. For years the ‘manuscript’ remained in my archives in digital form. Finally, in 2004, when I returned to the theme of this book by writing the paper “The Strategic Factor of Production in Technicians’ Capitalism” to be presented to the ‘John Kenneth Galbraith International Symposium’, to be held in Paris, September 23-25, I ‘rediscovered’ Technobureaucratic Capitalism. Since I have no short term plan of reworking the book¸ I decided to publish it in my web page in the original form.
    [Show full text]
  • Economies of Violence and Governable Spaces in the Niger Delta, Nigeria
    Sed Com 05 11/18/05 9:55 AM Page 101 5 The Sinister Political Life of Community Economies of Violence and Governable Spaces in the Niger Delta, Nigeria Michael Watts We seek to recover the…life of the community, as neither the “before” nor the “after” picture of any great human transformation.…We see “commu- nities” as creatures with an extraordinary and actually…quite sinister polit- ical life in the ground of real history. Kelly and Kaplan (2001:199) Community is an archetypal “keyword” in the sense deployed by Raymond Williams (1976). A “binding” word, suturing certain activities and their interpretation, community is also “indicative” (Williams’s term once again) in certain forms of thought. Deployed in the lan- guage for at least five hundred years, the word community has carried a range of senses denoting actual groups (for example, “commoners” or “workers”) and connoting specific qualities of social relationship (as in communitas). By the nineteenth century, community was, of course, invoked as a way of talking about much larger issues, about modernity itself. Community—and its sister concepts of tradition and custom— now stood in sharp contrast to the more abstract, instrumental, individ- uated, and formal properties of state or society in the modern sense. A related shift in usage subsequently occurred in the twentieth century, when community came to refer to a form or style of politics distinct from the formal repertoires of national or local politics. Here the ref- erence was direct politics, community participation and organization, often but not always populist in orientation, typically working with and 101 Sed Com 05 11/18/05 9:55 AM Page 102 Michael Wat ts for “the people.” At this historical moment we are awash in communi- ties of this kind; in fact the “self-governing community” is one of the defining formulations of neoliberal rule (Schofield 2002).
    [Show full text]
  • CID Working Paper No. 043 :: Economic Reforms And
    Economic Reforms and Constitutional Transition The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Sachs, Jeffrey D., Wing Thye Woo, and Xiaokai Yang. “Economic Reforms and Constitutional Transition.” CID Working Paper Series 2000.43, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, April 2000. Published Version https://www.hks.harvard.edu/centers/cid/publications Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:39525803 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA Economic Reforms and Constitutional Transition Jeffrey D. Sachs, Wing Thye Woo and Xiaokai Yang CID Working Paper No. 43 April 2000 Copyright 2000 Jeffrey D. Sachs, Wing Thye Woo and Xiaokai Yang and the President and Fellows of Harvard College Working Papers Center for International Development at Harvard University Economic Reforms and Constitutional Transition Jeffrey Sachs, Wing Thye Woo and Xiaokai Yang Abstract This paper investigates the relationship between economic reforms and constitutional transition, which has been neglected by many transition economists. It is argued that assessment of reform performance might be very misleading if it is not recognized that economic reforms are just a small part of large scale of constitutional transition. Rivalry and competition between states and between political forces within each country are the driving forces for constitutional transition. We use Russia as an example of economic reforms associated with constitutional transition and China as an example of economic reforms in the absence of constitutional transition to examine features and problems in the two patterns of transition.
    [Show full text]
  • Colorado: Learn, Live, Grow, and Embrace Community Capitalism
    UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO BOULDER LEEDS SCHOOL OF BUSINESS IN THIS ISSUE PAGE 1 Colorado: Learn, Live, Grow PAGE 2 Colorado Employment Will Continue PAGE 4 CEOs Discuss State’s Workforce PAGE 6 New Employment Issues PAGE 8 Making Sense of Commodities A publication of the Business Research Division Prices Volume 82, Number 1, 2016 PAGE 10 Colorado Real Estate Forum Keynote Address Colorado: Learn, Live, Grow, and Embrace Community Capitalism Jackson Rueter to do business. In 2009, DaVita announced audience of around 900. He detailed four it was moving its headquarters from El keys to successful talent strategy for the Colorado is in the midst of record Segundo, California, to Denver because of state: be a differentiated place to learn, be state in-migration and an economic boom. the state’s economic potential, as well as a differentiated place to live, be a differenti- Cultivating and attracting the right people is Denver’s central location and high quality of ated place to grow, and embrace community essential to effective talent management and life. In his keynote address at the 51st annual capitalism. strategy. This will help the state to continue Colorado Business Economic Outlook to grow its highly educated workforce and Forum, Thiry highlighted the importance Place to Learn remain an economic leader. of talent strategy in Colorado and its role Thiry began his discussion of education Kent Thiry, chairman and CEO of going forward. “The good thing about tal- in Colorado by saying, “Education is every- DaVita HealthCare Partners, believes that ent strategy is that all you have to do is be one’s issue,” noting that the future of the Colorado’s vibrant economy is a great place better than the other guy,” said Thiry to an nation will be determined in the classroom.
    [Show full text]
  • Jim Crow Credit Mehrsa Baradaran
    UC Irvine Law Review Volume 9 | Issue 4 Article 4 5-2019 Jim Crow Credit Mehrsa Baradaran Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.uci.edu/ucilr Part of the Banking and Finance Law Commons, and the Civil Rights and Discrimination Commons Recommended Citation Mehrsa Baradaran, Jim Crow Credit, 9 U.C. Irvine L. Rev. 887 (2019). Available at: https://scholarship.law.uci.edu/ucilr/vol9/iss4/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by UCI Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in UC Irvine Law Review by an authorized editor of UCI Law Scholarly Commons. Final to Printer_Baradaran (Do Not Delete) 6/13/2019 10:46 PM Jim Crow Credit Mehrsa Baradaran The New Deal for White America ............................................................................... 888 The Transformation of Consumer Credit ................................................................... 894 Title I of the National Housing Act of 1934 ................................................. 894 Changes to Banking Regulation ....................................................................... 900 Civil Rights Protests Against Credit Markets ................................................ 901 The Poor Pay More ......................................................................................................... 907 Black Capitalism .............................................................................................................. 9 1 7 Two Policies for Two Americas: The Community Reinvestment Act and
    [Show full text]
  • Entrepreneurs As Social Actors: Privatization and Social Change in China and Vietnam
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Heberer, Thomas Working Paper Entrepreneurs as social actors: Privatization and social change in China and Vietnam Duisburg Working Papers on East Asian Studies, No. 21/1999 Provided in Cooperation with: University of Duisburg-Essen, Institute of East Asian Studies IN-EAST Suggested Citation: Heberer, Thomas (1999) : Entrepreneurs as social actors: Privatization and social change in China and Vietnam, Duisburg Working Papers on East Asian Studies, No. 21/1999, Gerhard-Mercator-Universität Duisburg, Institut für Ostasienwissenschaften, Duisburg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/41015 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu DUISBURGER ARBEITSPAPIERE OSTASIENWISSENSCHAFTEN DUISBURG WORKING PAPERS ON EAST ASIAN STUDIES No.
    [Show full text]
  • Dissecting China's Rise: Controversies Over the China Model
    China Perspectives 2014/2 | 2014 Contested Urban Spaces Dissecting China’s Rise: Controversies over the China Model Xiaoshuo Hou Electronic version URL: http://journals.openedition.org/chinaperspectives/6484 DOI: 10.4000/chinaperspectives.6484 ISSN: 1996-4617 Publisher Centre d'étude français sur la Chine contemporaine Printed version Date of publication: 1 June 2014 Number of pages: 61-67 ISSN: 2070-3449 Electronic reference Xiaoshuo Hou, « Dissecting China’s Rise: Controversies over the China Model », China Perspectives [Online], 2014/2 | 2014, Online since 01 January 2017, connection on 28 October 2019. URL : http:// journals.openedition.org/chinaperspectives/6484 ; DOI : 10.4000/chinaperspectives.6484 © All rights reserved Article China perspectives Dissecting China’s Rise: Controversies over the China Model XIAOSHUO HOU ABSTRACT: The recent discussion of a “Beijing Consensus” and a China model seems to challenge neoliberalism as the dominating dis - course on development. This paper attempts to explain the contradictions in China’s development and discusses whether and how they can be redressed. Specifically, the paper analyses the key issues around the debate over the China model – how distinctive it is and whether it can be replicated elsewhere, and what real lessons can be drawn from China’s rise. It proposes a more nuanced view of the economic, social, and political structures in China with a focus on its mixed economy, the role of the state at both the central and local levels, and the possibility of Chinese-style democracy. It also offers suggestions for improving the China model. KEYWORDS: development, Beijing Consensus, China model, China’s rise, neoliberalism. hina’s increasing rise in the world is often juxtaposed against its bumpy road for many developing countries (e.g., in Latin America and sub- mounting domestic problems.
    [Show full text]
  • THE MORAL CASE for CAPITALISM James R
    M I MANHATTAN INSTITUTE FOR POLICY RESEARCH 2012 2012 SSUES SSUES I I AN AUDACIOUS PROMISE: No. 12 May 2012 THE MORAL CASE FOR CAPITALISM James R. Otteson “The market will take care of everything,” they tell us…. But here’s the problem: it doesn’t work. It has never worked. It didn’t work when it was tried in the decade before the Great Depression. It’s not what led to the incredible postwar booms of the ’50s and ’60s. And it didn’t work when we tried it during the last decade. I mean, understand, it’s not as if we haven’t tried this theory. —President Barack Obama, Osawatomie, Kansas, December 6, 2011 Milton Friedman once said that every time capitalism has been tried, it has succeeded; whereas every time socialism has been tried, it has failed. Yet President Obama has oddly claimed that we’ve tried free-market capi- talism, and it “has never worked.” This is rather remarkable. Since 1800, the world’s population has increased sixfold; yet despite this enormous increase, real income per person has increased approximately 16-fold. That is a truly amazing achievement. In America, the increase is even more dramatic: in 1800, the total population in America was 5.3 million, life expectancy was 39, and the real gross domestic product per capita was $1,343 (in 2010 dollars); in 2011, our population was 308 million, our life expectancy was 78, and our GDP per capita was $48,800. Thus even while the population increased 58-fold, our life expectancy doubled, and our GDP per capita increased almost 36-fold.
    [Show full text]