<<

The Origins of Divergence: , , and the Future of Development

Max Ajl*

Scholarshave asked, why is China poor? Why is Europe rich? Indeed, those questions

launched thousands of research projects looking into the lineages of Chinese destitu- tion and European opulence in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries.I For decades the standard scholarly explanation was the one advanced: only in the West did ratio- nalization, understood as the clear and premeditated pursuit of delineated objectives on the basis of self-conscious calculation and selection procedures, combine with an ascetic system to lead to sustained and self-sustaining growth.2 More recent work has undermined the empirical foundations of this claim. There is plenty of evidence of rational thought, defined in Weber's terms, in second millennium China. Furthermore, explaining tremendous processes of historical evolution of political economies through resort to "," essentially concluding that European industrialization was a product of European and its antecedents in the philosophy and knowledge of antiquity, hardly suffices to explain the available evidence. Furthermore, as Chinese industrialization proceeds apace, with a swelling middle class and a burgeoning emissions profile, those age-old assumptions about Chinese backwardness

Student of development sociology at Cornell University. Thanks to Philip McMichael for discussion. See e.g. Perry Anderson, Lineages ofthe Absolutist State (: Verso, 1979) at 401ff. 2 Max Weber, Economy and Society: An Outline ofInterpretativeSociology, ed by Guenther Roth & Claus Wittich (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1978) vol 1 & 2 [Weber, Economy and Society]; Max Weber, The ProtestantEthic and the Spirit of , translated by Talcott Parsons (London: Allen & Unwin, 1930) [Weber, The ProtestantEthic]. Mark Elvin, "Why China Failed to Create an Endogenous Industrial Capitalism: A Critique of Max Weber's Explanation" (1984) 13 Theory and Society 379 at 379-82. 144 JSDLP - RDPDD AJL hold even less sway. In Before and Beyond Divergence, Rosenthal and Wong's examination of the trajectories and prevalent at the far ends of the Eurasian land mass provides critical information for understanding the Chinese and European pasts, the present, and also their futures. Of course, as both empirical processes of development as well as knowledge about the Chinese past and present has accumulated, the assumptions that condition how research ques- tions get formulated have shifted. It has become increasingly clear that China used to not be so poor relative to Europe, while European affluence is a recent historical phenomenon, or at least, more recent than earlier Eurocentric accounts had posited. As demographic-statistical studies have shown with mounting force, the great divergence in living standards between the two ends of Eurasia may be of fairly recent provenance-perhaps, some argue, as late as 1850.6 But the precise moment when living standards started to diverge is a secondary issue. More significant is the ongoing process of revising the petrified orthodoxy created by past scholar- ship: China as a despotic Oriental state mired in backwardness, Europe as an industrial, mod- ernizing continent. As the picture has become clearer, it has become evident that the question of the social origins of industrialization is central to explaining modern Western wealth. It is to the debate about the provenance of European industrialization and China's relative lack of industry-the separate trajectories the two ends of Eurasian ended up taking-that Rosenthal and Wong contribute in Before andBeyond Divergence. Put differently, why was it that modern industrial growth was more likely to take place in the Occidental end of Eurasia? What was it about the specific socioeconomic configuration in Europe that made it the first in the world to experience an ? It is to that question that Wong and Rosenthal turn. They do not dispute the quotidian notion that the Euro-Atlantic world was the first place on the globe to experience modern -that is, to break through Malthusian limitations. What they do dispute are the the- ories that have been used to explain that fact, since revisionist scholarship has increasingly eroded some of the claims such theories were built upon, especially the foundational notion of European economic . Furthermore, as provocations like 's ReOrient and Giovanni Arrighi's in Beijing have argued, the rise of the Euro-Atlantic world to economic preemi- nence may well prove to be an evanescent phenomenon, as the world's center of economic gravity returns to its traditional equilibrium somewhere between the trading system traditionally traversed by commodity chains connecting the various coastal entrep6ts, and the vast landed trading system of China, the historical repository of the world's population,

Jean-Laurent Rosenthal & R Bin Wong, Before andBeyond Divergence: The Politics ofEconomic Changein China andEurope (Cambridge: Press, 2011). 5 See e.g. , The Structures of Everyday Lif: The Limits of the Possible, vol 1 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1981) at 102, 362. 6 Kenneth Pomeranz, " and Ecology on the Eve of Industrialization: Europe, China, and the Global Conjuncture" (2002) 107 American Historical Review 425 at 428ff. 7 See e.g. Anderson, supra note 1; Weber, The ProtestantEthic, supra note 2; Weber, Economy and Society, supra note 2; Braudel, The Structures ofEveryday Lft, supra note 5. AJL Volume 8: Issue 1 145 and thus unshockingly most of its material wealth. Indeed, it is hardly heterodox anymore to point out that the European trading system was for a long time relatively peripheral to the world trading system in terms of net flows.' And as development slowly begins to catch up with the weight of demographic mass, there are strong possibilities for a partial decentering of the economies sitting on either side of the Atlantic. Of course, later scholarship has toned down initial and overreaching claims.10 China has always had a huge chunk of the world's population. In preindustrial economies, most wealth comes from the land. Since the of land in noncapital intensive can only go so high, one would expect a very rough correlation between a countrys wealth and its population in a preindustrial era. Indeed, before industrialization it would have been unrea- sonable to expect sharp divergences in income or productivity in the most fecund and devel- oped of the world. And in any case, in many regions of China, towards the latter part of the second millennium income and productivity-per-worker in the agricultural sector were filly on par with those in Europe-in some places, perhaps exceeding them." However, many are understandably chary of explanations that go beyond demolishing Eurocentric tropes and substitute Sinocentric tropes in their place, or overemphasize the simi- larities between the two ends of Eurasia: Europe and China. As Peer Vries argues, "[t] he more 'Eurasian' resemblances and equivalents are brought into prominence, the more miraculous if not downright inexplicable becomes the enormous gap that emerged during the nineteenth century between Britain and China. How can situations that are surprisingly similar produce such huge differences?" 1 2 The search must be for some factor that made Europe and China dif- ferent from one another-the Industrial Revolution did not come from nowhere. Part of Wong and Rosenthal's method is intellectual demolition, the better to lay the ground of their own theory. Thus, they take aim not merely at what they consider myopically Eurocentric explanations like Douglas North's institutionalism, which moves briskly from the description of European institutions to the theoretical inference that such institutions were the only ones necessary for modern growth.1 They also take issue with Kenneth Pomeranz's seminal The Great Divergence, which focused on the propinquity for British development of seams located close to British industrial centers as well as a colonizing tendency which was able to overcome the equilibrium trap that would have been entailed by the land squeeze." Rosenthal and Wong do not discard such explanations, suggesting that they may well have

8 Andre Gunder Frank, ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998); Giovanni Arrighi, Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the Twenty-First Century (London: Verso, 2007). 9 Janet L Abu-Lughod, Before European : The World System A.D. 1250-1350 (New York: , 1989). 10 Peer Vries, "Are Coal and Really Crucial? Kenneth Pomeranz and the Great Divergence" (2005) 12 Journal of World History 407. Peer Vries, "The California School and Beyond: How to Study the Great Divergence?" (2010) 8 History Compass 730. 12 Ibid at 736-37. 13 Rosenthal and Wong, supra note 4. 14 Kenneth Pomeranz, The GreatDivergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000). 146 JSDLP - RDPDD AJL facilitated modern European growth. Indeed, total net primary production necessarily imposes its own limits on growth. matter, and being able to burn wood from elsewhere or use the stored energy of the past in the form of coal is a boon to development. For example, Rolf Sieferle argues that the British industrial revolution hinged on this bio-energetic boost." Yet Wong and Rosenthal show that such explanations are not sufficient to account for the directions chosen by Europe as opposed to those chosen by China. As they write, "dif- ferences in relative factor in China and Europe set in motion incentives to save on labor and invest in capital that figure prominently in Pomeranzs account"."6 They argue that the explanation for why the Chinese development path went one way while the European path wended another was not so much the palette of institutions from which European and Chinese merchants and industrialists chose as the larger framework within which they made their choices. Their core thesis is that the continental scale of the Chinese polity encouraged social peace, thereby sidestepping pressures to place artisans behind the bulwark of city walls or to use machines to economize on expensive labor, thereby encouraging more labor intensive development.17 In Europe, fissiparous political tendencies encouraged by-and which in turn fostered-warfare made capital cheaper relative to labor, accelerated its agglomeration in urban formations, pushed along urban , and impelled an elevated rate of capital invest- ment as well as the adoption of machinery in lieu of labor in ever-increasing areas of Europe. Labor also was expensive for reasons unmentioned by Wong and Rosenthal-in the pre- modern era, without adequate sanitation systems, cities tended to kill their inhabitants. Plague was endemic, and cities needed constant migration from the countryside merely to maintain their populations." In that sense, urbanization and the industrialization for which it was a cru- cible had a parasitic relationship with the countryside, drawing on its resources and its people while only much later being able to share the fruits of industrial progress with the population in the form of "development." Much of the book is taken up with dispelling common claims that seek to account for the divergence between Europe and China. For example, they note that it is regularly asserted that the relative predominance of formal institutions to deal with economic transactions and adjudicate economic infractions in Europe explains Europe's advancement vis-i-vis China." But Wong and Rosenthal attribute this difference to the scale of : there was, relatively speaking, more long-distance trade in continent-scale China, a consequence of peace that was in turn the consequence of political consolidation. Local courts were far less effective in adju- dicating such transactions than the security ensured by sprawling trading networks. Thus the Chinese for informal institutions comes to look less like a matter of mores and more of a question of simple efficiency. When Europeans engaged in long-distance trade they too opted for informal networks. Thus Rosenthal and Wong reverse the causal chain: bellicosity led

15 Rolf Peter Sieferle, The Subterranean Forest: Energy Systems and the IndustrialRevolution, translated by Michael P Osman (Cambridge: The White Horse Press, 2001). 16 Rosenthal and Wong, supra note 4 at 7.

17 Ibid at 33, 101-28. 18 Fernand Braudel, The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip II (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995) at 332-34. 19 Rosenthal and Wong, supra note 4 at 67-98. AJL Volume 8: Issue 1 147 to less long-distance trade, with the ratios of formal and informal institutions being effects of the ratios of long- versus short-distance trade. 20 Furthermore, we then see at the fringes of their arguments hints of why China and Chinese products for so long dominated the long-distance trading routes which composed the world-system before European dominance. They also discuss political scale: how China came to be a unified political entity whereas Europe came to be a divided one.21 That was a matter of history. There was nothing endemic to the Western end of Eurasia that made it inevitable that Europe be made up of a fractured set of states. The at its peak covered much of the Occident. In the past, China was a political mosaic rather than united. It was the evolution of China into a unified political entity that encouraged certain institutional choices. Pace Western social theories' rendering of China as developmentally stalled, they argue that China's expanse actually contributed to its develop- ment by enabling peaceful growth within the confines of a large state with secure borders.22 Eventually, gains from the relative lack of violence redounded to the benefit of Chinese development. Because the social surplus did not need to be diverted to building fortifications and buying weapons, the costs of maintaining order were relatively low, and the central state made local rulers shoulder much of the burden of constructing the institutional scaffolding for economic growth. This allowed for relatively low tax rates, thereby keeping in check separatist tendencies and allowing a central ruler to work in concert with the population and local poten- tates to maintain social order. With no political need to place manufacturing or population in cities, Chinese urbanization rates were extremely low. Cities accounted for no more than five percent of Chinas total population in 1850-less than they had in 1250.23 Meanwhile, a politically shattered Europe was developing methods of war that were increasingly capital-intense, encouraging the construction of expensive fortifications and investments in costly artillery. Like a homeostatic pressure system, the European states, amidst constant warfare, pushed against each others' borders with only some success. Were one to verge on overweening power a concert of others would soon gather against them. Continental- size political units did not appear. But when shouldering up against less martially oriented political economies, the militarized European states were able to expand and then engorge others' commodity circuits.' It was precisely this tendency which led the European empires to take over Asian trading systems in the nineteenth century, using violence to break into their markets and later, forcing them to deindustrialize and then penetrating internal markets with European manufactures, a point Wong and Rosenthal touch on only obliquely when they mention the impossibility of considering the two political units in isolation after 1850. Here the European legacy of violent state formation would have its effect on the larger world-system, with the colonial legacy as the unpredictable consequence of European political fragmentation and the violence with which it was ineluctably bound.

20 Aid at 95-96. 21 Iid at 12-34. 22 Iid at 182, 189, 205. 23 Iid at 111. 24 Giovanni Arrighi et al, "Historical Capitalism, East and West" in Giovanni Arrighi, Takeshi Hamashita & Mark Selden, eds, The Resurgence ofEast : 500, 150 and 50 Year Perspectives (London: Routledge, 2003) 259. 148 JSDLP - RDPDD AJL But no one could have predicted such connections between industrialization and violence. For China, the lack of war meant manufacturing could remain in cheap locations in the coun- tryside, thereby giving it cost advantages, as the ready availability of labor drove down its costs. Manufacturers made the sensible and rational choice of locating their workshops in the lower Yangtzi valley, close to river transport routes. In Europe manufacturing had to cluster behind the protective carapace of city walls, where labor was scarcer and dearer. The European warfare system was certainly not intended to create a menu of choices from which European indus- trialists would choose to locate their factories and workshops behind city walls. However, this was the dynamic it unintentionally facilitated, eventually setting in motion modern economic growth, the consequence of ruinous warfare which diverted the social surplus into the produc- tion of waste as well as the wasting of other societies. The unintended consequence was what we have come to call "development," although this term only came to denote enhanced living standards for the working classes in the Euro-Atlantic world after sustained social struggle from Europe's popular classes, who had to make demands on industrialists and merchants in order to receive a larger share of their countries' wealth.25 Wong and Rosenthal's emphasis that this was wholly unintended provides a brisk tonic to too many Eurocentric exceptionalist narra- tives, which posit European industrialism as reflecting some kind of autochthonous industri- ousness or idiosyncratic cultural intelligence. The authors could have dwelled more on how these war-making tendencies have been institutionalized in the Atlantic economic units, especially as the center of Western industrial and financial power has passed from on to the . 26 This question is central to understanding the last sixty years of . The accidental synergies between industrialization and war-making have taken on a markedly different form in the modern age, with much industrial production, especially of arms, essentially severed from productive developmental processes. In the Chinese model, despite its many flaws, there is no counterpart to the Western diversion of massive productive resources from social uses to warfare-in some senses an "advantage" of Chinese "backwardness." Other questions, too, remain unsettled, not least those raised by the issue of industrializa- tion. The authors surmise that by 2050 it is likely that China will strongly resemble Europe. Putting aside the probably insuperable ecological difficulties entailed by a Chinese reprise of the carbon-fueled European takeoff, lurking behind this observation is what seems like a nor- mative preference for a heavily industrialized society. But it is unclear how and why it would benefit the Chinese people to separate peasants from their land to the same extent as occurred in Europe. Similar policies in the Soviet Union did next to nothing to enhance overall social welfare, although heavy industrialization-as opposed to light industrialization-could not have proceeded apace without the sundering of links between peasants and the land.2 That process's premise should be questioned: do people in fact benefit from heavy industrialization? There is little evidence in favor of that proposition.

25 Sandra Halperin, "Re-envisioning Global Development: Conceptual and Methodological Issues" (2007) 4 Globalizations 543. 26 Giovanni Arrighi, The Long Twentieth Century: Power, and the Origins of our Time (New York: Verso, 2010). 27 Colin A.M. Duncan, "On Rapid Industrialization and Collectivization: An Essay in Historiographic Retrieval and Criticism" (1986) 21 Studies in Political Economy 137. AJL Volume 8: Issue 1 149 Furthermore, there is no question that if China proceeds on its current trajectory, it will more closely resemble Europe than it does now. But for those interested in questions of human development, this sidesteps the normative question of whether China should seek to emulate the European development path or whether it might seek to improve upon it. Even within the framework of heavy industrialization, there are choices to be made: uses far less energy per unit of gross domestic product than does Europe, let alone the United States. But the question of whether capital should be invested in heavy as opposed to light industrialization remains unasked. This is odd because at least one of the conclusions to be drawn from their book is that warfare was one of the core processes setting in motion the process of heavy indus- trialization. Human progress was an incidental rather than integral outcome. Still, Rosenthal and Wong leave us much to think with, through, and about. The authors' social science theory building is meticulous, and they are very circumspect in describing what their model does and does not do. Many will bridle at some of the details, but there seems little question that the book is one of the more stimulating and ambitious attempts to rethink the provenances of Eurasian political economies in some time. This book is a major achievement, and it deserves the widest audience.