Homophily in Social Networks and Labor Market Outcomes

Emmanuel Valat1 Université Panthéon-Assas Paris II & ESSEC Business School

Version: April 2010

We develop a labor matching model where about vacant jobs is partly obtained through contacts. From this framework we study the correlation between some charateristics of the structure of social networks and labor market outcomes. Workers are embeded in di¤erent network structures according to their type -or origin. Following recent theoretical and empirical …ndings, we consider that two characteristics of network composition are endogenous for each type: homophily -the tendency to associate with individuals of the same type- and network size. These two characteristics are a¤ected by changes in three key elements, the relative size of each group in the population, average preferences for same-type ties and in meetings. Our numerical simulations suggest a positive relation between network size and labor market outcomes, which is in line with the literature. Simulations however suggest something less expected, a positive correlation between homophily and labor market outcomes for members of the minority group. The relation is reversed for the majority group. We discuss conditions and explainations for this correlation. We furthermore notice that the way the three key elements we mentioned above a¤ect labor market outcomes for each group is in line with the growing empirical literature on the subject.

Key Words: Social Networks, Information Transmission, Homophily, Unemploy- ment. JEL Classi…cation: J15 ; J64 ; D83.

1 ERMES (EAC-7181 CNRS) Université Panthéon-Assas Paris II and ESSEC Business School. Ad- dress: Emmanuel Valat, Université Panthéon-Assas Paris 2 (ERMES), 12 Place du Panthéon, 75230 Paris Cedex 05. France. Phone: +33 1 53 63 53 46. E-mail: [email protected]

1 1. INTRODUCTION

It is now widely admitted that information transmission about job vacancies through Social Networks -SN below, for short- a¤ects labor market outcomes2 . Yet, a very few studies have focused on the way SN a¤ect inequalities between groups. We do not thus exactly know in which conditions members of ethnic minorities bene…t or not from the that a part of jobs are found through contacts. The common about the impact of SN on inequality between groups in the labor market is that members of the majority group will bene…t from word-of-mouth communication more than members of minority groups, unless members of the minority group are well organized. The work of Tassier & Menzcer (2008) -T&M below, for short- which constitute as far as we aware the single theoritical attempt to investigate this issue, tends to con…rm this belief. T&M show from a controlled experiment that members of the minority group will clearly bene…t from word-of-mouth communication about job vacancies only when SN are segregated3 and since both members of the minority’s SN and job networks4 are tied into little clusters5 . In some ways, they demonstrate that many conditions are request for information transfer about vacancies through contacts at the advantage of members of the minority group against members of the majority group. For many we will detail below, we contest this conclusion and construct a model where we show, unlike T&M, that information transfer through SN will most of the bene…t to members of the minority group against members of the majority group. In fact the study of T&M do not take into account recent …ndings from the literature on network formation which show that the level of segregation in SN vary with the relative size of each group in the population. Indeed, in T&M the level of segregation is the same for both of the two groups. Taking into account that segregation in SN for both types6 vary with the relative size of each group, we show that by construction, communication through contacts will bene…t, all other things being equal between the two groups, to members of the minority group. Before describing with more details our model and our main results, let us tell more about why the level of segregation in SN partly depend of the relative size of each group in the population.

In fact, recent works such as the one of Currarini Jackson & Pin (2009) -CJ&P below,

2 See the seminal works of Rees (1966) and Granovetter (1973). See also Ioannides & Loury (2004) for a literature review on the subject. 3 Segregation in SN re‡ects in T&M the fact that individuals tend to be tied with individual of the same type. The tendancy to form friendship with individual with similar characteristics is also often refered in the literature as "homophily" in SN. We thus can mention some "homophily rate" or "segregation rate" in any individual’s SN. 4 Jobs may be structured into networks. In this case, an employed individual will only transmit a job o¤er about job vacancy which is linked to his job. If jobs are not linked in the economy (the case where there are only independant workers), an employed individual will transmit an information on a vacancy he randomly heard about. 5 This works only for a high enough level of segregation in SN and when members of the majority group, unlike members of the minority, are randomly tied. "Randomly tied" in T&M means that they are not linked into little group of four individuals where they all have frienship with each other. 6 "Type" in our model will refer to ethnic related patterns.

2 for short, the work of Moody (2001) or the one of McPherson & al (2001), have shown that segretation in social relations depends on the ability of individual to realize their more or less strong preferences to form friendship with individual similar to themeselves7 . Segregation in SN is in fact positively correlated, all other things being equal, with the relative size of the concerned group in the society even if meeting opportunity biases also an important role as we will see below. T&M, without introducing segregation in SN in taking into account this feature, miss as a consequence some strong speci…cities of segregation in SN. In order to take into account with more precision segregation in SN, we rely upon the model of network formation of CJ&P. CJ&P have built a model where they replicate for each in the population average homophily8 rates -the proportion of individual of the same ethnic group among ties- and average number of contacts they observe in many US high schools9 in function of the relative size of each group. More precisely, in CJ&P’smodel, network formation depend on three exogenous variables: the level of preferences for same type ties and two things which a¤ect the ability of individuals to realize these preferences, meeting biases through same type and relative size of each group in the population. When both preferences and meeting biases are …xed, homophily varies with the relative size of each group in the population. Taking into account this model of network formation modify, as we show in our model, the results of T&M in relaxing the conditions for homophily in SN being at the advantage of the minority group.

Our theoretical model of the labor market with SN is inspired by the one of Calvò- Armengol & Zenou (2005) -C-A&Z below, for short- which has been modi…ed by Ioan- nides & Soetevent (2006) -I&S below, for short. These last two models study the impact of the average number of contacts between workers in the economy on labor market performances10 . We rely upon these theoretical works because they o¤er a more sim- ple framework for numerical computations than the one of T&M. In the …rst part of our model we brie‡y illustrate how simultaneous variations in the three parameters we mentioned above in‡uence for each type both the average homophily rate and average number of contacts. In the second part of the model11 , in a similar theoretical frame-

7 One of the most pervasive feature observed in SN is the tendancy of individuals to associate with individuals similar to themselves. If age, or socioeconomic status are in‡uencing characteristics of friendship formation, ethnic related patterns are by far the most in‡uencing ones (see for instance Lewis & al, 2008; Grosseti, 2007; McPherson & al, 2001; Moody, 2001; Marsden, 1988). This legitimates the fact that "type" in our model refer to ethnic related patterns even if our results may also be tested for gender or socioeconomic status. 8 Henceforth, we will mention "homophily" in SN as in CJ&P instead of "segregation" in SN. 9 Their model feets very well with empirical about the two characteristics of networks we mentioned. Their data come from the Add Health inquiy from 112 US high schools. 10 C-A&Z study the impact of uniformly distributed number of contacts among workers whereas I&S study the impact of randomly ditributed number of contacts. C-A&Z …nd a critical size of networks from which the competition between worker in a network a¤ect at the matching function. I&S do not …nd any congestion e¤ect when the number of contact is not uniformly distributed among the population of workers. In the same subject see Wahba & Zenou (2005) for an empirical work with data from the 1998 Egyptian Labor Market Survey. 11 There are no strategic links between labor market outcomes and the way networks form. In other words, network formation does not depend on any outcome expectations from the labor market.

3 work of the labor market as C-A&Z and I&S12 , we describe how these variations in both the number of contacts and homophily rates for each type modify job arrival rates and unemployment. We …rst deduce from our numerical simulations a positive relation between the number of contacts and labor market outcomes, which is in line with the literature. The second important is that, all other things being equal be- tween the two groups, homophily leads to a higher job arrival rate for members of the minority group. This e¤ect increases and then diminishes when the relative size of each group move closer. We moreover extend the analysis of our results in two directions. Looking further into the literature on SN and labor market outcomes for minorities, we …rst notice that introducing CJ&P’smodel of network formation into a model of the la- bor market will help us to give some more theoretical interpretations to recent empirical …ndings on the impact of SN on inequality between groups in the labor market. Indeed, many recent empirical studies insist on the fact that some factors, such as urban ethnic segregation, attachment to the of origin or relative size of a community in the population, in‡uence individuals sociability and then their situation in the labor market -see for instance Battu & al (2010), Damm (2009), Hellerstein & al (2008), Pattachini & Zenou (2008), Edin & al (2003) and Conley & Topa (2002). Our results are going in the same way as the ones of these empirical studies13 . The second extension consist in re-evaluating the positive e¤ect of homophily in SN on labor market outcomes for the minority group when members of the minority group face hiring discriminations14 . We show in this extension that biased homophily still have a positive e¤ect but this e¤ect is now surprisingly monotically increasing15 when the size of the groups tend to be closer. Something noteworthy is however that the negative e¤ect of hiring discrimination is largely stronger than the positive e¤ect of homophily for member of the minority group. Even with a low level of discrimination, the situation of the minority is, unlike the case without hiring discrimination, clearly worse than the one of the majority.

2. NETWORK FORMATION

We assume that there are two types of individuals i and j, (with two di¤erents

Ni Nj origins). We then have a population N = Ni + Nj where ni = N and nj = N (Ni is the number of individual of type i, Nj is the number of individual of type j and N the total number of individuals in the population). Individuals of type i form ties in function of the relative size of their group ni in the population, but also in function of 12 A theoretical matching model of the labor market à la Pissarides (2000) with SN. 13 Preferences for same type ties have a negative impact on labor market outcomes for members of the minority group whereas a rise in meeting biases through same type -which could for instance be associated to a rise in the global ethnic segregation in the society- have a positive impact for members of the minority group 14 Arrow (1998) suggested that the impact of SN on minority’s situation in the labor market should not be studied separatly from the study of hiring discrimination or any hiring penalty. 15 This is true in every cases excepted one (see Fig.5).

4 their preference to form tie with their type i and in function of their meeting opportunity biases (going to cultural , meeting through friends, etc.).

2.1. The basic mecanism

We consider a matching process between individuals à la CJ&P. Each individual maximize his utility U(si; di) which is increasing and concave and where si and di are respectively for an individual of type i the number of contact of the same type i and of the other type j. In fact, Ni individuals of type i enter in the matching process and form one tie in each period, the same for the Nj individuals of type j. According to his utility and his constraint, each individuals decides to enter l in the process to get contacts. At each time individuals meet other individuals of both types. In the end of the process individuals of type i went on average li times in the process and have each formed li ties with li = si + di. Then, all individual of type i considered have formed

Ni li contacts. 

2.2. Preferences and meeting opportunity biases

2.2.1. Preferences for same-type ties

i We consider the following utility function, U(si; di) = (si + di) where [0; 1] i i 2 depreciates the utility of a contact with an individual of type j for individuals of type i and i [0; 1] is a coe¢ cient which catches the decreasing marginal utility of the total 2 number of contacts. We consider i = j = . Doing so, type i and type j will have the same satisfaction for the total number of ties they form. Moreover, when i < 1, each type give more value to a contact with an individual of the same type.

Individuals of type i choose to enter in the matching process li times in function of both U(si; di) and the cost ci of entering the process. Each individual of type i meets an individual of the same type with probability qi each time he enters the process and an individual of the other type with probability (1 qi).

Knowing the probability qi to meet someone of the same type for type i, we have si = liqi and di = li(1 qi). Then

U(liqi; li(1 qi)) = (liqi + li(1 qi)) (1) i

5 If ci [0; 1] is the cost to enter the process, individuals of type i solve the following 2 program:

Max [U(liqi; li(1 qi)) cili] (2) li

As for , we henceforth assume that ci = cj = c.

From (2) and (1) we …nd that the optimal number of contact li for an agent of type i is 1 1 1 l = ((1 ) qi + ) (3) i c i i  

2 1 1 1 @li 1 @li Note that = (1 qi) (1 i)qi + i 0, that is to say @ i c 0 1 () @ i  0 0   B  C the number of contact rise when preferences@ decreaseA ( i 1). In the same way, the | {z } | {z } ! 2 1 1 1 @li 1 number of contact rises when qi 1 because as we see = (1 i) (1 i)qi + i ! @qi c 0 1  0 0 @l  B  C i 0. @ A () @qi  | {z } | {z }

2.2.2. Biases in meeting opportunity

Without any meeting biases, since there is a large number of agents of each type, individuals of type i and those of type j have the same probability to meet an individual

Mi of type i. qii = qji = qi = M stands for this probability, where Mi = Nili is the total number of matching individuals of type i make and where M is the total number of matching individuals of both type i and j make so that M = Nili + Njlj. In the same Mj way we have qjj = qij = qj = M .

As CJ&P we introduce biases in meeting opportunity for each type toward individ- uals of the same type. This meeting could for instance represent the more or less important average physical or geographical between individual of the same type as mentionned in Conley and Topa (2002). If qii and qij are respectively for an individual of type i the probability to meet an individual of type i and j, then, instead of having

Mi Mj qi + qj = 1, which would be logical with qi = M and qj = M because Mi + Mj = M, we have

i j qi + qj = 1 (4) where i > 0 represent the meeting bias through same type for type i and j > 0 the meeting bias through same type for type j. Probabilities to meet individual of the other

6 type are respectively (1 qi) for individuals of type i and (1 qj) for individuals of type j.

i > 1 implies for instance for individuals of type i that they will have higher probability to meet individual of the same type than at random. When i > j, biases in meeting opportunity are higher for type i.

2.3. Additionnal condition

Since the total number of contacts formed by individuals of type i with individuals of type j is by de…nition the same as the total number of contacts formed by individuals of type j with type i, we have

(Mi) (1 qi) = (Mj) (1 qj)

() (Nil) (1 qi) = Njl (1 qj) i j  1 () i j nil (1 qi) = (1 ni) l 1 1 q (5) i j i    

This condition (5) will help us to solve the model.

2.4. Homophily rate and density of networks for each type

Individuals of type i …nally form on average si + di contacts. In the same way individuals of type j form sj + dj contacts. From all the previous equations we have

si = si(Ni; ; ) = l qi (6) i i i  di = di(Ni; ; ) = l (1 qi) i i i  and

sj = sj(Nj; ; ) = l qj (7) j j j  dj = dj(Nj; ; ) = l (1 qj) j j j 

We …x i; i; j and j. We have to …nd li (ni), qi (ni), lj (ni) and qj (ni). To do so,

7 we rely upon (1), (3), (4) and (5) and solve the following system:

1 1 1 l = ((1 ) qi + ) i c i i i j 8  qi + qj = 1 > > 1 1 > 1 > 1 i j (8) > l = 1 j 1 q + j > j c i <  1     i j > nili (1 qi) = (1 ni) lj 1 1 qi > >     > :>

We cannot analytically solve (8) to obtain li, qi, lj and qj, that is why as CJ&P we use simulation. We …x and c such that the total number of contacts each individual …nally forms approximatly vary between 10 and 20. This correspond to current …gures used in comparable researches (see Fontaine, 2008, Ioannides et Soetevent, 2006).

si We represent in the Fig.1 homophily curves Hi (ni) = and in the Fig.2 the si+di representative curves li (ni) of the number of contacts formed by individuals of type i, with and the same for the two types. In the Fig.1 we observe the impact of simultaneous variation in ni and , and also in ni and on Hi (ni). We see that Hi is always increasing in ni. Moreover, when > 1, a rise in preferences ( 0) have a ! negative impact on Hi if type i is the minority. But when 0 < 1, a rise in has a  positive impact on Hi. When 0 < 1 and > 1, Hi (ni) is an increasing and concave  function.

8 Hi 1

0.75

0.5

0.25

0 0 0.25 0.5 0.75 1

ni

Fig.1 Homophily rate Hi (ni).

li 17.5

16.25

15

13.75

12.5

11.25

10

8.75

7.5

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

ni

Fig.2 Average nbr. of contacts li (ni).

No biases (black thin solid) : = 1 & = 1 Medium biases (black dashes) : = 0:8 & = 2 Strong pref. and medium biases in meeting (gray dashes) = 0:1 & = 2 Medium pref. and strong biases in meeting (black thick solid) = 0:8 & = 5 Only biases in meeting (boxes) = 1 & = 2

The total number of contacts li (ni) an individual of type i has does not vary exactly in the same way as Hi (ni). Both li (ni) and Hi (ni) are increasing in ni. Furthermore, when exists (0 < < 1), a rise in has a positive impact on bothe li (ni) and Hi (ni).

But when > 1, a rise in preferences ( 0) clearly have a negative impact on li ! whereas it has a little negative impact on homophily rate when type i is the minority

9 and a little positive impact when type i stands for the majority.

3. THE LABOR MARKET

We now aim at estimating the impact of the variation in both homophily rate and number of contacts on job arrival rate and unemployment for each type. Heterogeneity only comes from the three factors we mentionned above. The labor market with we build steams from C-A&Z’s matching model à la Pissarides (2000) with discrete time periods16 , word-of-mouth communication about vacant jobs and an explicit network structure which come from CJ&P’smodel as decribed in the …rst section. Our model is di¤erent from C-A&Z’s one in allowing for individuals with di¤erent network structure. It follows the extension of C-A&Z’s model proposed by I&S, excepted that we do not consider random social network as in I&S but only two kind of workers with social networks re‡ecting individuals preference about friendship. In fact our model is positionned between C-A&Z and I&S models because we have two kinds of network but we keep a uniformly distributed number of contact for each type instead of Poisson distribution as in I&S.

However, as in C-A&Z an I&S we have identical workers - they are similar excepted that they are tied in function of their type - and identical …rms. At the begining of each time period tn each worker receives information about vacant job in a formal way (they can go to agencies, read newspaper, search through the web, etc.) with probability vtn . They also may receive information through contacts, this is what we call the "informal way" of receiving information. We describe the mecanism below. Each worker may lose his job with probability b. We denote ut the global unemployment rate at the end of period t. Finally, as in C-A&Z an I&S, we assume that newly-employed workers produce y0 at the …rst period they are employed and y1 in the next periods with y0 < y1. In the same way they earn w0 and w1. This induces that employed worker have not any interest to keep a job o¤er for themselve.

3.1. Transmission of job o¤er through contacts

We assume discrete time so that at each time period tn an employed worker who receive a job o¤er will choose only one of his unemployed contacts. As in C-A&Z one may interprete this as if an employed woker talk to only one of his direct unemployed contact a day. This imply that at each period, a worker of type i who receive a job o¤er

16 See Fontaine (2008) for a Matching model with SN and continuous time.

10 will select at random one of his siui + diuj unemployed contact, ui and uj being the unemployement rate of individual of type i and j.

The transmission proccess may then be summarized as follow. Consider ego, an unemployed individual of type i. Only employed ego’scontacts will transmit him infor- mation about jobs. At the steady state, let us note uei = Hiui + (1 Hi) uj the average unemployment rate in the network of an individual of type i. uei may be the average unemployment rate in one of ego’s employed contact of type i. Then the probability that ego’s employed contact who hold a job o¤er has k other unemployed contact and choose ego among all these individuals is

li 1 l i 1 li 1 li 1 k k 1 (1 uei) (1 uei) uei = (9) k + 1 k ueili k=0 X  

li 1 li 1 k k where (1 uei) u is the binomial distribution standing for the exact prob- k ei ability that there are k unemployed individual in the network of an employed individual  l 1 (1 uei) i of type i. (1 ui) v is then the probability that an individual of type i is ueili employed, receive a job o¤er and transmit it to ego.

If ego is an unemployed individual of type i, he has si contacts of his type. l si 1 (1 uei) i 1 (1 ui) v is then probability that any of these si contacts do not ueili transmit to ego an information about a job o¤er. The probability 'ii to receive a job o¤er through a contact of the same type for an individual of type i is then 1 l si 1 (1 uei) i 1 (1 ui) v . In the same way we obtain the probability 'ij that ego ueili lj di   1 (1 uej ) receive a job o¤er through a contact of the other type j, 1 1 (1 uj) v , uej lj where uej = Hjuj + (1 Hj) ui.  

We …nally have the probability 'i for an individual of type i to receive a job o¤er through network

'i = 'ii + 'ij and after simpli…cation

si di li lj 1 (1 uei) 1 (1 uej) 'i = 2 1 (1 ui) v 1 (1 uj) v (10) ueili ! uejlj !

In the same way we …nd

sj dj lj li 1 (1 uej) 1 (1 uei) 'j = 2 1 (1 uj) v 1 (1 ui) v (11) uejlj ! ueili !

From these results, one may deduce the probability pi that an unemployed individual

11 of type i receive a job o¤er. Taking into account both formal and informal method we have

pi = v + (1 v) ' (12) i In the same way we …nd

pj = v + (1 v) ' (13) j

3.2. The matching function

The corresponding matching function takes into account the two types such that

m (ui; uj; v; ni) = niuipi + (1 ni) ujpj (14)

The job …lling rate is de…ned as follow

m (u ; u ; v; n ) f (u ; u ; v; n ) = i j i i j i v and the probability that a vacant job is …lled by an unemployed individual of type i is

niuipi fi (ui; uj; v; ni) = m (ui; uj; v; ni) and (1 ni) ujpj fj (ui; uj; v; ni) = m (ui; uj; v; ni)

3.3. The steady-state labor market equilibrium

3.3.1. The free entry condition

The expected pro…t E of a …lled job by a worker of type i who have on average itn si + di contacts is at tn: 1 Eit = y1 w1i + (1 b)Eit + bVt (15) n 1 + r n+1 n+1 h i where y1 is the productivity of an employed individual, w1i is the wage of an individual of type i and Vt is the expected pro…t of a vacant job for a …rm at tn+1. Moreover, n+1

12 if f is the rate at which a …rm …ll a vacant job and fi the probability to …ll a job through a type i unemployed individual, then V is: tn

1 1 Vt = h+(1 f) Vt +f y0 w0 + (1 b) Efi;j Ei;jt + bVt n 1 + r n+1 1 + r  n+1 n+1   h i (16)  where h is the cost of a vacant job for …rms, r the interest rate and where the expectation

Efi;j is taken with respect to fi;j (ui; uj; v; ni).

At the steady state we have Eit = Eit = Ei and Vt = Vt = V . n n+1 n n+1 Moreover, with the free entry condition we have V = 0. With y0 = w0 = 0, these con- 1+r 1+r ditions lead (16) to h 1 b = f Efi;j Ei;j . From (15) we deduce Ei = (y1 w1i ) r+b 1+r  and Ej = y1 w1 . We then have j r+b    r + b h = Ef f y1 w1 (17) 1 b i;j  i;j  

3.3.2. Wages determination

Utility of unemployed individuals :

If WUitn is type i unemployed individual utility, r is the real interest rate, w0 is the wage of an individual entering employment and W the utilty of a type i employed Eitn+1 individual at tn+1, then

1 1 WU = (1 pit ) WU + pit w0 + (1 b) WE + bWU itn 1 + r n itn+1 n 1 + r itn+1 itn+1    At the steady state, W = W = W and W = W = W . We …nally Eitn Eitn+1 Ei Uitn Uitn Ui have 1 1 WU = (1 pi) WU + pi w0 + ((1 b) WE + bWU ) (18) i 1 + r i 1 + r i i  

Utility of employed individuals :

Utility WEitn of a type i employed individual is:

1 WE = w1 + (1 b) WE + bWU itn i 1 + r itn+1 itn+1 h i then at the steady state

1 WE = w1 + [(1 b) WE + bWU ] (19) i i 1 + r i i

13 with w1 the wage and b the job destruction rate.

Finding wages :

From (19) and (18) we …nd at the steady state

1 + r WEi WUi = w1i (20) r + b + pi (1 b)

If we note x (0; 1) the surplus share attributed to workers and if wages are Nash 2 bargained we have

x 1 x w1 = arg max (WE WU ) (E V ) i i i i We then have the following …rst order condition

(1 x)(WE WU ) = x (E V ) (21) i i i

From (21), (20) and (15) and from the free entry condition V = 0,

(1 x)(WE WU ) = x (E V ) i i i

() x (r + b) + xpi (1 b) w1i = y1 (22) r + b + xpi (1 b)

In the same way we …nd

x (r + b) + xpj (1 b) w1j = y1 (23) r + b + xpj (1 b)

3.3.3. Finding the vacancy rate at the steady state

From (22), (23) and (17) we …nd

fy1 h Efi;j = (24) r + b + x (1 b) pi;j (1 b) (1 x)  

14 3.3.4. The steady-state unemployment rate

At the begining of each period tn, a proportion of type i unemployed individuals

…nd a job with probability pitn . A rate uitn 1 pitn of individual of type i thus enters employment at the begining of tn, where uitn 1 is the unemployment rate of a type i individual when entering tn. Moreover, we have a rate 1 uitn 1 of type i employed individuals at the begining of tn. If, at each period, some employed individuals lose their job at rate b, individual of type i lose their job at tn at rate b 1 uitn 1 + uitn 1 pitn .   of unemployment between tn and tn 1 is equal to the di¤erence between those who have entered unemployment at the beginig of period tn and those who have lost their job at the end of tn, then

uitn uitn 1 = b 1 uitn 1 + uitn 1 pitn uitn 1 pitn   We then have, at the steady state, with uitn = uitn 1 = ui, and pitn = pitn+1 = pi b ui = (25) pi (1 b) + b and b uj = (26) pj (1 b) + b Moreover, we …nd the steady-state average unemployment rate

u = niui + (1 ni) uj (27) and b u = (1 b) p + b

3.4. Calibration

We start from the following system to calibrate our model for types i and j -see appendix A for more details about the choice of parameters chosen for calibration:

15 E fy1 = h (24) fi;j r+b+x(1 b)pi;j (1 b)(1 x) 1 1 8 i h i i WUi = 1+r (1 p ) WUi + p w0 + 1+r ((1 b) WEi + bWUi ) (18) > > 1 h i > WEi = w1i + [(1 b) WEi + bWUi ] (19) > 1+r >  = y w + 1 [(1 b) + b ] (15) > Ei 1 1i 1+r Ei V > b > ui = (25) > pi(1 b)+b > b > uj = (26) > pj (1 b)+b > < u = niui + (1 ni) uj (27) x(r+b)+xpi (1 b) > w1 = y1 (22) > i r+b+xpi (1 b) > > x(r+b)+xpj (1 b) > w1j = y1 (23) > r+b+xpj (1 b) > > pi = v + (1 v) ' (12) > i > > pj = v + (1 v) 'j (13) > > :>

3.5. Simulation results and interpretation

We choose a set of for and in order to illustrate the impact of both the variation in preferences and meeting opportunities biases on job arrival rate and unem- ployment rate.

16 pi(ni) 0.0023

0.0022

0.0021

0.002

0.0019

0.0018

0.0017

0.0016

0.0015

0.0014

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5

ni

Fig.3 Job arrival rate for minority pi (ni).

ui(ni) 0.13

0.125

0.12

0.115

0.11

0.105

0.1

0.095

0.09

0.085

0.08

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5

ni

Fig.4 Unemployment rate ui (ni).

No biases (black thin solid) : = 1 & = 1 Medium biases (black dashes) : = 0:8 & = 2 Strong pref. and medium biases in meeting (gray dashes) = 0:1 & = 2 Medium pref. and strong biases in meeting (black thick solid) = 0:8 & = 5 Only biases in meeting (boxes) = 1 & = 2

17 3.5.1. The main observations

When biases do not exist (see in Fig.3 and Fig.4 the black thin solid, = 1 and = 1), there are not any variation in both the job arrival rate and the unemployment rate. Indeed, there are not any that information ‡ows di¤ers between individuals of type i and j as they have the same number of total contacts and the same number of contacts of each type (see Fig.1 and Fig.2). Thus, whatever the size of the groups ni, individuals have the same probability to receive a job o¤er.

Members of the minority group are advantaged:

Since biases in preferences and meetings exit (0 < < 1 and > 1) and since a part of information circulate through SN, we observe that individuals from the minor- ity group are most of the time avantadged as compared with the average situation in the economy17 . In other word it seems that the of biases in preferences and meetings bene…t most of the time to members of the minority group -excepted for small groups with high preferences, see the case with = 0:1 in gray dashes.

Non-monotonicity of the job arrival rate curve:

An other important point is, when both biases in preferences and meetings exit, that a rise of the relative size of the minority group induce an increasing and decreasing form of the job arrival rate curve18 -see Fig.3 and Fig.4. Why is thus the minority advantadged, why do the job arrival rate curve have this increasing and decreasing form and what are the mechanisms induced by the variations in ni, and ?

3.5.2. What are the impact of variations in homophily, in number of contacts and in relative size of groups?

Considering the structure of our model, only three parameters have a direct impact on labor market outcomes, the homophily rate Hi (ni), the total number of contacts li (ni) and the relative size of each groups which may be resumed by ni. Fig.1 and Fig.2 give information about the way ni, and in‡uence Hi (ni) and li (ni). We also know from the literature - see C-A&Z and I&S - that the number of contacts li (ni) have in this type of model a positive e¤ect on job arrival rate. We nevertheless do not know anything about the e¤ect of Hi (ni) and about the combined e¤ect of li (ni) and Hi (ni) on job arrival rates. To better understand the global mechanism at work we compare situations with di¤érents ni, and . From this we deduce the e¤ect of the existance

17 The average situation in the economy may be compared to the situation where there are neither biases in meetings nor biases in preferences ( and are equal to 1). Note that this will change when we will consider below a case with hiring discrimination for members of the minority group. 18 The relation is inverse for unemployment.

18 of biased homophily - Hi (ni) = ni - on job arrival rate. Once the e¤ect of Hi (ni) = ni 6 6 on labor market is clearly known, one may interprete the global e¤ect of Hi (ni), li (ni) and ni.

The impact of Hi (ni):

An interesting case is the one with biases in meetings only (see the curve shaped with boxes, = 1 and = 2). From Fig.1 we observe that in this case Hi (ni) > ni, which means that there are biased homophily19 . Moreover, one may observe from Fig.2 that, with biases in meetings only, li (ni) is constant. Homophily is then biased whereas all individuals have the same number of contacts (li is neutral). We then use this case to control for the e¤ect of Hi (ni) > ni. We observe from Fig.3 that the concave increasing and decreasing form of the job arrival rate curve is conserved. The fact that

Hi (ni) > ni is then su¢ cient to explain both the fact that members of the minority group are advantaged and the increasing and decreasing form of the job arrival rate curve for members of the minority group when ni rise. Even if we already have some information from the literature about it, let us now discuss the e¤ect of li (ni).

The impact of li (ni):

Are our simulation results about the e¤ects of the number of contacts on labor market outcomes in line with the literature on social networks? We know from the theoretical 20 literature that a rise in li (ni) have a positive e¤ect on job arrival rate . But what happens when homophily in SN exist? Two cases from the previous graphs may be compared to confront our result with the literature results. From Fig.3 one may notice that the case with medium biases (see black dashes, = 0:8 and = 2) is a little less e¢ cient for the minority group than the case with biases in meeting only (see boxes,

= 1 and = 2). We see from Fig.1 that the homophily rate Hi (ni) is not di¤erent between these two cases. The number of contacts is however a little higher for the case with meeting biases only (see Fig.2). The case with higher level of contacts being advantageous for members of the minority group, we deduce that the number of contact li (ni) have in our model a positive e¤ect on job arrival rate for minority. This positive e¤ect seems to be con…rmed by another comparison, the one between the two cases we have just mentionned above and the case with strong preferences and medium biases in meeting (gray dashes, = 0:1 and = 2). Indeed, with strong preferences ( = 0:1) homophily rate does not di¤er a lot with the two previous cases (see Fig.1) whereas the number of contacts an individual create is strongly a¤ected (see Fig.2). Our simulation framework only allow us to con…rm that our model seems to be in line with the literature.

19 Biases homophily means that at each giving point (ni; nj ), expected when ni = nj , individuals of type i and j do not have the same number of contacts of each type. 6 20 Let us bring to mind that in C-A&Z, when contacts are uniformly distributed, we have a positive correlation between density of networks and job arrival rate until some value of the density of SN in the economy. Yet, in the same theoretical framework, I&S have shown that when number of contacts each individual has is randomly distributed, the relation remains increasing only.

19 It does not allow us to conclude about the fact that this positive correlation between the number of contacts and job arrival rate is due to homophily21 or the fact that we do not consider a high enough number of contacts22 .

The impact of ni:

What …nally about the direct impact of ni? It seems that a variation in ni only, when there is no biases (it means when Hi (ni) = ni and li (ni) is constant) does not lead to any variation in the job arrival rate (see the black thin solid in Fig.3). From this we conclude that a variation in ni have a direct impact on job arrival rate only when

Hi (ni) = ni and when li (ni) is not constant. 6 Some of the mechanisms at work have then clearly been identi…ed. The impact of li (ni) is well understood, individuals bene…t from a rise in li (ni) in receiving a larger

‡ow of information about vacant jobs. Hi (ni) have a positive impact on job arrival rate for the minority. But how now explain the direct impact of Hi (ni) on labor market outcomes and what are the economic behind the increasing and decreasing form of the job arrival rates curves observe in Fig.3? Let us now explain in a more intutive way the combined impact of variations in ni and Hi (ni) on job arrival rate.

3.5.3. Why do the existence of biased homophily tend to advantage the minority group?

Two important questions must …nally be clari…ed : why is the minority advantaged and how the increasing and decreasing form of the job arrival rates curves could be explained? We know from the previous discussion that the answer comes from the explaination of the consequences of the variations in Hi (ni) on labor market outcomes.

Explanation for the positive correlation between homophily and labor market outcomes for members of the minority group:

As job information is uniformly distributed through the formal channel to individ- uals whatever their type23 , the advantage of the minority group obviously comes from di¤erence in the structure of networks. Thus, looking into equations (12) and (13), when ni < 0:5, we have 'i (ni) > 'j (ni). Looking into 'i (ni) and 'j (ni) -see equations (10) and (11)- we see that the single di¤erences between theses two expressions are the value of the exponents si, di, sj and dj. When ni < 0:5 -type i is the minority- we observe from Fig.1 that minority’s networks are more mixed (lower homophily rate) than majority’s

21 I&S have shown that when considering randomly distributed number of contacts accross the popu- lation of workers, we have an increasing relation between global job arrival rate and the average number of contacts of workers in the economy. 22 Indeed, C-A&Z …nd a critical network size above which the job arrival rate decrease. 23 The probability v to receive a job o¤er through formal channel is the same in equations (12) and (13).

20 networks. In other words, distribution of conctact is better balanced for type i (si and di are not to much di¤erent) than for type j (sj is very high whereas dj is not very far from zero). This means that more opened or mixed group (who can receive job o¤er through contacts of both type) is advantaged. Thus, in our model, homophily bene…t to members of the minority as they have by construction a lower homophily rate than members of the majority. The di¤erence between the two groups tend to decrease as homophily rate of each group tend to come nearer. We then may assume that when determinents of SN formation have not the same value for members of the minority and the majority groups, this situation with advantaged for the minority could change. If homophily is higher for members of the minority than for members of the majority, homophily will maybe bene…t to members of the majority. Of course, as our model is complex and many things can occur, this situation should be studied in additional simulations.

Explanation for the non-monotonicity of the job arrival rates curve:

Following C-A&Z and I&S, we have assumed a binomial distribution of unemploy- ment into networks -see equation (9). Looking into this distribution we observe that there are the same variables -uei and li- in the numerator and the denominator though operations with these variables are not identical. A rise in Hi (ni) will obviously have the same consequences on the variation of uei in each part of the expression but the variation of uei will not have the same impact on the denominator and the nominator. We observe that a positive variation in Hi (ni) may have a higher impact on the numerator untill a

…xed value Hi (ni) and then a higher impact on the denominator. In other words, not only the minority is advantaged when Hi (ni) > ni but the situation of the minority is improved until some openness Hi (ni) of the network and then deteriored. The fact that unemployment is distributed at random in each networks allow for an increasing and decreasing impact of homophily rate.

3.5.4. What about the impact of variations in , and ni on job arrival rate and unemployment?

Fig.3 is su¢ cient to compare the e¤ect of preferences, meeting biases and relative size of the group on job arrival rate for members of the minority group.

The impact of a variation in preferences for same type ties on job arrival rates:

When comparing the case with "medium biases" -black dashes- and the case with "strong preferences and medium biases in meetings" -gray dashes, one may observe that the situation of members of the minority group is depreciated when preferences rises. This could even hamper frienship formation for individual from very little group (see Fig.2) and globally disadvantage members of the minority group in comparison with

21 members of the majority group. In other works it could counterbalance the positive e¤ect of biased homophily for minority and inverse the global e¤ect. However, this is all in all in line with the very few existing empirical works on the subject -see for instance Battu & al (2010). It give an additional simple explanation to empirical observations.

The impact of a variation in meeting biases through same type on job arrival rates:

As we mentioned, a rise in meeting opportunity biases may be associated to a rise in the global ethnic segregation in the society. When comparing in Fig.3 the case with "medium biases" -black dashes- and the case with "medium preferences and strong meeting biases" -black thick solid, one may observe that the situation of members of the minority group has moved in a positive direction. Looking into Fig.1, one may conclude that this is due to the existance of biased homophily. In fact this rise the di¤erence between tahe average homophily rate of the majority group and the minority, particularly for little ni -for very little relative size of the minority group. These results also are in line with the empirical literature which is a little more developed in this area -see for instance Damm (2009), Hellerstein & al (2008), Pattachini & Zenou (2008), Edin & al (2003) and Conley & Topa (2002).

The impact of a variation in the relative size of groups on job arrival rates:

From Fig.3 we see that a rise in the average size of the minority group always has -when biases exist- a positive and then negative e¤ect on job arrival rates for members of the minority group. This is conversely true for members of the majority group. There is not any empirical study to our which explore this correlation, excepted the one of Munshi (2003) which works on very rich data on Mexican migrant in the US. But if this link seems to be robust there is not any clear interpretation emerging from this study.

3.6. The labor market with discrimination

We now consider that members of the minority group will be exogenously confronted to hiring discrimination. Indeed, as suggested by Arrow (1998), the impact of SN on labor market for minority and hiring discrimination should not be studyied separatly. This remark could be taken as something judicious to do in our model as when members of the minority are subjected to hiring discrimination, having more link with individual from the minority will increase the number of unemployed contacts and the lower the probability to get information on job vacancies through SN.

If i is the minority, we have the same model as before excepted that

pi = Dv + (1 Dv) D' (28) i

22 with D [0; 1]. Equation (13) is not a¤ected. Moreover let us mention that the para- 2 meter D do not interfere in the probability v of an employed individual of type i to hear about a job vacancy -see this probability v in both equations (10) and (11). In fact, when he is employed, a member of the minority group just hear of a vacancy in his …rm and transmit the information. He will be discriminated against only if he apply for the job. In the same way as before we choose a set of value for and but this time taking into account equation (28) instead of equation (12).

23 pi(ni) 0.00135 0.0013 0.00125 0.0012 0.00115 0.0011 0.00105 0.001 0.00095 0.0009 0.00085 0.0008 0.00075 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5

ni Fig.5 Job arrival rate for minority with D=0.5

ui(ni) 0.21

0.2

0.19

0.18

0.17

0.16

0.15

0.14

0.13

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5

ni Fig.6 Unemployment rate with D=0.5

No biases (black thin solid) : = 1 & = 1 Medium biases (black dashes) : = 0:8 & = 2 Strong pref. and medium biases in meeting (gray dashes) = 0:1 & = 2 Medium pref. and strong biases in meeting (black thick solid) = 0:8 & = 5 Only biases in meeting (boxes) = 1 & = 2

24 3.6.1. The main observations

We …rst observe that this time, when members of the minority are subjected to hiring discrimination, the situation of the minority is worse than the one of the majority. Discrimination seems to have a larger e¤ect than the positive one of SN with homophily when discrimination exist. Indeed, as we see in Fig.5, biased homophily still have24 a positive impact on job arrival rate for the minority.

Let us concentrate on the situation without any biases. Unlike the case without discrimination, there is now an impact of SN on labor market outcomes even when there are not any biases (the case in black thin solid, = 1 and = 1). Job arrival rate for the minority pi rises with homophily rate Hi. Why is it so? Something noteworthy is that when there are not any biases, individuals of type i and j have the same amount of contact of each type. Di¤erences between the two groups25 then only come from the di¤erent size of the group. Thus when the size of each group tend to be closer, the situation of the minority is improving. In fact, as members of the minority group are discriminated against in the hiring process, having more link from the minority group in his SN will reduce the ability of the network to provide information about vacant 26 job . When relative size of the minority group ni rises, the number of contacts from the minority rises in both SN of individuals of type i and j, but it has a larger negative e¤ect in networks of individual of type i. The relative situation of the minority is going better in comparison with the situation of the majority which is going worse.

Looking into the other cases with biased homophily in SN, one may notice that the order of the results has not changed in comparison with the case without discrimination, excepted in the case when there are strong biases in meeting (black thick solid, = 0:8 & = 5). In this latter case, the very high homophily rate we observe in Fig.1 make the black thin curve varying di¤erently. Having a high level of segregation in the network may create a higher positive e¤ect for very small groups and then a negative e¤ect until regain a low positive e¤ect. The mechanism seams to be much more complicated when homophily in SN is combined with hiring penalty for members of the minority group.

4. CONCLUDING REMARKS

Heterogeneity in our model comes from variations in both homophily rate and average number of contacts by individual in each group. Our numerical simulations are mainly in

24 Excepted in the case with high meeting opportunity biases in black thick solid, = 0:8 & = 5. 25 Excepted the exogenous steady rate of hiring discrimination D. 26 Hiring discrimination rises unemployment rate for members of the minority group (see unemploy- ment rate in Fig.6 for members of the minority group in comparison with the average unemployment rate in the economy which is …xed at 10%).

25 line with theoretical and empirical works which have investigated the impact of variations in the average number of contacts each individual has on labor market performances. Job arrival rate is increasing in the number of contacts. Our results are however, for the issue of how homophily in‡uence labor market outcomes, partly di¤erent from other works. Indeed, unlike T&M’s experiment, which constitute as far as we aware one of the very few attempts to study this issue, we consider that homophily in SN vary with the size of the groups. Homophily is then, all other things being equal between the two groups, higher for the majority group. The minority group will be in some way relatively more opened and thus more able to receive through SN. Taking into account endogenous homophily in a simple matching model of the labor market with word-of-mouth communication allow us to release the constraints27 assumed by T&M for homophily to be at the advantage of members of the minority group.

Some additional remarks may be made. First, introducing a model of network for- mation into a model of the labor market with SN allow us to compare some of our results with empirical studies which try to identify how some social patterns in‡uence both SN and labor market outcomes for various groups of individuals with migrant …liation in the society. Our results are mainly in line with empirical results which show that a rise in preferences for same type ties damages the situation of the minority whereas a rise in meeting opportunity through same type -for instance average ethnic segregation in the society such as urban ethnic segregation28 , improves labor market outcomes for members of the minority group. The other important remark about our model is that the e¤ect of homophily for members of the minority group remains positive since members of the minority group are a¤ected by an exogenous hiring penalty. Indeed, the existence of hiring discrimination could have transformed the positive e¤ect of biased homophily for members of the minority group into a negative e¤ect: having more links coming from the minority group would increase the number of unemployed contacts, which would thus decrease the number of potential sources of information and increase the competition for information in the network. But as homophily grows with the relative size of the minority group, the relative part of contacts from the minority also rises in members of the majority29 ’SN. The majority group is more a¤ected by this phenomenon than the minority. However, the e¤ect of hiring discrimination for the minority is in our simu- lations, even with a low level of discrimination, by far larger than the positive e¤ect of biased homophily for the minority group. This latest remark allow us to assume that our theoretical scenario o¤ers a potential explanation for the di¤erence in the average level of unemployment observed in France between North African orginated workers, French

27 In T&M this clearly works only when members of the minority group are tied into little clusters whereas members of the majority group are randomely tied. Jobs must also be organized into networks and not be independant each other. 28 See for instance Damm (2009), Hellerstein & al (2008), Pattachini & Zenou (2008), Edin & al (2003) and Conley & Topa (2002). 29 When the relative size of the minority group increase, both the relative size and the average ho- mophily rate are decreasing for the majority group.

26 workers and Portuguese originated workers30 (see Domingues Dos Santos, 2005).

Finally, ethnic oriented homophily being one of the most signi…cant pattern of SN according to many empirical studies, we think that the consequence of biased homophily in SN on market mechanisms should in the generate more attention. We need more theoretical and empirical explorations to clarify the consequences of homophilous behaviors on many observed features of the labor market. By introducing homophily in SN in a dynamics framework31 , one could for instance try to explain why the edge of a giving group of migrant workers or workers with migrant …liation in a labor pool matters a lot as Patel and Vella (2007), Frijters & al (2005) and Munshi (2003) have empirically observed. Other future researches may also go further in analysing the structure of networks by using graph theory as in Càlvo-Armengol & Jackson (2004). Graph theory could for instance be used to introduce clusters32 in SN -little groups of individuals all tied together. But instead of T&M, clusters should not be exogenously introduced in a model with homophily in SN. Indeed, if clusters modify information circulation -see Jackson (2008a)- and it has been shown -see Jakson (2008b)- that biased-homophily increases clustering in networks. A latest remark may be made about the introduction of jobs networks. Unlike T&M, something which could be interesting to take into account is the fact that jobs are most of the time linked in function of their quality33 . Someone who works in a good job will more often heard about an o¤er on a good job vacancy than someone who work in a bad job. Moreover, someone employed in a bad job will rationally keep the information for him in order to improve his situation. Thus, as homophily in SN in‡uence information transfer, one should study in which conditions it makes some groups more able than others to get good jobs.

30 Portuguese workers have on average the lowest rate of unemployment, even lower than the one of French workers. Portuguese workers could then be identi…ed in our model to members of the minority group when they are not discriminated against, whereas North African worker may be assimilated to discriminated members of the minority group. 31 See Fontaine (2008) for a theoretical model with a dynamic evolution of employment into networks. 32 Non-randomness -which in some way re‡ects clustering or the fact that individuals make ties with friends of friends- have been taking into account by Tassier and Menzcer (2008) but without taking into account any link between homophily rate and randomness as it should be done according to Jackson (2008a, 2008b). 33 of jobs may refer to working conditions, wages or any advantages which could improve workers satifaction. See for instance the paper of Pissarides (1994) about bad jobs and good jobs.

27 5. REFERENCES

Arrow K. (1998) "What Has Economic to Say about Racial Discrimination?" Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(2), p.91-110.

Battu, H. and Y. Zenou (2010), « Oppositional identities and employment for ethnic minorities. from England » , Economic Journal, forthcoming.

Battu H., M. McDonald and Y. Zenou (2007), « Oppositional identities and the labor market » , Journal of Population , 20, p.643-667.

Càlvo-Armengol A. and M. Jackson (2004) “Social Networks in determining employ- ment: patterns, dynamics and inequality”, American Economic Review, 94, p. 426-454.

Càlvo-Armengol A. and Y. Zenou (2005) "Job Matching, Social Network and Word- of-Mouth Communication, Journal of Urban Economics, 57, p.500-522.

Conley T.G. and G. Topa (2002) "Socio-Economic distance and spatial patterns in unemployment", Journal of Applied Econometrics, 17, p.303-327.

Currarini S., M. Jackson and P. Pin (2008) “An economic model of friendship: ho- mophily, minorities and segregation”, Econometrica, Vol.77, N4, p.1003-1045.

Damm, A.P. (2009) "Ethnic Enclaves and Immigrant Labor Market Outcomes: Quasi- Experimental Evidence", Journal of Labor Economics, 27(2), p.281-314.

Domingues Dos Santos M. (2005) « Travailleurs Maghrébins et Portugais en France : le poids de l’origine » , Revue Economique, Vol 56, p.447-464.

Edin P-A., P. Fredriksson and O. Aslund (2003) "Ethnic enclaves and the economic succes of immigrants-Evidence from a natural experiment", Quarterly Journal of Eco- nomics, 118, p.329-357.

Fontaine F. (2008) "Why are similar workers paid di¤erently? The role of social networks.", Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 32, issue 12, p.3960-3977.

Frijters P. Shields M.A. and Wheatley Price S. (2005) "Job search methods and their succes: a comparison of immigrants and natives in the UK", The Economic Journal, 115 (November).

Granovetter M. (1973) "The Strength of Weak Ties", American Journal of ,

Vol.78, N6, p.1360-1380.

Grosseti M. (2007) "Are French network di¤erent?", Social Network, 29, p.391-404.

28 Hellerstein J.K., M. McInerney & D. Neumark (2008) "Neighbors and Co-Workers: the Importance of Residential Labor Market Networks", NBER-WP,N14201.

Holzer H. (1987) "Informal Job Search and Black Youth Unemployment", American

Economic Review, Vol. 77, N3.

Ioannides Y. and L. Datcher Loury (2004) "Job information Networks, Neighborhood e¤ects and Inequality", Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), p.1056-1093.

Ioannides Y. and Soetevent A. (2006) "Wages and Employment in a random Social Network with Arbitrary Distribution", American Economic Review, Vol. 96,

N2.

Jackson M. (2008a) "Social and Economic Networks", Princeton University Press.

Jackson M. (2008b) "Average Distance, Diameter, and Clustering in Social Networks with Homophily", Proceedings of the Workshop in Internet and Network Economics (WINE 2008).

Lewis K., J. Kaufman, M. Gonzalez, A. Wimmer and N. Christakis (2008) "Tastes, ties, and time: A new social network dataset using .com", Social Network, 30, p.330-342.

Marsden P. (1988) "Homogeneity in con…ding relations, Social Network, 10, p.57-76.

McPherson M., L. Smith-Lovin & J.M. Cook (2001), "Birds of a Feather: Homophily in Social Networks", Annual Review of Sociology, 27, p.415-444.

Moody J. (2001) "Race, School Integration, and Friendship Segregation in America",

American Journal of Sociology, Vol.107, N3, p.679-716.

Munshi K. (2003) « Networks in modern economy: Mexican migrants in the US Labor Market”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 2003, p.549-599.

Patacchini E. and Zenou Y. (2008) "Ethnic Networks and Employment Outcomes",

IZA Discussion Paper n3331.

Patel K. and Vella F. (2007) "Immigrant Networks and their implications for occu- pational Choice and Wages", IZA Discussion Paper n3217.

Pissarides C. (2000) "Equilibrium Unemployment Theory", Cambridge, Massachus- setts: MIT Press, 2nd Edition.

Pissarides C.A. (1994) "Search Unemployment with On-the-job Search", Review of Economic Studies, 61, p.457-475.

29 Rees A. (1966) "Information networks in Labor Markets", American Economic Re- view, 56, p.559-566.

Tassier T. & F. Menczer (2008) "Social Network Structure, Segregation, and Equality in the Labor Market with Referral Hiring, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organiza- tion, Vol.66, p.514-528.

Wahba J. and Y. Zenou (2005) “Density, social networks and job search methods: theory and application to Egypt”, Journal of Development Economics, 78, p.443-473.

30 APPENDIX A: THE CHOICE OF PARAMETERS

As Fontaine (2008), we choose the following value corresponding to the French econ- omy: If r is the daily interest rate, we choose r = 0:00016. b, the daily job destruction rate is …xed such that b = 0:0002. The bargaining power of workers x is as usual x = 0:5. The cost of a vacant job is estimated to 0:3, the h = 0:3. We …x the global unemployment rate u = 0:1.

As in C-A&Z and I&S, productivity of workers is normalized to 1, then y1 = 1.

Moreover y0 is …xed to 0.

APPENDIX B: INTRODUCING A PARAMETER "A" TAKING INTO ACCOUNT INSTUTIONNAL SPECIFICITIES MAKING U = 0:1

Let us add to the matching function m (ui; uj; v; ni) = niuipi +(1 ni) ujpj we have in the model, a parameter A such that

m (ui; uj; v; ni) = A (niuipi + (1 ni) ujpj)

Let now determine the value of A when u = 0:1 is …xed.

b b(1 u) (1) Starting from u, we have u = (1 b)p+b which imply p = (1 b)u . n u (1 ni)uj (2) On another hand we have p = A i i (v + (1 v) ' ) + v + (1 v) ' . u i u j   From (2) we deduce that

niui (1 ni) uj p = A (v + (1 v) ' ) + v + (1 v) ' u i u j    ()

niui niui (1 ni) uj (1 ni) uj p = A v + (1 v) ' + v + (1 v) ' u u i u u j  

() (1 v) p = A v + niui' + (1 ni) uj' u i j    () p A = (1 v) v + niui' + (1 ni) uj' u i j  31 and from (1), we have

b(1 u) (1 b)u A = (1 v) v + niui' + (1 ni) uj' u i j 

APPENDIX C: INTRODUCING A PARAMETER "A" TAKING INTO ACCOUNT INSTUTIONNAL SPECIFICITIES MAKING U = 0:1 WHEN DISCRIMINATION EXIST

As above without discrimination, we determine the value of A when u = 0:1 is …xed.

In the same way as above, we have b b(1 u) (1) u = (1 b)p+b which imply p = (1 b)u , but now if type i stands for the minority and as members of the minority group are discriminated against at rate D [0; 1], we do not have (2) but 2 n u (1 ni)uj (2bis) p = A i i (Dv + (1 Dv) D' ) + v + (1 v) ' . u i u j   Starting from (2bis) we have

p A = n u (1 ni)uj i i (Dv + (1 Dv) D' ) + v + (1 v) ' u i u j  () p u A =  niui (Dv + (1 Dv) D' ) + (1 ni) uj v + (1 v) ' i j and introducing (1) we …nd 

b(1 u) (1 b)u u A =  niui (Dv + (1 Dv) D' ) + (1 ni) uj v + (1 v) ' i j  () b (1 u) A = (1 b) niui (Dv + (1 Dv) D' ) + (1 ni) uj v + (1 v) ' i j 

32