Herd Behavior and the Quality of Opinions

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Herd Behavior and the Quality of Opinions Journal of Socio-Economics 32 (2003) 661–673 Herd behavior and the quality of opinions Shinji Teraji Department of Economics, Yamaguchi University, 1677-1 Yoshida, Yamaguchi 753-8514, Japan Accepted 14 October 2003 Abstract This paper analyzes a decentralized decision model by adding some inertia in the social leaning process. Before making a decision, an agent can observe the group opinion in a society. Social learning can result in a variety of equilibrium behavioral patterns. For insufficient ranges of quality (precision) of opinions, the chosen stationary state is unique and globally accessible, in which all agents adopt the superior action. Sufficient quality of opinions gives rise to multiple stationary states. One of them will be characterized by inefficient herding. The confidence in the majority opinion then has serious welfare consequences. © 2003 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. JEL classification: D83 Keywords: Herd behavior; Social learning; Opinions; Equilibrium selection 1. Introduction Missing information is ubiquitous in our society. Product alternatives at the store, in catalogs, and on the Internet are seldom fully described, and detailed specifications are often hidden in manuals that are not easily accessible. In fact, which product a person decides to buy will depend on the experience of other purchasers. Learning from others is a central feature of most cognitive and choice activities, through which a group of interacting agents deals with environmental uncertainty. The effect of observing the consumption of others is described as the socialization effect. The pieces of information are processed by agents to update their assessments. Here people may change their preferences as a result of E-mail address: [email protected] (S. Teraji). 1053-5357/$ – see front matter © 2003 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.socec.2003.10.004 662 S. Teraji / Journal of Socio-Economics 32 (2003) 661–673 interpersonal contact. Then information externalities arise that drive towards the emergence of some patterns of influences among individuals.1 Recently there has been increasing interest in economic models in the presence of in- formation externalities, which put a great emphasis on the notion of social learning. In social and economic situations, we are often influenced in our decision making by what others around us are doing.2 Mimetic contagion was thought of as an irrational behavior that is responsible for pathological dynamics such as financial bubbles. Some studies have been seen as a way to formulate rigorously a number of challenges to standard economic doctrine.3 Individual behavior may be governed by herd externality. What everyone else is doing is rational because their decisions may reflect information that they have and we do not. Everyone may do what everyone else is doing, even when his or her private information suggests doing something different. The sort of herding behavior corresponds to human be- havior reported by Becker (1991). When faced with two apparently very similar restaurants on either side of a street, a large majority chose one rather than the other, even though this involved waiting in line. The consequences will indeed be different due to the behavior of other agents in a society.4 An individual’s choice will then depend on his or her degree of confidence in the majority view concerning the state of the world. It is important to observe the self-reinforcing nature of confidence in the group opinion in a society. In this paper, the quality (precision) of opinions, which reflects the confidence in the majority opinion, is a central parameter. Several questions arise regarding the relationship between the quality of opinions and herd externality. Specifically, by comparing situations where each person’s decision is more or less responsive to the majority view, this paper considers how the quality of opinions has an impact on the efficiency of the long-run outcome in the social learning. The social learning model of Banerjee (1992) and Bikhchandani et al. (1992) describes the decision problem faced by a sequence of exogenously ordered individuals each acting under the state of the world.5 An agent conditions the decision in a Bayes-rational fashion on both one’s privately observed information and the ordered history of all predecessors’ decisions. The rest of the population is then allowed to choose sequentially, with each agent observing the choices made by all the predecessors. An information cascade occurs when agents ignore their own information completely and simply take the same action as predecessors have taken. The aggregate information that is available in the population is not correctly revealed by the sequence of decisions. This may eventually lead the whole 1 This terminology may be a close parallel to what Leibenstein (1950) called the “bandwagon effect” and “snob effect” in his classic study on the static market demand curve. By the bandwagon (snob) effect he referred to the extent to which the demand for a commodity is increased (decreased) because others are consuming the same commodity. 2 Note that the decision may not be optimal from the social point of view since the individual does not take account of the effect of his or her decision on the information of others. 3 See, for example, the analysis of ‘rumours’ in Banerjee (1993) and ‘fashions’ in Karni and Schmeidler (1990). 4 See also Kirman (1993) for an explanation of asymmetric aggregate behavior arising from the interaction between identical individuals. 5 Anderson and Holt (1997) induce the emergence of information cascades in a laboratory setting. Their re- sults seem to support the hypothesis that agents tend to decide by combining their private information with the information conveyed by the previous choices made by other agents, in conformity with Bayesian updating of beliefs. S. Teraji / Journal of Socio-Economics 32 (2003) 661–673 663 population to take the wrong decision, and therefore to a socially inefficient outcome. However, the formation of a cascade is strongly influenced by the initial decisions. Orléan (1995) considers the dynamics of imitative decision processes in non-sequential contexts where agents are interacting simultaneously and modifying their decisions at each period in time. Such a framework is better suited for the modeling of herd behavior. In many circumstances, agents are always present and they revise their opinions in a continuous mode, not one for all. In this setting, opinions are modified endogenously as a result of interaction between agents. He describes the herd behavior as corresponding to the stationary distribution of a stochastic process rather than to switching between multiple equilibria. In this paper, to offer a clear justification for possible equilibrium patterns, I provide an explanation for switches from one to the other in the social learning dynamics.6 It is worth to offer an equilibrium selection criterion of how a particular equilibrium will emerge collectively in a non-sequential context. In this paper, I consider a choice between two competing alternatives with unequal pay- offs, and show how individuals are likely to herd onto a single choice. I specify a sim- ple model for boundedly rational choice given the information conveyed by the majority opinion. I consider the society consisting of a continuum of agents each of whom are Bayesian optimizers. They must make a short-run commitment to the action they chose. Opportunities to switch actions arrive at random, which are identical and independent across agents.7 This friction reflects uncertainty that leads to inertia. Following this in- terpretation, no agent can change his or her choice at every point in time because of the inability to make an assessment of the current configuration of opinions continuously. It seems to capture a certain aspect of boundedly rational behavior. The social dynam- ics generate equilibrium paths of behavioral patterns in the presence of herd externality. In some situation, the stability properties of stationary states depend not on the initial decisions, but rather on the degree of quality of opinions defined below. What may be surprising is that the two stationary states, corresponding to the two long-run configu- rations of opinions, possess different stability properties when we change the quality of opinions. I show that sufficient quality of opinions tends to yield inefficient herding in the long-run. A key element is the multiplicity of equilibrium paths of behavioral patterns.8 Then one has to determine which equilibrium actually gets established. The emphasis on the quality of opinions also distinguishes my work from other explanations of equilibrium selection in economic problems (e.g. Keynesian macroeconomics in Cooper and John, 1988 and 6 Akerlof (1980) says that there are multiple equilibria in the sense that different customs, once established, could be followed in equilibrium. In one of these equilibria a custom is obeyed, and the values underlying the custom are widely subscribed to by members of the community. In the other equilibrium, the custom has disappeared, no one believes in the values underlying it, and it is not obeyed. 7 The equilibrium dynamics of this kind is used in Matsuyama (1992). However, the interpretation attached to this dynamics here is quite different. 8 The fundamental argument in the path dependency literature (David, 1985; Arthur, 1989) is that the free market typically generates sub-optimal equilibrium solutions to a variety of economic problems and the probability of sub-optimal equilibrium outcomes increases where increasing returns prevail. It is even possible for efficient and inefficient (sub-optimal) solutions to prevail simultaneously in the world of path dependency. For this reason, one cannot expect the free market to force the economy to converge to unique equilibrium. 664 S. Teraji / Journal of Socio-Economics 32 (2003) 661–673 economic development in Murphy et al., 1989; Matsuyama, 1992).9 The literature offers very few formal approaches to the process through which interacting agents’ beliefs are formed.
Recommended publications
  • A Behavioural and Neuroeconomic Analysis of Individual Differences
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Apollo Herding in Financial Behaviour: A Behavioural and Neuroeconomic Analysis of Individual Differences M. Baddeley, C. Burke, W. Schultz and P. Tobler May 2012 CWPE 1225 1 HERDING IN FINANCIAL BEHAVIOR: A BEHAVIOURAL AND NEUROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF INDIVIDUAL DIFFERENCES1,2 ABSTRACT Experimental analyses have identified significant tendencies for individuals to follow herd decisions, a finding which has been explained using Bayesian principles. This paper outlines the results from a herding task designed to extend these analyses using evidence from a functional magnetic resonance imaging (fMRI) study. Empirically, we estimate logistic functions using panel estimation techniques to quantify the impact of herd decisions on individuals' financial decisions. We confirm that there are statistically significant propensities to herd and that social information about others' decisions has an impact on individuals' decisions. We extend these findings by identifying associations between herding propensities and individual characteristics including gender, age and various personality traits. In addition fMRI evidence shows that individual differences correlate strongly with activations in the amygdala – an area of the brain commonly associated with social decision-making. Individual differences also correlate strongly with amygdala activations during herding decisions. These findings are used to construct a two stage least squares model of financial herding which confirms that individual differences and neural responses play a role in modulating the propensity to herd. Keywords: herding; social influence; individual differences; neuroeconomics; fMRI; amygdala JEL codes: D03, D53, D70, D83, D87, G11 1. Introduction Herding occurs when individuals‘ private information is overwhelmed by the influence of public information about the decisions of a herd or group.
    [Show full text]
  • Herd Behavior by Commonlit Staff 2014
    Name: Class: Herd Behavior By CommonLit Staff 2014 “Herd behavior” is a term used to describe the tendency of individuals to think and act as a group. As you read, take notes on the causes of herd behavior. Background [1] The term “herd behavior” comes from the behavior of animals in herds, particularly when they are in a dangerous situation such as escaping a predator. All of the animals band closely together in a group and, in panic mode, move together as a unit. It is very unusual for a member of the herd to stray from the movement of the unit. The term also applies to human behavior, and it usually describes large numbers of people acting the same way at the same time. It often has a "Herd of Goats" by Unknown is in the public domain. connotation1 of irrationality, as people’s actions are driven by emotion rather than by thinking through a situation. Human herd behavior can be observed at large-scale demonstrations, riots, strikes, religious gatherings, sports events, and outbreaks of mob violence. When herd behavior sets in, an individual person’s judgment and opinion- forming process shut down as he or she automatically follows the group’s movement and behavior. Examples of Herd Behavior Herd behavior in humans is frequently observed at times of danger and panic; for example, a fire in a building often causes herd behavior, with people often suspending their individual reasoning and fleeing together in a pack. People in a crisis that requires escape will attempt to move faster than normal, copy the actions of others, interact physically with each other, and ignore alternative strategies in favor of following the mass escape trend.
    [Show full text]
  • Changing People's Preferences by the State and the Law
    CHANGING PEOPLE'S PREFERENCES BY THE STATE AND THE LAW Ariel Porat* In standard economic models, two basic assumptions are made: the first, that actors are rational and, the second, that actors' preferences are a given and exogenously determined. Behavioral economics—followed by behavioral law and economics—has questioned the first assumption. This article challenges the second one, arguing that in many instances, social welfare should be enhanced not by maximizing satisfaction of existing preferences but by changing the preferences themselves. The article identifies seven categories of cases where the traditional objections to intentional preferences change by the state and the law lose force and argues that in these cases, such a change warrants serious consideration. The article then proposes four different modes of intervention in people's preferences, varying in intensity, on the one hand, and the identity of their addressees, on the other, and explains the relative advantages and disadvantages of each form of intervention. * Alain Poher Professor of Law at Tel Aviv University, Fischel-Neil Distinguished Visiting Professor of Law at the University of Chicago Law School, Visiting Professor of Law at Stanford Law School (Fall 2016) and Visiting Professor of Law at Berkeley Law School (Spring 2017). For their very helpful comments, I thank Ronen Avraham, Oren Bar-Gill, Yitzhak Benbaji, Hanoch Dagan, Yuval Feldman, Talia Fisher, Haim Ganz, Jacob Goldin, Sharon Hannes, David Heyd, Amir Khoury, Roy Kreitner, Tami Kricheli-Katz, Shai Lavi, Daphna Lewinsohn- Zamir, Nira Liberman, Amir Licht, Haggai Porat, Eric Posner, Ariel Rubinstein, Uzi Segal, and the participants in workshops at the Interdisciplinary Center in Herzliya and the Tel Aviv University Faculty of Law.
    [Show full text]
  • Conformity, Gender and the Sex Composition of the Group
    Stockholm School of Economics Department of Economics Bachelor’s Thesis Spring 2010 Conformity, Gender and the Sex Composition of the Group Abstract In light of the current debate of the sex distribution in Swedish company boards we study how a proportional increase of women would affect conformity behavior. We compare conformity levels between men and women as well as conformity levels between same-sex and mixed-sex groups. The results suggest that same-sex groups conform significantly more than mixed-sex groups due to higher levels of normative social influence. No differences are found in the levels of informational or normative social influence between men and women. These finding possibly suggest lower levels of normative social influence in company boards with more equal sex distribution. Key Words: Conformity, Gender Differences, Group Composition Authors: Makan Amini* Fredrik Strömsten** Tutor: Tore Ellingsen Examiner: Örjan Sjöberg *E-mail: [email protected] **E-mail: [email protected] Acknowledgements We would like to thank our tutor Tore Ellingsen for his guidance and inspiration during the thesis work. We would also like to express our gratitude to Magnus Johannesson and Per-Henrik Hedberg who have devoted their time to support our work through very important and helpful comments. Finally we are impressed by the large number of students from the Stockholm School of Economics who participated in the experiments. This study would of course never have been possible without you. Table of Contents 1. Introduction............................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Collective Behaviour
    COLLECTIVE BEHAVIOUR DEFINED COLLECTIVE BEHAVIOUR • The term "collective behavior" was first used by Robert E. Park, and employed definitively by Herbert Blumer, to refer to social processes and events which do not reflect existing social structure (laws, conventions, and institutions), but which emerge in a "spontaneous" way. Collective Behaviour defined • Collective behaviour is a meaning- creating social process in which new norms of behaviour that challenges conventional social action emerges. Examples of Collective Behaviour • Some examples of this type of behaviour include panics, crazes, hostile outbursts and social movements • Fads like hula hoop; crazes like Beatlemania; hostile outbursts like anti- war demonstrations; and Social Movements. • Some argue social movements are more sophisticated forms of collective behaviour SOCIAL MOVEMENTS • Social movements are a type of group action. They are large informal groupings of individuals and/or organizations focused on specific political or social issues, in other words, on carrying out, resisting or undoing a social change. CBs and SMs 19th C. ROOTS • Modern Western social movements became possible through education and the increased mobility of labour due to the industrialisation and urbanisation of 19th century societies Tilly’s DEFINITION SM • Charles Tilly defines social movements as a series of contentious performances, displays and campaigns by which ordinary people made collective claims on others [Tilly, 2004].]: Three major elements of SMs • For Tilly, social movements are a major vehicle for ordinary people's participation in public politics [Tilly, 2004:3]. • He argues that there are three major elements to a social movement [Tilly, 2004 THREE ELEMENTS OF SMs 1. Campaigns: a sustained, organized public effort making collective claims on target authorities; 2.
    [Show full text]
  • The Emergence of Animal Social Complexity
    The Emergence of Animal Social Complexity: theoretical and biobehavioral evidence Bradly Alicea Orthogonal Research (http://orthogonal-research.tumblr.com) Keywords: Social Complexity, Sociogenomics, Neuroendocrinology, Metastability AbstractAbstract ThisThis paper paper will will introduce introduce a a theorytheory ofof emergentemergent animalanimal socialsocial complexitycomplexity usingusing variousvarious results results from from computational computational models models andand empiricalempirical resultsresults.. TheseThese resultsresults willwill bebe organizedorganized into into a avertical vertical model model of of socialsocial complexity.complexity. ThisThis willwill supportsupport thethe perspperspectiveective thatthat social social complexity complexity is isin in essence essence an an emergent emergent phenomenon phenomenon while while helping helping to answerto answer of analysistwo interrelated larger than questions. the individual The first organism.of these involves The second how behavior involves is placingintegrated aggregate at units socialof analysis events larger into thethan context the individual of processes organism. occurring The secondwithin involvesindividual placing organi aggregatesms over timesocial (e.g. events genomic into the and context physiological of processes processes) occurring. withinBy using individual a complex organisms systems over perspective,time (e.g. fivegenomic principles and physiologicalof social complexity processes). can Bybe identified.using a complexThese principles systems
    [Show full text]
  • Cyberbullying Ullying Has His- Cyberbullying
    SPRING 2009 VOL. 36 NO. 108 TIInterEDInterEDHE JOURNALnter OF THE ASSOCIATIONION FOR THE ADVANCEMENEDT OF IINTERNATIONALIONAL EDUCATIONION AAIE IN THIS ISSUE Cyberbullying ullying has his- cyberbullying. Chib- President's Message --------------------------- 2 torically been re- By Barrie Jo Price, Anna C. baro (2007) states that portedB to be the most McFadden and Juanita McMath cyberbullying is one Executive Director's Message --------------- 3 common form of vic- of the most preva- Editor's Desk ------------------------------------- 4 timization in schools with over 5 million lent forms of harassment among Grade 6 students reporting being threatened physi- through Grade 8 students. Superintendent of the Year: Ladd ----------- 7 cally, verbally or indirectly every year, with that number on the rise as cyberbullying Though it may begin in elementary schools, Memo to the Board ----------------------------- 8 becomes part of a computer-mediated research indicates that Middle School stu- Recruiting & Retaining Staff -----------------11 culture (Harris, Petrie & Willoughby, dents appear to be the most frequent tar- 2002; Willard, 2006; Anderson & Sturm, gets or at least those for whom this activity Treasurer's Report ---------------------------- 12 2007). is most reported (Beale & Hall, 2007; Hin- duja & Patchin 2009). This finding, coupled Research is the Key -------------------------- 14 How frequently does cyberbullying occur? with a recent report from the Pew Research Superintendent of the Year Program ----- 17 Tonn (2006) reported on a study in which Center, shows half of all youth (in the U.S.) one third of United States (U.S.) youths online between the ages of 12 and 17 have GovNet ------------------------------------------ 19 surveyed (ages 12-17) reported experienc- a social networking account of some kind ing cyberbullying in the past 12 months, (Facebook, MySpace, etc.).
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Forecasting. Experimental Evidence on Individual Biases
    ECONOMIC FORECASTING EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE ON INDIVIDUAL BIASES, GROUP COOPERATION AND HERD BEHAVIOR Dissertation zur Erlangung des Doktorgrades der Wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Fakultät der Georg-August-Universität Göttingen vorgelegt von Lukas Meub geboren in Lich Göttingen, 2014 Erstgutachter: Prof. Dr. Kilian Bizer Zweitgutachter: Prof. Dr. Markus Spiwoks Weiteres Mitglied der Prüfungskommission: Prof. Dr. Claudia Keser CONTENTS 1 INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY 1 2 ANCHORING: A VALID EXPLANATION 21 FOR BIASED FORECASTS WHEN RATIONAL PREDICTIONS ARE EASILY ACCESSIBLE AND WELL INCENTIVIZED? (with Till Proeger and Kilian Bizer) 3 AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY ON SOCIAL ANCHORING 49 (with Till Proeger) 4 ARE GROUPS LESS BEHAVIORAL? 75 THE CASE OF ANCHORING (with Till Proeger) 5 OVERCONFIDENCE AS A SOCIAL BIAS: 109 EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE (with Till Proeger) 6 STRATEGIC COORDINATION IN FORECASTING: 123 AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY (with Kilian Bizer, Till Proeger and Markus Spiwoks) 7 A COMPARISON OF ENDOGENOUS AND EXOGENOUS 169 TIMING IN A SOCIAL LEARNING EXPERIMENT (with Till Proeger and Hendrik Hüning) 8 THE IMPACT OF COMMUNICATION REGIMES 201 ON GROUP RATIONALITY: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE (with Till Proeger) V VI Chapter I INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY - 1 - - 2 - “Much has been written about the doubtful accuracy of economists’ predictions. [...] They are better at predicting the direction than the actual magnitude of events. [...] This is disappointing, but it does not mean that economics is not a science.” (‘Economics’, Encyclopædia Britannica1) The forecasting of economic developments guides decisions in all areas of public interest, whether in governments, finance or corporations.2 Accurate predictions hold an essential role for private and public actors’ ability to enable the efficient planning and execution of their strategic objectives.
    [Show full text]
  • Digital Interaction and Empathy. the Challenges and Opportunities of Combining Technology with Artificial Intelligence
    Expert report Digital interaction and empathy. The challenges and opportunities of combining technology with artificial intelligence. 29 April 2019 PREFACE People are profoundly social creatures. Every day, we think together? At best, joint thinking can be compared to opment into an effectively interacting individual takes many wonder what other people think of us. Despite knowing that running a kilometer in just one minute, which sounds impos­ times as long as for other animals. It has been suggested that lying is wrong, we do so to make a better impression on oth­ sible. For individuals it is indeed impossible, but joint think­ this is because there is so much to learn in mutual interac­ ers. Some researchers believe that reason evolved so that we ing based on effective interaction makes things possible that tion. could make arguments for, and justify, solutions that we had seemed impossible at first. already chosen. In so far as our capabilities allow, we are all responsible We humans do not always use our opportunities construc­ for how we treat each other. Such a responsibility applies The latest technological developments challenge people tively. We intentionally offend one another, build threat sce­ even when we are not face­to­face with the other person. to consider their own strengths, those abilities which are so narios and behave nastily and unpleasantly towards others. unique that a machine cannot be programmed to replicate Such behavior can have serious consequences. For a child, The new social media environments and the Internet in them. Such strengths involve creative, unpredictable solu­ it can result in life­long trauma.
    [Show full text]
  • The Asian-European Agenda Ideas for Crisis Prevention and Effective Cooperation
    Kerry Brown, Heungchong Kim, Françoise Nicolas, Michael Reiterer, Michito Tsuoroka, Lay Hwee Yeo, Hong Zhou The Asian-European Agenda Ideas for Crisis Prevention and Effective Cooperation Europe in Dialogue 2012 | 04 Address | Contact: Bertelsmann Stiftung Carl-Bertelsmann-Straße 256 P.O. Box 103 33311 Gütersloh GERMANY Phone +49 5241 81-0 Fax +49 5241 81-81999 The Asian-European Agenda Armando Garcia Schmidt Phone +49 5241 81-81543 E-Mail [email protected] 2012 | 04 Joachim Fritz-Vannahme Phone +49 5241 81-81421 E-Mail [email protected] Europe in Dialogue www.bertelsmann-stiftung.org The European Way of Life Europe in Dialogue Europeans can be proud as they look back on fi fty years of peaceful integration. Nowa- In “The European Way of Life” the Bertelsmann Stif- days many people worldwide see the European Union as a model of how states and their tung looks back at what the European Union has citizens can work together in peace and freedom. However, this achievement does not already achieved, and sets its sights on the future. automatically mean that the EU has the ability to deal with the problems of the future What are the challenges to which European po- in a rapidly changing world. The European Union must continue developing its unity in licymaking will have to rise in the years ahead? diversity dynamically, be it with regard to energy issues, the euro, climate change or new How can the European project be given a new types of confl ict. Indeed, self-assertion and solidarity are key to the debates shaping our lease of life? Europeans tend to be rather critical future.
    [Show full text]
  • Herding in Humans
    Review Herding in humans Ramsey M. Raafat1,2, Nick Chater1,2 and Chris Frith3,4 1 Cognitive, Perceptual and Brain Sciences research department, University College London, Gower Street, London WC1E 6BT, UK 2 ESRC Centre for Economic Learning and Social Evolution (ELSE), Drayton House, Gordon Street, London WC1H OAN 3 Wellcome Trust Centre for Neuroimaging at University College London, 12 Queen Square, London WC1N 3BG, UK 4 Niels Bohr Project ‘‘Interacting Minds’’, Centre for Functionally Integrative Neuroscience, Aarhus University Hospital, 8000 Aarhus C, Denmark Herding is a form of convergent social behaviour that can been investigated in social psychology and terms such as be broadly defined as the alignment of the thoughts or Fad, Fashion, Mass Hysteria, Bandwagon Effect, Group- behaviours of individuals in a group (herd) through local think and Herd Instinct have entered common parlance. interaction and without centralized coordination. We Whereas the concepts behind herd mentality and herd suggest that herding has a broad application, from behaviour have a rich history (Table 1), the methods, intellectual fashion to mob violence; and that under- techniques and approaches currently used to elucidate them standing herding is particularly pertinent in an increas- are relatively recent. In this article we review the extensive ingly interconnected world. An integrated approach to range of theoretical frameworks for describing herding. herding is proposed, describing two key issues: mech- Similar ideas and explanations have emerged in many anisms of transmission of thoughts or behaviour be- fields, albeit with different emphases, demonstrating the tween agents, and patterns of connections between interdisciplinary nature of the concept. We propose a frame- agents.
    [Show full text]
  • Herd Behavior and Individuals' Information System Behaviors
    HERD BEHAVIOR AND INDIVIDUALS’ INFORMATION SYSTEM BEHAVIORS: USAGE, ABANDONMENT, AND EXPLORATION INTENTIONS By Mirmahdi Darbanhosseiniamirkhiz (Mehdi Darban) A dissertation submitted in partial fuLfiLLment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy (Management & Information Systems) Department of Management & Information Systems 2018 DoctoraL Committee: Dr. Greta Polites, Chair Dr. Mary Hogue Dr. Dong-Heon Kwak Dr. Christopher Groening Dissertation written by: Mirmahdi Darbanhosseiniamirkhiz B.S., University of Tabriz, 1999 M.B.A., University TechnoLogy MaLaysia, 2013 Ph.D., Kent State University, 2018 Approved by: Dr. Greta Polites Chair, DoctoraL Dissertation Committee Dr. Mary Hogue Member, DoctoraL Dissertation Committee Dr. Dong-Heon Kwak Member, DoctoraL Dissertation Committee Dr. Christopher Groening Member, DoctoraL Dissertation Committee Accepted by: DoctoraL Director, Graduate Programs Dean, Graduate Programs TABLE OF CONTENTS TABLE OF CONTENTS ........................................................................................................................................... iii LIST OF TABLES ...................................................................................................................................................... vii LIST OF FIGURES ................................................................................................................................................... viii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ......................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]