Personal Carbon Allowances Revisited
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Shadow Price of Carbon in Economic Analysis Guidance Note
Guidance note on shadow price of carbon in economic analysis Nov 12, 2017 Shadow price of carbon in economic analysis Guidance note This guidance note is intended to help World Bank staff value carbon emissions in economic analysis of investment project financing. The economic analysis is requested under Operational Policy and Bank Procedure (OP/BP) 10.00. The guidance provided in this note aims to enhance the economic analysis by using the shadow price of carbon for applicable projects. It replaces the 2014 “Social Value of Carbon in Project Appraisal Guidance Note”. The note will be updated and complemented from time to time, based on new knowledge and feedback from teams. Applicability The use of shadow price of carbon in the economic analysis is a corporate commitment1 for all IBRD/IDA investment project financing that are subject to GHG accounting. GHG accounting is undertaken for IBRD/IDA investment lending projects in Global Practices with Bank approved GHG accounting methodologies. Projects that are not subject to GHG accounting do not have to use the shadow price of carbon in the economic analysis.2 The corporate commitment to apply shadow price of carbon in economic analysis is effective for projects with concept notes approved on or after July 1, 2017. Projects that are not subject to GHG accounting are invited to use shadow price of carbon in the economic analysis, on a voluntary basis. Background In 2015, the world came together and agreed to limit global warming to less than 2ºC by 2100, and make best efforts to limit warming to 1.5ºC. -
Using Cap and Share to Control Emissions from the EU Transport Sector
Using Cap and Share to control emissions from the EU transport sector Executive Summary. Cap and Share is a cap and trade system in which tradable rights to whatever is being capped are distributed on an equal-per-person basis to every adult in the general population rather than being auctioned or being grandfathered (given) to existing users. Because those receiving the rights under C&S sell them within a year of receipt, it automatically compensates the least-well- off in society for the price rises that the shortages brought about by the imposition of the cap inevitably generate. This fairness and built-in fiscal neutrality make it a more politically acceptable way to control emissions than other allocation methods. Carbon dioxide emissions from all forms of transport apart from rail are rising within the EU at a time when those from other sectors are falling. Within the transport sector, emissions from road vehicles are rising most rapidly in absolute terms. However, the EU emissions trading system is unsuited to controlling them because of the way it was designed. As only aviation and marine emissions can be taken into the ETS with reasonable ease, this is what the Commission is proposing to do. This paper argues that capping some transport emissions and not others would be a serious mistake because the various transport modes are in competition with each other. Not only would the Commission's proposals distort competition between the modes but, because of the short-term inelasticity of the demand for transport, they are unlikely to cause total transport emissions to fall. -
Personal Carbon Trading
Personal carbon trading Tina Fawcett, Environmental Change Institute, University of Oxford [email protected] Yael Parag, School of Sustainability, IDC Herzliya [email protected] Aims of presentation 1. Introduce the concept of personal carbon trading and the mechanisms by which it could deliver change. 2. Summarise research evidence and ongoing research activity. 3. Suggest how this idea can be taken forward. Personal carbon trading • Equal allowances for adults • Reducing annual allowance, signaled well in advance • Tradable • To include personal transport & household energy use • Mandatory • By electronic card Inspired by “Contraction and Convergence” (www.gci.org.uk) How would PCT work? Economic behaviour Carbon price signal, Incentive to maximise External benefits constraint Emissions Reduction Intrinsic Energy PCT Carbon perception Demand Allocation, visibility, Reduction awareness, budgeting motivation Social support Social norms (new) definition of acceptable personal carbon consumption From: Parag, Capstick and Poortinga (2011) Some research findings In theory, PCT is a serious alternative to increased energy taxation, with some understanding of what institutions and systems would be needed to introduce it. Overall, PCT should be a progressive policy, but some poorer individuals will be worse off. Given the (theoretical) choice between PCT and increased carbon taxation, more people say they favour PCT. Technology to enable an electronic card PCT system already exists. PCT would cost more to introduce than upstream trading or direct taxation. Current research Good News NICHE trial in Australia – the Norfolk Island Carbon / Health Evaluation Study “the first real test of Personal Carbon Trading in the world” “Orlem ai orn Norf'k. 350 people registered for the trial, electronic carbon Liiden d' wieh tu wan accounting system, rewards for participation, energy sastienebl fyuutcha. -
How to Price Carbon to Reach Net-Zero Emissions in the UK
How to price carbon to reach net-zero emissions in the UK Joshua Burke, Rebecca Byrnes and Sam Fankhauser Policy report May 2019 The Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy (CCCEP) was established in 2008 to advance public and private action on climate change through rigorous, innovative research. The Centre is hosted jointly by the University of Leeds and the London School of Economics and Political Science. It is funded by the UK Economic and Social Research Council. More information about the ESRC Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy can be found at: www.cccep.ac.uk The Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment was established in 2008 at the London School of Economics and Political Science. The Institute brings together international expertise on economics, as well as finance, geography, the environment, international development and political economy to establish a world-leading centre for policy-relevant research, teaching and training in climate change and the environment. It is funded by the Grantham Foundation for the Protection of the Environment, which also funds the Grantham Institute – Climate Change and the Environment at Imperial College London. More information about the Grantham Research Institute can be found at: www.lse.ac.uk/GranthamInstitute About the authors Joshua Burke is a Policy Fellow and Rebecca Byrnes a Policy Officer at the Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment. Sam Fankhauser is the Institute’s Director and Co- Director of CCCEP. Acknowledgements This work benefitted from financial support from the Grantham Foundation for the Protection of the Environment, and from the UK Economic and Social Research Council through its support of the Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy. -
Emissions Gap Report 2018 © 2018 United Nations Environment Programme November 2018
Emissions Gap Report 2018 © 2018 United Nations Environment Programme November 2018 ISBN: 978-92-807-3726-4 Job number: DEW/2210/NA This publication may be reproduced in whole or in part and in any form for educational or non-profit services without special permission from the copyright holder, provided acknowledgement of the source is made. UN Environment would appreciate receiving a copy of any publication that uses this publication as a source. No use of this publication may be made for resale or any other commercial purpose whatsoever without prior permission in writing from UN Environment. Applications for such permission, with a statement of the purpose and extent of the reproduction, should be addressed to the Director, Communication Division, UN Environment, P. O. Box 30552, Nairobi 00100, Kenya. The designations employed and the presentation of the material in this publication do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of United Nations Environment Programme concerning the legal status of any country, territory or city or its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. For general guidance on matters relating to the use of maps in publications please go to http://www.un.org/Depts/Cartographic/english/htmain.htm Disclaimers Mention of a commercial company or product in this document does not imply endorsement by UN Environment or the authors. The use of information from this document for publicity or advertising is not permitted. Trademark names and symbols are used in an editorial fashion with no intention on infringement of trademark or copyright laws. -
Putting a Price on Carbon with an ETS
Putting a Price on Carbon with an ETS Summary of Key Findings: • An ETS is an explicit carbon pricing instrument that limits or caps the allowed amount of GHG emissions and lets market forces disclose the carbon price through emitters trading emissions allowances. • 35 countries (incl. 28 in the EU) and 20 subnational jurisdictions have adopted emissions trading programs. Defining Emissions Trading Schemes (ETS) An ETS – or cap-and-trade program – is managed by a governing jurisdiction that sets a limit or a cap on the total level of covered GHG emissions – including CO2. The allowances to emit are distributed to liable entities (direct emission sources or others) that must redeem allowances for every emitted ton of CO2, with the possibility to buy additional allowances or sell unused ones. As liable entities consider the cost of their emissions within their production processes and the possibility to buy or sell allowances, a market for CO2 emerges, setting a price on CO2 that acts as a reduction incentive for all liable entities. This price influences decisions both in the short-term management of existing assets and in the longer-term direction of investments. 1 An ETS – as opposed to a tax – is a quantity-based policy, i.e., it offers certainty over the environmental outcome (i.e., “cap”) but leaves it to the market (i.e., “trade”) to set the price of carbon. ETS around the World Emissions trading was first experimented in the United States, through an amendment to the U.S Clean Air Act (1990) that introduced a market-based regulation to control sulfur dioxide emissions from coal- burning electric utility plants – the primary cause of acid rain. -
Carbon Prices Under Carbon Market
Carbon prices under carbon market scenarios consistent with the Paris Agreement: Implications for the Carbon Offsetting and Reduction Scheme for International Aviation (CORSIA) Analysis conducted by Pedro Piris-Cabezas, Ruben Lubowski and Gabriela Leslie of the Environmental Defense Fund (EDF)* 20 March 2018 Executive Summary This report analyzes alternative scenarios for the demand for and supply of greenhouse gas emissions units and the resulting carbon price ranges facing the Carbon Offsetting and Reduction Scheme for International Aviation (CORSIA). The International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO), the United Nations specialized agency for international air transport, agreed on CORSIA in 2016 as part of a package of policies to help achieve its goal of carbon-neutral growth for international aviation over 2021-2035.1 The current study explicitly examines emissions unit demand and supply in the context of broader carbon markets expected to emerge as the 2015 Paris Agreement2 moves forward. The projected demand for emissions units from the implementation of CORSIA is based on an interactive tool from the Environmental Defense Fund (EDF) that estimates overall coverage and demand from CORSIA in light of current levels of anticipated participation.3 We estimate carbon prices by applying EDF’s carbon market modeling framework to consider various scenarios for domestic and international emission trading. The EDF carbon market tool balances demand and supply of emissions reductions from multiple sources and sectors in a dynamic framework. We examine the price of emissions reduction units in CORSIA in a context where airlines will face competing demand for units from other sectors covered under each nation’s current Nationally Determined Contributions (NDC) pledges. -
Personal Carbon Trading and British Columbia's Climate Policy
Beyond the Carbon Tax: Personal Carbon Trading and British Columbia's Climate Policy by Laura Isela Guzmán Flores B.A., Universidad Tecnológica de México, 1999 Thesis Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Arts IN THE DEPARTMENT OF GEOGRAPHY FACULTY OF ENVIRONMENT Laura I. Guzmán 2014 SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Summer 2014 All rights reserved. However, in accordance with the Copyright Act of Canada, this work may be reproduced, without authorization, under the conditions for “Fair Dealing.” Therefore, limited reproduction of this work for the purposes of private study, research, criticism, review and news reporting is likely to be in accordance with the law, particularly if cited appropriately. Approval Name: Laura Isela Guzmán Flores Degree: Master of Arts (Geography) Title of Thesis: Beyond the Carbon Tax: Personal Carbon Trading and British Columbia's Climate Policy Examining Committee: Chair: Janet Sturgeon Associate Professor Alex Clapp Senior Supervisor Associate Professor Mark Jaccard Supervisor Professor School of Resource and Environmental Management Stephanie Bertels Internal Examiner Assistant Professor Beedie School of Business Date Defended: August 11th, 2014. ii Partial Copyright License iii Ethics Statement iv Abstract This thesis proposes a policy framing, communication and implementation model for personal carbon trading in British Columbia. Personal carbon trading is a scheme under which all individuals are allocated a number of free carbon allowances forming a personal carbon budget. Persons whose carbon emissions are lower than their carbon budgets can sell their surplus to persons who have exceeded theirs. As distributed allowances are reduced annually, consumers are encouraged to modify their behaviour and/or adopt technologies in order not to exceed their carbon budget. -
FEASTA Submission to …
Submission of Evidence to the ERFA Committee’s examination of international climate policy post-2012 Executive Summary ● There is an urgent need for climate action but the UNFCCC process is moving at a snail's pace. It has become a Gordian Knot of complexity. A simpler process could cut through the knot and lead to a climate treaty being achieved in a relatively short period. ● The overall goals of the process need to be established. If these can be kept simple, it is much easier for competing schemes to be compared and for existing schemes such as the EU ETS to be used to achieve them. ● Simple schemes are also the easiest to explain and communicate. So far, the public has been unable to follow the UNFCCC process because it is just too involved. ● Equitable schemes are the hardest to oppose and so have the greatest chance of success. ● The ideal climate proposal should therefore be simple and equitable. A simple and equitable scheme is proposed in this paper. This is Cap and Share, a development of the well-known Contraction and Convergence approach. 1.Introduction 1.1 FEASTA is the Foundation for the Economics of Sustainability. It is based in Dublin and has an international membership (see www.feasta.org). Our evidence here relates mainly to items 1, 3 and 7 in the EFRA Committee’s list of issues in its Call for Evidence. 2. Background 2.1 There is a clear consensus that there is an urgent need to take effective action to limit the extent of climate change. -
The Pathway to a Green New Deal: Synthesizing Transdisciplinary Literatures and Activist Frameworks to Achieve a Just Energy Transition
The Pathway to a Green New Deal: Synthesizing Transdisciplinary Literatures and Activist Frameworks to Achieve a Just Energy Transition Shalanda H. Baker and Andrew Kinde The “Green New Deal” resolution introduced into Congress by Representative Alexandria Ocasio Cortez and Senator Ed Markey in February 2019 articulated a vision of a “just” transition away from fossil fuels. That vision involves reckoning with the injustices of the current, fossil-fuel based energy system while also creating a clean energy system that ensures that all people, especially the most vulnerable, have access to jobs, healthcare, and other life-sustaining supports. As debates over the resolution ensued, the question of how lawmakers might move from vision to implementation emerged. Energy justice is a discursive phenomenon that spans the social science and legal literatures, as well as a set of emerging activist frameworks and practices that comprise a larger movement for a just energy transition. These three discourses—social science, law, and practice—remain largely siloed and insular, without substantial cross-pollination or cross-fertilization. This disconnect threatens to scuttle the overall effort for an energy transition deeply rooted in notions of equity, fairness, and racial justice. This Article makes a novel intervention in the energy transition discourse. This Article attempts to harmonize the three discourses of energy justice to provide a coherent framework for social scientists, legal scholars, and practitioners engaged in the praxis of energy justice. We introduce a framework, rooted in the theoretical principles of the interdisciplinary field of energy justice and within a synthesized framework of praxis, to assist lawmakers with the implementation of Last updated December 12, 2020 Professor of Law, Public Policy and Urban Affairs, Northeastern University. -
Oriental Despotism. a Comparative Study of Total Power. New Haven: Yale University Press
credo – economic beliefs in a world in crisis Wittfogel, K. A. (1957). Oriental Despotism. A Comparative Study of Total Power. New Haven: Yale University Press. Index Wkipedia. (2013, August). Kaldor-Hicks Efficiency. Retrieved December 29th, 2013, from Wkipedia: Abatement cost conceived of like an insurance premium, 381 Australian aboriginal people, 118, 129, 131 https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Kaldor%E2%80%93Hicks_efficiency Aborigines and land care, 118-131 Austrian economists, 64, 176, 296, 312, 314 Adaptation level, 53 Austrian school, 311 WorkingGroup1. (2013). IPCC Process. Retrieved January 3rd, 2014, from Inter-governmental Panel on Advertisers, 71, 75-76 Authenticity, 80, 83, 354 Climate Change: http://www.climatechange2013.org/ipcc-process/ Advertising, 73-77, 79-80, 88, 97, 237, 301, 351 Autistic economics, 54, 435 Xenophon, & Dakyns(Tr), H. H. (2013, January). The Economist. Retrieved December 31st, 2013, from Affluenza, 80, 83-84, 95, 420, 444 Autonomy, 12, 124, 234, 321, 437 Project Gutenberg: http://www.gutenberg.org/files/1173/1173-h/1173-h.htm Age of Commerce, 29-30, 122, 127, 152 Autopoiesis, 124 Agricultural policy, 157 ‘Bads’ and goods, 414 Yan, K. (2012, February 2nd). The Global CDM Hydro Hall of Shame. Retrieved January 3rd, 2014, from China, 15, 23, 79, 157-158, 195, 198, 226, 291, 297, 379, 440 Banks, 99, 173, 230, 289, 291, 293, 315, 325, 328, 331, 335-337, 339-340, 343-344, 346, 352-354, 356-360, 362-363, 366 International Rivers: http://www.internationalrivers.org/blogs/246/the-global-cdm-hydro-hall-of-shame Ming sheng, 157 Bank credit creation, 173, 335, 339 Mughal India, 157 Bank reform, 354-365 Young, R., Cowe, A., Nunan, C., Harvey, J., & Mason, L. -
Climate Curriculum Learning Outcomes NOV19.Indd
CLIMATE What should young people know about 1 13 ACTION The Big Ideas: Climate Action by the time they leave school? Climate Curriculum Learning Outcomes KEY IDEAS SCIENTIFIC BACKGROUND By the end of Year 2: By the end of Year 4: By the end of Year 6: By the end of Year 9: By the end of Year 11: → Pupils understand that → Pupils understand that → Pupils can clearly → Students can clearly explain → Students can name a range of some human activity burning coal, oil and articulate the link the scientific consensus that greenhouse gases and describe in causes pollution in the gas has an impact on between burning human burning of fossil fuels is detail the processes that lead to air which is affecting the the climate and have a fossil fuels and the main and original cause of their increasing concentrations in world’s climate / making basic understanding of climate change using today’s climate change the atmosphere the world hotter the scientific processes appropriate scientific Students can describe Students know where uncertainties involved vocabulary → → → Pupils understand the processes that undermine or remain in climate science, e.g. how distinction between → Pupils are familiar with → Pupils can name key boost carbon sinks atmospheric water vapour will ‘weather’ and ‘climate’ the terms ‘atmosphere’, carbon sinks such as change; when tipping points may Students are aware that in ‘Climate Change’ forests, peatlands, → be reached; climate inertia; how Pupils know that the the public arena there are → and ‘greenhouse gas oceans, algal blooms,