Antitrust Market Definition: an Integrated Approach

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Antitrust Market Definition: an Integrated Approach California Law Review VOL. 72 JANUARY 1984 No. 1 Copyright 0 1983 by California Law Review, Inc. Antitrust Market Definition: An Integrated Approach Robert G. Harris and Thomas M. Jorde TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE I. INTRODUCTION ............................................ 3 A. The Importance of Market Definition in Antitrust ...... 3 B. An IntegratedApproach io Market Definition .......... .6 II. "PROTECTED INTEREST" ORIENTATION IN MARKET DEFINITION .............................................. 8 A. Public Policy Criteriaand Antitrust Objectives ......... 9 1. Fairness........................................... 9 2 Equity ............................................ 10 3. Efficiency ......................................... 11 B. Benefts of a Fairnessand Equity-BasedApproach ..... 11 C. Protection of Buyer and Seller Interests ............... 14 1. Protection of Buyer Interests ...................... 14 2. Protection of Seller Interests ....................... 16 D. A "ProtectedInterest" Orientationin Market Defnition ............................................. 18 III. MARKET TRANSACTIONAL ORIENTATION IN MARKET D EFINITION ............................................... 20 A. The InstitutionalNature of Markets ................... 22 1. Types of Markets ................................. 22 2 Diferences Between Auction and Nonauction M arkets ........................................... 24 a. The Nature of the Exchange ................... 24 CALIFORVIA LAW PEVIEWV [Vol. 72:1 b. Relations Between Buyers and Sellers .......... 24 c. Transaction Costs............... ......... 25 . Buyers ..................................... 25 &. Sellers ..................................... 25 d Interconnectedness ............................. 26 B. Behavior of Buyers and Sellers in Markets ............ 27 1. The "Satisficing" Model ........................... 28 2 Market Defnition, Satiqfcing, and the Transaction Problem .......................................... 29 C. Use of TransactionalOrientation in Market D o nition ............................................. 31 IV. BURDEN-SHIFTING ORIENTATION IN MARKET D EFIN ITION ............................................... 34 A. The Stages of Burden Shifting ........................ 35 B. Just4cationfor Burden Shifting ....................... 37 1. Policies in Support of Burden Shifting ............. 37 2 Cases Employing the Burden-ShiftingApproach .... 39 C The Government as Plaintiff........................... 41 V. IMPLEMENTATION OF THE INTEGRATED APPROACH TO MARKET DEFINITION ..................................... 42 A. The Plaint~i(sPrima Facie Market Defnition ......... 42 L Identfcation of ProtectedInterests ................ 43 2 Identftation of RelatedMarkets and Market Particpants....................................... 45 3. Definition of a Relevant Product or Geographic M arket ........................................... 46 a. The Product Market ........................... 46 b. The Geographic Market ........................ 47 4. Calculation of Relevant Market Share ............. 51 B. The Defendant's Rebuttal Burden ..................... 53 1. Rebutting the Prima Facie Case Directly ........... 54 2 Proofof Potential Competition ..................... 56 a. Diversion ofAdditional Supply .................. 57 b. Expansion ofAdditional Supply ................ 59 c. New Production Sources of Additional Supply 61 C. The Plaintiff's Response ............................... 62 D. Special Problems Related to InternationalTrade ...... 62 E Applicability of the IntegratedApproach to Market Defnition ............................................. 64 L Consistent Application of the Approach ............ 64 2. Market Defnition and Market Power .............. 65 CONCLUSION ................................................... 66 1984] ANTITRUST MARKET DEFINITION Antitrust Market Definition: An Integrated Approach Robert G. Harrist and Thomas M. Jordet I INTRODUCTION A. The Importance of Market Defnition in Antitrust Congress enacted the antitrust laws to promote and preserve com- petition, based on the belief that an economic system organized around competitive markets is most likely to further several important objec- tives. Buyers receive fair prices and an adequate range of product and service choices. Sellers obtain entrepreneurial opportunity and a mar- ketplace that supports competition on the merits. Allocative and pro- ductive efficiency, and democratic values advance as a result of the dispersion of economic, social, and political power.1 To promote the process of competition and these objectives, the antitrust laws prohibit aggregations and exercises of horizontal market power and vertical ar- t Professor of Business Administration, University of California, Berkeley. B.A. 1965, M.A. 1973, Michigan State University; Ph.D. 1977, University of California, Berkeley. t Professor of Law, Boalt Hall School of Law, University of California, Berkeley. B.A. 1969, J.D. 1972, Yale University. * The authors gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments of Alan A. Fisher, Daniel Furniss, Robert H. Lande, Howard Latin, Mark LeHocky, Joel Linzner, and Lawrence A. Sullivan. 1. See W. SHEPHERD, THE TREATMENT OF MARKET POWER 3, 5, 183-224 (1975); L. SULLI- VAN, HANDBOOK OF THE LAW OF ANTITRUST § 1, at 10 (1977); id § 5, at 20-21; Dougherty & Davidson, Limitation Without Regulatiox The FTC'S Bureau of Competition Approach to Con- glomerate Mergers, 1980 UTAH L. Rev. 95; Flynn, Antitrust Jurisprudence: Symposium on the Economic, Politicaland Social Goals of Antitrust: Introduction, 125 U. PA. L. REv. 1182 (1977); Joffe, BeyondAntitrust, 28 CATH. U.L. REv. 1 (1978); Jorde, The Seventh Amendment Right to Jury TrialofAntirust Issues, 69 CALIF. L. REv. 1, 36 (1981); Pitofsky, The PoliticalContent of.4ntitrust, 127 U. PA. L. REv. 1051, 1066 (1979); Schwartz, "Justice"andOther Non-Economic Goals ofAnti- trust, 127 U. PA. L. Rev. 1076 (1979); Sullivan, Economics andMore HumanisticDisciplines: What Are the Sources of WisdomforAntitrust?, 125 U. PA. L. REv. 1214 (1977). Brodley, Book Review, 24 STAN. L. REv. 1155 (1972) (reviewing J. McGEE, IN DEFENSE OF INDUSTRIAL CONCENTRA- TION (1971)); Dewey, Book Review, 87 YALE LJ. 1516 (1978) (reviewing R. BORIC, THE ANTI- TRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF (1978)); First, Book Review, 52 N.Y.U. L. REv. 947 (1977) (reviewing R. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW: AN ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE (1976)); Scher- er, Book Review, 86 YALE L.J. 974 (1977) (reviewing R. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW: AN Eco- NOMIC PERSPECTIVE (1976)). CALIFORNIA LAW REVIEW[o [Vol. 72:1 rangements that may foreclose markets.2 Certain antitrust offenses, such as horizontal price fixing3 and market division,4 as well as vertical price fixing,5 are considered so pernicious that they are deemed per se unreasonable restraints of trade, and require no proof of market power or market foreclosure. In all other cases, however, horizontal market power or vertical market restraints must be proved to establish liability. In such cases, to provide a basis for measuring market power or fore- closure,6 it is necessary to define the "relevant market."' 7 Market definition in antitrust is thus not an end in itself. The pur- pose of defining a market is to help measure a firm's power over price and output, or its power to foreclose markets. If it were possible to prove such power directly, definition of the relevant market would not be necessary. Theoretically at least, market power could be proved solely by evidence of predatory conduct,' excessive profits,9 price-cost margins,10 price discrimination,1" or elasticities of supply and de- mand.12 However, practical problems of acquiring and presenting proof of these alternative indicators of market power have caused liti- gants and courts alike generally to abandon such efforts.13 In most cases, therefore, market definition is a necessary step in the measure- ment of market power. To facilitate proof and to provide a rough approximation of mar- ket power in an adversarial system, courts have adopted a market structure method of analysis. First, the court defines a relevant market in terms of product and geographic space. The court then measures individual firm shares and industry concentration levels in that market. Courts have discussed and used this method of relevant market defini- tion and market power inference in antitrust cases involving monop- 2. Sherman Antitrust Act, ch. 647, §§ 1-7, 26 Stat. 209, 209-10 (1890) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7 (1982)); Clayton Act, ch. 323, 38 Stat. 730 (1914) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 12-27 (1982)); Federal Trade Commission Act, ch. 311, 38 Stat. 717 (1914) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 41-58 (1982)). 3. See, ag., United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 218 (1940). 4. See, eg., United States v. Topo Assocs., 405 U.S. 596, 608 (1972). 5. See, ag., Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145 (1968). 6. See Jorde, supra note 1, at 43-52. 7. See, e.g., Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 324 (1962). 8. See, e.g., United States v. American Tobacco Co., 221 U.S. 106 (1911); Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911); L. SULLIVAN, supra note 1, § 6, at 23-24; id. § 9, at 33; Flynn, Monopolization Under the ShermanAct: The Third Wave andBeyond, 26 ANTITRUST BULL. 1, 31- 32 (1981). 9. 2 P. AREFDA & D. TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW g 508, 512 (1978). 10. Id. 1 509, 513. 11. Id. 514. 12. See, ag., Landes & Posner, Market Power in Antitrust Cases, 94 HARV. L. Rnv. 937 (1981). 13. See Jorde, supra note 1, at 40-41.
Recommended publications
  • Twelve Fallacies of the “Neo-Antitrust” Movement
    TWELVE FALLACIES OF THE “NEO-ANTITRUST” MOVEMENT Seth B. Sacher John M. Yun Antonin Scalia Law School, George Mason University George Mason University Law & Economics Research Paper Series 19-12 This paper is available on the Social Science Research Network at ssrn.com/abstract=3369013 TWELVE FALLACIES OF THE “NEO-ANTITRUST” MOVEMENT Seth B. Sachera and John M. Yunb Antonin Scalia Law School George Mason University May 1, 2019 Abstract Antitrust enforcement is back in the spotlight with advocates from both the political left and the populist political right demanding fundamental competition policy changes. While there are differences among those calling for such changes, several common beliefs generally unite them. This includes a contention that the writings and interpretations of Robert Bork and the Chicago School of economics have led antitrust astray in a manner fundamentally inconsistent with the original intent of the Sherman Act. Further, they are united by a belief that recent empirical, economic studies indicate the economy is becoming overly concentrated, that market power has been increasing dramatically, that performance in many, if not most, markets has been deficient, and that too much profit is going to too few firms. In this article, we identify and detail twelve fallacies of what we call the “neo-antitrust movement” and their associated claims. At the heart of these fallacies is a fundamental misunderstanding of economics and the consumer welfare standard that has been at the heart of competition policy since at least the 1960s. Additionally, there is a heavy reliance on studies that, upon closer scrutiny, do not support the positions of those who cite them.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Introduction
    1 Introduction The Australian Energy Market Agreement (AEMA) establishes a process for the Australian Energy Market Commission (AEMC or ‘the Commission’) to assess and provide advice to the Ministerial Council on Energy (MCE) on competition in the retail electricity and natural gas markets of jurisdictions for the purpose of phasing out retail price regulation where effective retail competition is demonstrated (clause 14.11).1 1.1 Revisions to Statement of Approach In response to a request for advice by the MCE, this Statement of Approach sets out the proposed methodology and consultation approach the AEMC will adopt in conducting the retail competition reviews. The AEMC has previously prepared and published versions of the Statement of Approach which have been applied to the retail competition reviews undertaken in Victoria in 2007, South Australia in 2008 and the Australian Capital Territory in 2010. Over time, the MCE, in consultation with the AEMC, has periodically approved revisions and updates to the Statement of Approach to reflect developments and reforms in energy markets and revised timings of the AEMC’s remaining jurisdictional reviews. This latest MCE approved version of the Statement of Approach has been prepared for application to the New South Wales retail competition review in 2012-13. 1.2 Scope The scope of the competition reviews is set out in clauses 14.11(a) and (c) of the AEMA (see Appendix A). According to the AEMA, the aim of the competition reviews is to assess the effectiveness of competition in the electricity and gas retail markets for the purpose of the retention, removal or reintroduction of retail energy price controls.
    [Show full text]
  • Comparative Market Structures in Developing Countries
    380. 141 LI7" M671 No. 75 i"J- _ , Comparative Market Structures In Developing Countries by Marvin Miracle The University of Wisconsin LAND TENURE CENTER Madison, Wisconsin 53706 Comparative Market Structures in Developing Countries. 380.14i Wisconsir Uniro Lard Tenure Center. NTIS M671 Comparative Market Structures in Devel­ j)b oping'hp. Cou;triesoMarvh-7 P. Miracle. 19'0° I-,r /0L6 Bibliographic footnotes. C LTC Repriit -,o, 75. i. Markets. 2. Capital markets. 3. Marketing - Agricultural commodities, I. Miracle, Marvin P. IT. Title. Reprinted from Nebraska Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 9, No. 4, Autumn 1970. Copyright by the University of Nebraska, 1970 COMPARATIVE MARKET STRUCTURES IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES* Marvin Miracle Associate Professor,Departmentof AgriculturalEconomics and Chairman,African Studies Program Universityof Wisconsin Market structures in developing countries arc of interest for a number of reasons. Apart from the possibility that market structure may have an important impact on the rate of economic growth-a possibility that will not be explored here-market structure is of interest because it clearly affects the distribution of income, a subject that is increasingly of interest among those working on the problems of developing countries. It is also of interest because economic theory has its widest applications when per­ fect competition can be assumed. In fact, in absence of evidence to the contrary, something close to perfect competition is nearly always assumed by planners in developing countries. The literature on market structures in developing countries-which are here defined to exclude Communist-bloc countries-is relatively thin, un­ usually widely scattered, and so far has resulted in few insights as to the impact of market structure on the pace and character of economic devel­ opment.
    [Show full text]
  • Effective Competition and Corporate Disclosure A
    EFFECTIVE COMPETITION AND CORPORATE DISCLOSURE A CRITICAL STUDY by RAZAHUSSEIN M, DEVJI B. Sc. (Econ)», University of London, 1961 Barrister-at-Law, Honourable Society of Middle Temple, London, 1962 A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION In the Faculty of Graduate Studies We accept this thesis as conforming to the required staricTardT THE UNIVERSITY OF BRITISH COLUMBIA September, 1968 In presenting this thesis in partial ful• filment of the requirements for an advanced degree at the University of British Columbia, I agree that the Library shall make it freely available for reference and study* I further agree that permission for ex• tensive copying of this thesis for scholarly purposes may be granted by the Head of my Department or by his representatives. It is understood that copying or publication of this thesis for financial gain shall not be allowed without my written permission. Faculty of Commerce and Business Administration, The University of British Columbia, Vancouver 8, B. C. Canada. ABSTRACT Economic activity in the United States and Canada is predominantly performed by corporations. They are by far the largest private employers of workers, the biggest investors and the predominant instrument of production. They are rapidly growing in size, are generating sufficient funds internally to carry out most of their expansion programs, and are diversifying into unrelated activities. Their affairs are increasingly managed by professional executives who have little, if any, stake In the risk capital. The shareholders, who are legally pre• sumed to exercise control over the powers and actions of corporate executives, are normally too numerous and scattered so as not to be in a position to have a significant influence on the policies of the corporations.
    [Show full text]
  • CHOICE – a NEW STANDARD for COMPETITION LAW ANALYSIS? a Choice — a New Standard for Competition Law Analysis?
    GO TO TABLE OF CONTENTS GO TO TABLE OF CONTENTS CHOICE – A NEW STANDARD FOR COMPETITION LAW ANALYSIS? a Choice — A New Standard for Competition Law Analysis? Editors Paul Nihoul Nicolas Charbit Elisa Ramundo Associate Editor Duy D. Pham © Concurrences Review, 2016 GO TO TABLE OF CONTENTS All rights reserved. No photocopying: copyright licenses do not apply. The information provided in this publication is general and may not apply in a specifc situation. Legal advice should always be sought before taking any legal action based on the information provided. The publisher accepts no responsibility for any acts or omissions contained herein. Enquiries concerning reproduction should be sent to the Institute of Competition Law, at the address below. Copyright © 2016 by Institute of Competition Law 60 Broad Street, Suite 3502, NY 10004 www.concurrences.com [email protected] Printed in the United States of America First Printing, 2016 Publisher’s Cataloging-in-Publication (Provided by Quality Books, Inc.) Choice—a new standard for competition law analysis? Editors, Paul Nihoul, Nicolas Charbit, Elisa Ramundo. pages cm LCCN 2016939447 ISBN 978-1-939007-51-3 ISBN 978-1-939007-54-4 ISBN 978-1-939007-55-1 1. Antitrust law. 2. Antitrust law—Europe. 3. Antitrust law—United States. 4. European Union. 5. Consumer behavior. 6. Consumers—Attitudes. 7. Consumption (Economics) I. Nihoul, Paul, editor. II. Charbit, Nicolas, editor. III. Ramundo, Elisa, editor. K3850.C485 2016 343.07’21 QBI16-600070 Cover and book design: Yves Buliard, www.yvesbuliard.fr Layout implementation: Darlene Swanson, www.van-garde.com GO TO TABLE OF CONTENTS ii CHOICE – A NEW STANDARD FOR COMPETITION LAW ANALYSIS? Editors’ Note PAUL NIHOUL NICOLAS CHARBIT ELISA RAMUNDO In this book, ten prominent authors offer eleven contributions that provide their varying perspectives on the subject of consumer choice: Paul Nihoul discusses how freedom of choice has emerged as a crucial concept in the application of EU competition law; Neil W.
    [Show full text]
  • Haiti: Toward a New Narrative
    TRADE AND COMPETITIVENESS GLOBAL PRACTICE Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Systematic Country Diagnostic BACKGROUND PAPER Public Disclosure Authorized Haiti: Toward a New Narrative Haiti—Let’s Talk Competition A Brief Review of Market Conditions Georgiana Pop Public Disclosure Authorized Trade and Competitiveness Global Practice Haiti—Let’s Talk Competition A Brief Review of Market Conditions Georgiana Pop © 2016 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org Some rights reserved 1 2 3 4 19 18 17 16 This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved. Rights and Permissions This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 IGO license (CC BY 3.0 IGO) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following conditions: Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: Pop, Georgiana.
    [Show full text]
  • A New Standard for Antitrust the Effective Competition Standard: in Practice
    A NEW STANDARD FOR ANTITRUST THE EFFECTIVE COMPETITION STANDARD: IN PRACTICE ISSUE BRIEF BY MARSHALL STEINBAUM AND MAURICE E. STUCKE | SEPTEMBER 2018 Today’s economy has a market power problem. Consumers are paying higher prices; new entrants face tougher barriers; workers have little power to demand competitive wages and benefits and less mobility to leave for a better offer; and suppliers often can’t reach the market without paying powerful intermediaries for the privilege. The available economic data all point to declining competition, increasing concentration, less innovation, and widening wealth and income inequality. There are many drivers of our market power problem. One significant factor is weak antitrust law and enforcement. Over the past 35 years, Americans have paid the price for a “consumer welfare” standard, which the courts created and interpreted in ways that neither benefit consumers nor their welfare. After nearly four decades, no consensus exists on what the consumer welfare standard actually means. While it is intended to prevent monopolies from charging higher prices, it has failed even on this measure, as the empirical evidence reveals. Moreover, the consumer welfare standard ignores vast segments of the economy, including the adverse effects of mergers, powerful buyers, and unilateral restraints on upstream suppliers and workers. With such price-centric tools, the U.S. competition agencies often cannot assess how mergers and restraints will impact what is increasingly important in the 21st century economy, namely quality, privacy, and innovation. Exacerbating the shortcomings of this “consumer welfare” standard is the courts’ unwieldy, case-by-case rule-of-reason analysis, which is too costly and time-consuming for anyone other than a well-financed plaintiff to undertake.
    [Show full text]
  • Proceedings of the Fifth Workshop of the Apec-Oecd
    PROCEEDINGS OF THE FIFTH WORKSHOP OF THE APEC-OECD CO-OPERATIVE INITIATIVE ON REGULATORY REFORM PARIS, FRANCE 2-3 December, 2003 2 TABLE OF CONTENTS I. PROCEEDINGS OF THE PARIS WORKSHOP ................................................................ 5 II. AGENDA OF THE PARIS WORKSHOP......................................................................... 11 III. WELCOME AND OPENING SPEECH ............................................................................ 17 IV. SUMMARY OF THE PRESENTATIONS ........................................................................ 21 APPENDIX 1: ELEMENTS OF THE PROTOTYPE INTEGRATED CHECKLIST PARTICULARLY RELEVANT TO THIS WORKSHOP................................................................................ 45 APPENDIX 2: PROTOTYPE APEC-OECD INTEGRATED CHECKLIST ON REGULATORY REFORM ............................................................................................................................ 47 APPENDIX 3: APEC PRINCIPLES TO ENHANCE COMPETITION AND REGULATORY REFORM ...................................................................................... 67 APPENDIX 4: THE 1997 OECD POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS ON REGULATORY REFORM.... 71 APPENDIX 5: SUBMITTED PAPERS ....................................................................................................... 73 APPENDIX 6: LIST OF PARTICIPANTS................................................................................................ 143 3 4 I. PROCEEDINGS OF THE PARIS WORKSHOP (SECOND WORKSHOP OF THE SECOND PHASE OF THE
    [Show full text]
  • Transnational Corporations
    VOLUME 15 NUMBER 1 APRIL 2006 TRANSNATIONAL CORPORATIONS United Nations New York and Geneva, 2006 United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Division on Investment, Technology and Enterprise Development Editorial statement Transnational Corporations (formerly The CTC Reporter) is a refereed journal published three times a year by UNCTAD. In the past, the Programme on Transnational Corporations was carried out by the United Nations Centre on Transnational Corporations (1975-1992) and by the Transnational Corporations and Management Division of the United Nations Department of Economic and Social Development (1992-1993). The basic objective of this journal is to publish articles and research notes that provide insights into the economic, legal, social and cultural impacts of transnational corporations in an increasingly global economy and the policy implications that arise therefrom. It focuses especially on political and economic issues related to transnational corporations. In addition, Transnational Corporations features book reviews. The journal welcomes contributions from the academic community, policy makers and staff members of research institutions and international organizations. Guidelines for contributors are given at the end of this issue. Acting Editor: Anne Miroux Associate Editor: Shin Ohinata Production Manager: Tess Ventura Guest editor for special issue: Peter Buckley home page: http://www.unctad.org/TNC Subscriptions A subscription to Transnational Corporations for one year is US$ 45 (single issues are US$ 20). See p. 239 for details of how to subscribe, or contact any distributor of United Nations publications. United Nations, Sales Section, Room DC2-853, 2 UN Plaza, New York, NY 10017, United States – tel.: 1 212 963 3552; fax: 1 212 963 3062; e-mail: [email protected]; or Palais des Nations, 1211 Geneva 10, Switzerland – tel.: 41 22 917 1234; fax: 41 22 917 0123; e-mail: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955 Herbert Hovenkamp
    University of Minnesota Law School Scholarship Repository Minnesota Law Review 2009 United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955 Herbert Hovenkamp Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mlr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Hovenkamp, Herbert, "United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955" (2009). Minnesota Law Review. 483. https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mlr/483 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the University of Minnesota Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in Minnesota Law Review collection by an authorized administrator of the Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Article United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955 Herbert Hovenkampt INTRODUCTION: HISTORICAL EXPLANATION AND THE MARGINALIST REVOLUTION The history of legal policy toward the economy in the United States has emphasized interest group clashes that led to regula- tory legislation.' This is also true of the history of competition policy. 2 Many historians see regulatory history as little more than a political process in which well-organized, dominant interest groups obtain political advantage and protect their particular in- dustry from competition, typically at the expense of consumers.3 t Ben V. & Dorothy Willie Professor, University of Iowa College of Law. Thanks to Christina Bohannan for commenting on a draft. Copyright 0 2009 by Herbert Hovenkamp. 1. See, e.g., WILLIAM J. NOVAK, THE PEOPLE'S WELFARE: LAW AND REGULA- TION IN NINETEENTH-CENTURY AMERICA 83-84 (1996); THE REGULATED ECONO- MY: A HISTORICAL APPROACH TO POLITICAL ECONOMY 12-22 (Claudia Goldin & Gary D.
    [Show full text]
  • THE RULE of REASON, WORKABLE COMPETITION, and MONOPOLY GEORGE W.Stockingi
    THE RULE OF REASON, WORKABLE COMPETITION, AND MONOPOLY GEORGE W.STOCKINGi- AGITATION for changing the antitrust laws is as old as the laws themselves, but the intensity of the demand for modification, and its objectives, have varied. The recent clamor for change culminated in the appointment of the Attorney General's National Committee to Study the Antitrust Laws. The most ardent proponents of revision had laid down two principles by which they would have the Sherman Act interpreted: the rule of reason and the concept of workable competition.' This article will sketch briefly the develop- fiDirector, Institute of Research and Training in the Social Sciences; Chairman, De- partment of Economics, Vanderbilt University; co-author (VATxixs), MoNoraL" A-D FREE ENTERPRisE (1951). The author is indebted to Mrs. Elizabeth R. Post, LLB., Yale 1948, member of the Tennessee Bar, and to Paul T. Bechtol, Jr., graduate assistant in economics, for their help in preparing this article, and to his colleague, Professor James W. McKie, for his critical comments. 1. For an exposition of the rule of reason and the concept of workable competition as modifications of antitrust policy, see Oppenheim, Federal Antitrust Legislation: Guide- posts to a Revised National Antitrust Policy, 50 MIc. L. Rnv. 1139 (1952). The effective- ness of Oppenheim's demand for change is reflected in his having been made co-chairman with Judge Stanley N. Barnes, Assistant Attorney General in charge of the Antitrust Division, of the Attorney General's National Committee to Study the Antitrust Laws. Endorsement of these principles appears in Smith, Effective Competition: Hypothesis for Modernizing the Antitrust Laws, 26 N.Y.U.L.
    [Show full text]
  • The End of Antitrust History Revisited
    BOOK REVIEW THE END OF ANTITRUST HISTORY REVISITED THE CURSE OF BIGNESS: ANTITRUST IN THE NEW GILDED AGE. By Tim Wu. New York, N.Y.: Columbia Global Reports. 2018. Pp. 154. $14.99. Reviewed by Lina M. Khan∗ INTRODUCTION In April 2007 the Antitrust Modernization Commission reported to Congress that “the state of the U.S. antitrust laws” was “sound.”1 Created by lawmakers to examine whether antitrust laws should be re- vised, the bipartisan Commission concluded that existing statutes were sufficiently flexible to address emerging issues, and that courts, antitrust agencies, and practitioners were now in proper agreement that “con- sumer welfare” was the “unifying goal of antitrust law.”2 A decade later, the American Bar Association’s Antitrust Section delivered a similar as- sessment, remarking that “the Nation’s system of competition enforce- ment has been in good hands.”3 These reports represented a high-water mark of agreement within the antitrust community that, despite ongoing debates about specific doctrinal tests or particular standards of proof, antitrust law was, altogether, on the right course. The fact that antitrust had shed its public appeal in favor of an expert-driven enterprise — becoming “less democratic and more technocratic”4 — was generally seen as further evidence of its success.5 ––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––– ∗ Academic Fellow, Columbia Law School; Counsel, U.S. House Committee on the Judiciary, Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial, and Administrative Law. This Review reflects my per- sonal views and not those of the Committee or any of its members. For insightful comments and conversations, I am grateful to Eleanor Fox, David Grewal, Lev Menand, John Newman, and Mar- shall Steinbaum.
    [Show full text]