The Evolution of Water Rights

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Evolution of Water Rights Volume 35 Issue 4 Fall 1995 Fall 1995 The Evolution of Water Rights Anthony Scott Georgina Coustalin Recommended Citation Anthony Scott & Georgina Coustalin, The Evolution of Water Rights, 35 Nat. Resources J. 821 (1995). Available at: https://digitalrepository.unm.edu/nrj/vol35/iss4/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UNM Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Natural Resources Journal by an authorized editor of UNM Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]. ANTHONY SCOTT* GEORGINA COUSTALIN The Evolution of Water Rights ABSTRACT This article looks at the evolution of water rights since early medieval times in England, North America and Australia. Different water rights characteristicssuch as quality of title, exclusivity and transferability are traced. Bases of two water regimes-types are identified: riparianland ownership (community of users) and actual use of the streamwater(priority of use). We identify periods in which one or the other of these types of regimes prevailed and suggest a "twists and turns" pattern of alternation between them. Aspects common to all periods, such as prescription and seniority, are described. Finally, after looking at the dynamics of change from one base to another, we project into the future a new property regime which could respond to increased and more varied demands to use water, conserve it and protect the water shed. PART I: INTRODUCTION A water right can be widely defined as the right to use or enjoy the flowing water in a stream. It may emerge from a person's ownership of land on the banks of the stream ("riparian ownership"), or from a person's actual use of the stream. It may be administered and controlled by a government agency, or it may not be administered at all, and be subject to enforcement only in the courts. A water right can also be created indirectly through a contract with a rights holder. Some water rights are quantitative, applying to a fixed amount of water, measured by rate of flow. Others set no limits so long as the holder does not reduce or pollute the flow available to other water right-holders on the stream. Some continue only as long as the holder continues his specific water use, while others continue whether he uses the water or not. In different parts of the world, even among countries which have the same system of law (for example, the common law countries), and even * Anthony Scott is emeritus professor of economics at the University of British Columbia. Has specialized in the economics of natural resources and of institutions. Georgina Coustalin, B.A., LI.B., is in practice with Steeves and Co. Vancouver. She has specialized in history of law. NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [Vol. 35 within a single country, the regimes of water rights can be found to be very different. Demand and supply play a role here. Furthermore, over time, there have been "evolutions" of water rights. Comparative evolution is the theme of this study. Two questions suggest themselves: (1) Is a water right a different type of right than a land right?; and (2) Is a water right a 'property' right? We answer both questions in the affirmative. An affirmative answer to the first question gives us a reason to look at water rights separately from land rights, and an affirmative answer to the second question gives us a basis for comparing them through the mechanism of their "characteristics." The physical attribute of water in rivers and streams that distin- guishes it most from land for the purpose of a study of rights is its fluidity. The individual drops of water flowing in a stream are always in motion, and travel from one right-holder's location to another's. Hence the holder's right is more than to identifiable drops-it extends to theflow, as represent- ed by the stream's velocity, its level and its quality at any particular instant. This is a modem view of the water right; in early medieval times the law had tried to ignore the fluidity of water and to treat the right as if it were over land. What finally sets off a water right from a freehold, leasehold, profit-A-prendre or any other type of land holding, is the fact that the exercise of the right has "external" effects beyond those felt by the right-holder himself. Conversely, his right is vulnerable to challenges by others on the stream, just "his" flow is vulnerable to variations caused by others' uses. This interdependence among water users, which has led economists to dub such a stream a "common property" is far, far greater than among landowners or land users. The "common property" feature means that a water right has far less exclusivity than has a land right. Certain land rights also lack some exclusivity, but water rights lack so much more exclusivity as to warrant separate study. Is a water right a "property" right? A lawyer would say that only if the right derived directly from a grant of land, could it be called a "real property" right. Anything else would be a "personal right" and outside the scope of a study on natural resources property. An economist would not limit the definition in this way, but would call a property right any one which gave its holder powers to use, manage or alienate a thing or to drive profit from it. A contractual right regarding the use of land would therefore be a type of land property right in the eyes of an economist but not of a lawyer. What they would both have to agree on as a minimal requirement for a land property right, however, would be social recognition, enforce- ment and protection of the holder's powers given under the right. This minimal and broad definition gives us a basis of comparison of various water rights regimes. The points of comparison will be the extent of six "characteristics" of property rights: Fall 1995] EVOLUTION OF WATER RIGHTS duration or permanence; flexibility; exclusivity or specificity; quality of title or security; transferability or assignability; and divisibility. The changing regulation of water-rights holders by statute and by the several branches of the common law: criminal, tort, property and contract, has worked to alter the amount of each of the six characteristics oaf their right. The ability of legislators and courts to make these changes has itself been subject to change according to the prevailing powers of Parliament and the forms of legal action in use at the time. Different forms of action had, for example, different requirements regarding 'standing' of a plaintiff to sue, and the burden of proof. In proposing a reconciliation of the ideas of economists and lawyers with regard to property rights, we have been guided by the following 1. If a person has a legal entitlement to something that can be enforced and protected, he has a "right." 2. If a person has no legal entitlement to do something, but others have no means of preventing or blocking him from his use or enjoyment of it, and he has the legal means of protecting his action from harm from others, what he has is tantamount to a "right." He can use the thing unimpug- ned and unhindered. 3. The corollary of I and 2: If a person has a legal or technical entitlement which the court will not enforce, then he does not, practically speaking, have a "right," for any other member of the public is in as good a position as he is with regard to the use and enjoyment of the thing. The first statement is not controversial and would be accepted both in the courts and in economic analyses. Courts have parted from econo- mists over the second statement. They have strenuously resisted calling what is "tantamount to a right" a legal entitlement, because the instances of it have no roots in land or water ownership but only in the power of an individual to prevent others from doing something.' Yet for hundreds of years these same courts protected, through their procedures, the quasi-legal 1. The authors gratefully acknowledge the assistance and comments they have received form nay persons. Among them they would mention: Richard Campbell, Sandy Clark, Ronald Cummings, Anthony Dorcey, Mason Gaffney, David Getches, Mischa Gisser, Linda Hannah, Charles Howe, Elizabeth Kirk, Arthur Maass, Ben Marr, Mary McGregor, Christopher Mowlin, Peter H. Pearse, Christine Riek, Ruth Picha, Murray Rankin, Bernadette Stale, Jennifer Steward, Andrew Thompson, Stephen Wisenthal. See Mason v. Hill, 110 Eng. Rep. 692 (K.B. 1833), discussed in Part IIl.C., infra. NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [Vol. 35 right of "prior-use" water diversion which was founded on this precept formed the basis of a huge network of contracting and industrial develop- ment on the rivers of England.2 The third statement may appear controver- sial, but was recognized by the courts in the eighteenth century case of Ashby v. White.3 In that case, which concerned voting rights, the court resolved that "want of right and want of remedy are reciprocal," or without a remedy, there is no right.4 Thus we propose as a further definition of a property right: "The ability to do something which is recognized directly or indirectly in law, to the extent that the law can be expected positively to protect that ability or negatively to prevent others from interfering with that ability." An evolution in water rights has indeed taken place in the common law world, if one considers "rights" in the sense of the above broad definition.
Recommended publications
  • Farmland Investments and Water Rights: the Legal Regimes at Stake
    Farmland Investments and Water Rights: The legal regimes at stake Makane Moïse Mbengue Susanna Waltman May 2015 www.iisd.org/gsi www.iisd.org © 2015 The International Institute for Sustainable Development Published by the International Institute for Sustainable Development. International Institute for Sustainable Development The International Institute for Sustainable Development (IISD) contributes to sustainable development by advancing policy recommendations on international trade and investment, economic policy, climate change and energy, and management of natural and social capital, as well as the enabling role of communication technologies in these areas. We report on international negotiations and disseminate knowledge gained through collaborative projects, resulting in more rigorous research, capacity building in developing countries, better networks spanning the North and the South, and better global connections among researchers, practitioners, citizens and policy-makers. IISD’s vision is better living for all—sustainably; its mission is to champion innovation, enabling societies to live sustainably. IISD is registered as a charitable organization in Canada and has 501(c)(3) status in the United States. IISD receives core operating support from the Government of Canada, provided through the International Development Research Centre (IDRC), from the Danish Ministry of Foreign Affairs and from the Province of Manitoba. The Institute receives project funding from numerous governments inside and outside Canada, United Nations agencies,
    [Show full text]
  • LAND TENURE and RIGHTS for Improved Land Management and Sustainable Development
    GLOBAL LAND OUTLOOK WORKING PAPER LAND TENURE AND RIGHTS for Improved Land Management and Sustainable Development Prof. Emmanuel Kasimbazi September 2017 DISCLAIMER The designations employed and the presentation of material in this information product do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the United Nations Convention to Combat Desertification (UNCCD) concerning the legal or development status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. The mention of specific companies or products of manufacturers, whether or not these have been patented, does not imply that these have been endorsed or recommended by UNCCD in preference to others of a similar nature that are not mentioned. The views expressed in this information product are those of the authors or contributors and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of UNCCD. CONTENTS Acronyms 03 Executive Summary 04 1. General Introduction 06 1.1 Introduction 06 1.2 Objectives and Scope of the Paper 06 1.3 Structure of the Paper 07 2. Context and Background 07 3. Land Tenure Systems 08 3.1 Definition of the term land tenure 08 3.2 Types of Tenure 08 4. Land Policy and Regulatory Framework 11 5. Land Rights and Gender 14 6. Customary Land Rights 15 7. Land Administration and Institutions 15 7.1 Institutions at the international level 16 7.2 Institutions at the regional level 16 7.3 Institutions at National level 16 8. Land Registration and Titling Systems 18 9. Sustainable Land Management 19 10.
    [Show full text]
  • Land Tenure: an Introduction
    The U.S. Congress established the East-West Center in 1960 to foster mutual understanding and coopera- tion among the governments and peoples of the Asia Pacific region including the United States. Funding for the Center comes from the U.S. govern- ment with additional support provided by private agencies, individuals, corporations, and Asian and Pacific governments. East-West Center Working Papers are circulated for comment and to inform interested colleagues about work in progress at the Center. For more information about the Center or to order publications, contact: Publication Sales Office East-West Center 1601 East-West Road Honolulu, Hawaii 96848-1601 Telephone: 808-944-7145 Facsimile: 808-944-7376 Email: [email protected] Website: www.EastWestCenter.org EAST-WEST CENTER WORKING PAPERS Economics Series No. 49, June 2002 Land Tenure: An Introduction Sumner La Croix Sumner La Croix is a Senior Fellow and Coordinator of China Research at the East-West Center, and he is Professor and Chair in the Department of Economics at the University of Hawaii. His book, Japan's New Economy: Continuity and Change in the Twenty-First Century, was published by Oxford University Press in 2001. La Croix has published numerous articles on the economic history and development of the Asia-Pacific region, with particular emphasis on intellectual property conflicts, institutional change and economic reform, the Asia-Pacific civil aviation industry, and foreign direct investment in China. Forthcoming in Oxford Encyclopedia of Economic History. East-West Center Working Papers: Economics Series reports on research in progress. This paper has been peer-reviewed. The views expressed are those of the author and not necessarily those of the Center.
    [Show full text]
  • SECTION 1.0 Summary of California Water Rights
    SECTION 1.0 Summary of California Water Rights 1.1 Types of Water Rights In California, the different types of water rights include: 1.1.1 Prescriptive Water use rights gained by trespass or unauthorized taking that ripen into a title, on a par with rights to land gained through adverse possession.1 1.1.2 Pueblo A water right possessed by a municipality that, as a successor of a Spanish-law pueblo, is entitled to the beneficial use of all needed, naturally occurring surface and groundwater of the original pueblo watershed.2 1.1.3 Groundwater The Dictionary of Real Estate Appraisal, defines groundwater as “all water that has seeped down beneath the surface of the ground or into the subsoil; water from springs or wells.”3 This is an adequate working definition if the “springs or” is eliminated because once water issues out of a spring it becomes surface water, not groundwater. As is also indicated in the following text, it is not water flowing in an underground channel. Groundwater should be thought of as the water that occupies the space between soil particles beneath the surface of the land. Groundwater is extracted exclusively by means of wells. Whenever groundwater reaches the surface in a natural manner, whether through springs or seepage into a surface water stream channel or lake, it ceases to be groundwater and becomes surface water. The jurisdiction of the SWRCB [State Water Resources Control Board] to issue permits and licenses for appropriation of underground water is limited by section 1200 of the California Water Code to “subterranean streams flowing through known and definite channels.” If use of underground water on nonoverlying land is proposed and the source of the water is a subterranean stream flowing in a known and definite channel, an application pursuant to the California Water Code is required.
    [Show full text]
  • Landowner's Guide to Washington Water Rights
    2019 / THIRD EDITION LANDOWNER’S GUIDE TO WASHINGTON WATER RIGHTS 2019 LANDOWNER'S GUIDE TO WASHINGTON WATER RIGHTS TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter 1 – Introduction Chapter 6 – Valuing & Selling Your Water Right A Landowner’s Story, p. 3 Valuing Your Water Right, p. 29 Purpose, p. 4 Leasing or Selling Your Water Right, p. 29 Washington’s Water Challenge, p. 5 Chapter 7 – Water Rights Adjudications, p. 30-31 Chapter 2 – Water Right Basics What is a Water Right? p. 6-7 Chapter 8 – Instream Flows & Trust Water Rights Key Water Right Concepts , p. 8-15 Instream Flows and Instream Flow Rules, p. 32-33 How Is a Water Right Established? p. 16 Interruptible Rights, p. 32 Washington Trust Water Rights Program, p. 34-35 Chapter 3 – Understanding Your Water Right Learning About Your Water Right, p.18 Chapter 9 – Exempt Wells, p. 36-37 Evaluating a Water Right, p. 19-23 Buying Land, p. 24 Chapter 10 – Win-Win Water Solutions, p. 38-39 Chapter 4 – Managing Your Water Right Appendix A – Glossary, p. 40-43 How Do You Keep Your Water Right? p. 25-26 Metering Your Water Right, p. 27 Appendix B – Legal Descriptions, p. 44-45 Chapter 5 – Changing or Transferring Your Water Right Appendix C – Resources, p. 46 Changes and Transfers, p. 28 Water Conservancy Boards, p. 28 Acknowledgements, p. 47 Trout Unlimited – Washington Water Project is a nonprofit organization working to create solutions for instream flow, community, and agricultural water needs. We work with private landowners on voluntary projects, and we provide water expertise to NGOs, government agencies, and tribal entities.
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Land Tenure?
    Land Tenure and Property Rights Concepts and Terminology Presenter: John Bruce Property Rights and Resource Governance Issues and Best Practices Washington, DC October 2012 Land in the News Delegates And Government Clash On Rwanda: Land Customary Land Registration Complete What's Behind International Land Grabs? Families in Kacyiru, Zimbabwe land reform 'not Kimicanga Areas to a failure' Be Expropriated 2 Objectives 1. Introduce some fundamental concepts and terms used in the course concerning both issues and interventions in land tenure systems 2. Provide participants with a shared vocabulary of land tenure and property rights 3. Identify a few common confusions in the use of key terms which can lead to miscommunication in policy discussions 3 What is land tenure? 1. Land Tenure and Real Property 2. What’s the point of property rights in land? . Avoiding a free-for-all . Reducing risks and creating incentives . Allowing land to move among users . Creating capital - land is a financial asset 4 What is tenure—A bundle of rights 5 What are some basic tenures? 1. Tenures are characterized in terms of: . Type of right: ownership (freehold), tenancy (leasehold), usufruct (use right), concession, license . Holder: individual (private), state (public), community (common) 2. Tenures are not made in Heaven but are created by law 6 Property regimes . Individual property: Strands of property bundle are held by a natural or legal person . Community property: Strands are shared among members of a community or association . Public (or state) property: Strands are concentrated, held and managed by the government . Terra nullius: Land to belongs to no one.
    [Show full text]
  • Instream Flows and the Public Trust
    Instream Flows and the Public Trust Timothy M. Mulvaney* I. INTRODUCTION ................................................................................. 316 II. A FRAMEWORK FOR INSTREAM FLOW MANAGEMENT .................... 321 A. Traditional Water Rights Systems .......................................... 322 1. Riparian Rights ............................................................... 322 2. Appropriative Rights ...................................................... 324 B. Conversion to Regulated Riparianism ................................... 327 1. An Initial Foray into Appropriation ............................... 327 2. The Existing Regulated Riparian System ..................... 328 a. Agency Structure for Managing Instream Flows ....................................................................... 329 b. The Water Permit System ...................................... 331 c. Water Management Planning ................................ 334 III. CURRENT USE OF THE 7Q10 METHOD FOR PRESERVING INSTREAM FLOWS ............................................................................. 336 A. Importance of Maintaining a Relatively Natural Flow ......... 337 B. Principles of Instream Flow Protection .................................. 338 C. Documented Failures of 7Q10 in Protecting Instream Flows ........................................................................................ 339 D. State Departures from 7Q10 ..................................................... 340 E. Contemporary Stresses on Surface Waters ...........................
    [Show full text]
  • The Commons and Customary Law in Modern Times: Rethinking the Orthodoxies
    UNDP-International Land Coalition Workshop: Land Rights for African Development: From Knowledge to Action Nairobi, October 31 – November 3, 2005 (Proceedings: http://www.undp.org/drylands/lt-workshop-11-05.htm) The Commons and Customary Law in Modern Times: Rethinking the Orthodoxies Liz Alden Wily Independent Consultant Land Tenure Adviser [email protected] INTRODUCTION Let me first lay out my position from the outset - 1. Conceptual confusion still blights ideas of the commons. It is necessary to draw a distinction between territories over which communities customarily exercise domain (Communal Domain) and tangible real estate, those properties within those domains which are the private group-owned property of all members of a community of persons, and which are held (for good reasons) in undivided shares. These are Common Properties. 2. It is my view that individually-held properties have been and still are - despite the last decade of reforms - the wrong target for rural tenure registration and collateralization in agrarian conditions. 3. Priority focus should be upon the rural commons. It is these estates, not the family farm or house, which always have been, and remain today at most risk from involuntary loss. It is these community-owned properties to which governments throughout the continent have so consistently helped themselves and/or reallocate to others and which still bear the status in over half of African States as de facto un-owned or public land. These losses continue right up until the present.1 Moreover these losses directly affect the poor. For even the poorest members of rural communities, those without land or too little land to live on (the ‘land poor’) share the customary ownership of these estates with other, richer members of the community.
    [Show full text]
  • Landowner's Guide to Washington Water Rights
    2019 / THIRD EDITION LANDOWNER’S GUIDE TO WASHINGTON WATER RIGHTS 2019 LANDOWNER'S GUIDE TO WASHINGTON WATER RIGHTS TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter 1 – Introduction Chapter 6 – Valuing & Selling Your Water Right A Landowner’s Story, p. 3 Valuing Your Water Right, p. 29 Purpose, p. 4 Leasing or Selling Your Water Right, p. 29 Washington’s Water Challenge, p. 5 Chapter 7 – Water Rights Adjudications, p. 30-31 Chapter 2 – Water Right Basics What is a Water Right? p. 6-7 Chapter 8 – Instream Flows & Trust Water Rights Key Water Right Concepts , p. 8-15 Instream Flows and Instream Flow Rules, p. 32-33 How Is a Water Right Established? p. 16 Interruptible Rights, p. 32 Washington Trust Water Rights Program, p. 34-35 Chapter 3 – Understanding Your Water Right Learning About Your Water Right, p.18 Chapter 9 – Exempt Wells, p. 36-37 Evaluating a Water Right, p. 19-23 Buying Land, p. 24 Chapter 10 – Win-Win Water Solutions, p. 38-39 Chapter 4 – Managing Your Water Right Appendix A – Glossary, p. 40-43 How Do You Keep Your Water Right? p. 25-26 Metering Your Water Right, p. 27 Appendix B – Legal Descriptions, p. 44-45 Chapter 5 – Changing or Transferring Your Water Right Appendix C – Resources, p. 46 Changes and Transfers, p. 28 Water Conservancy Boards, p. 28 Acknowledgements, p. 47 Trout Unlimited – Washington Water Project is a nonprofit organization working to create solutions for instream flow, community, and agricultural water needs. We work with private landowners on voluntary projects, and we provide water expertise to NGOs, government agencies, and tribal entities.
    [Show full text]
  • Enclosures As a Land Management Tool for Food Security in African Drylands
    Journal of Land Use Science ISSN: 1747-423X (Print) 1747-4248 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/tlus20 Enclosures as a land management tool for food security in African drylands Gert Nyberg, Stephen M. Mureithi, Deborah N. Muricho & Madelene Ostwald To cite this article: Gert Nyberg, Stephen M. Mureithi, Deborah N. Muricho & Madelene Ostwald (2019) Enclosures as a land management tool for food security in African drylands, Journal of Land Use Science, 14:1, 110-121, DOI: 10.1080/1747423X.2019.1636147 To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/1747423X.2019.1636147 © 2019 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group. View supplementary material Published online: 30 Jun 2019. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 179 View related articles View Crossmark data Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=tlus20 JOURNAL OF LAND USE SCIENCE 2019, VOL. 14, NO. 1, 110–121 https://doi.org/10.1080/1747423X.2019.1636147 Enclosures as a land management tool for food security in African drylands Gert Nyberga, Stephen M. Mureithib, Deborah N. Murichob and Madelene Ostwaldc,d,e aDepartment of Forest Ecology and Management, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences (SLU), Umeå, Sweden; bDepartment of Land Resource Management and Agricultural Technology (LARMAT), University of Nairobi, Nairobi, Kenya; cCentre for Environment and Sustainability (GMV), University of Gothenburg/Chalmers University
    [Show full text]
  • Land Tenure: Lessons for Sustainability Through Information Sharing
    LandTenureEng 6/1/06 2:35 PM Page 2 ORGANIZATION OF AMERICAN STATES DEPARTMENT OF SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT OF SUSTAINABLE DEPARTMENT POLICY SERIES, NUMBER 10 — APRIL 2006 Land Tenure: Lessons for Sustainability Through Information Sharing Despite so many efforts to reform aspects of property rights, ■ Conflicts over land and lack of adequate land dispute to regularize land registration of rural and urban land and to resolution mechanisms. modernize land registration systems, a lot still remains to be done ■ Resistance by political and economic interest groups. to address the needs of marginalized groups, especially women, ■ Non-implementation of existing laws and lack of a legal indigenous peoples and poor rural farmers who are denied framework for pursuing reforms. basics rights over land. By creating systems and networks within which practical information and experiences can be shared, Governments spend a considerable governments will be able to use the best regulations, options amount of time and effort managing, and practices available to reform aspects of property rights. planning and securing property. Each of these functions is run by a myriad of LAND POLICY ISSUES IN LATIN separate agencies creating difficulties in AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN (LAC) registering a property. Data from the Latin America has, on average, the most inequitable distribution Doing Business report show that the of land. The magnitude of land distribution inequality meas- number of days on average to register ured by the Gini coefficient of land distribution goes from 0.55 a property in LAC is 76.5 while in the to 0.94 resulting that in the 1970s and 1980s it was possible to OECD countries takes on average about find countries where 6% of the population controlled all the 32 days.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Land Tenure in Queensland
    Understanding Land Tenure in Queensland Presented by: Greg Short Understanding Land Tenure in Queensland Presentation Overview • Basic Definitions • The Legislation we operate under • Non Freehold tenure • Unallocated State Land – Lease Types • Non-Freehold – Term Leases • Other ways to occupy State Land • Freehold Tenure • Secondary Interests: Lease, Profit á Prendre, Covenant, Easements, Other Secondary Interests • Conclusion (Reference guides) www.bennettandbennett.com.au Definitions Tenure: The legal right to live in a particular building or to use a particular piece of land during a fixed period of time (Collins English Dictionary). Land Tenure: Is the means of identifying who has the right to use and occupy land in accordance with the varying degrees of ownership (Land Title Practice Manual). Freehold Land: Is where land has been alienated from the State and the ownership rests with the individual owner for an estate in fee simple. (Land Title Practice Manual) Non-Freehold Land: Is the land that has not been freeholded in Queensland including land below HWM (Land Title Practice Manual). Leasehold: The holding of a property by lease (Google Dictionary). www.bennettandbennett.com.au The Main Legislation Dealing with Tenure in Queensland The Land Act 1994 • The general object of this Act is to manage all state land for the benefit of the people of Queensland having regard to the principles of Sustainability, Evaluation, Development, Community Purpose, Protection, Consultation and Administration. The Land Act applies to all land, including land below HWM. Although the Land Act generally applies to non-freehold land, most freehold land contains a reservation to the state for minerals.
    [Show full text]