Perspectives on Labor Process Theory

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Perspectives on Labor Process Theory 978–0–19–953532–105-Alvesson-Ch-05 OUP072-Alvesson-et-al (Typeset by SPi, Chennai) 99 of 122 December 18, 2008 18:31 chapter 5 .............................................................................................................. PERSPECTIVES ON LABOR PROCESS THEORY .............................................................................................................. paul thompson damian p. o’doherty Editorial Note .......................................................................................................................................... Theoretical perspectives are invariably partial, comprising variants and factions. There is a legacy of debate and disputation in critical theory. In the case of labor process theory (LPT), development has taken the form of a heated debate in recent years between structuralist and poststructuralist perspectives. To reflect this position, we have invited proponents of the two variants—Paul Thompson and Damian O’Doherty—to each present a short half-chapter on their respec- tive approach and understanding of labor process theory so that the chapter as a “whole” conveys a sense of a perspective in ferment. Rather than replay the original debates, the contributors have been sensibly asked to consider the following: r What is LPT and what kind of problems (as a theory) is it intended to address/solve? r How successful has it been in addressing those problems and issues? r What are the actual and potential relationships between LPT and CMS? 978–0–19–953532–105-Alvesson-Ch-05 OUP072-Alvesson-et-al (Typeset by SPi, Chennai) 100 of 122 December 18, 2008 18:31 100 paul thompson & damian p. o’doherty Au: Please check “I Paul IPaul Thompson:Labor Process Theory Thompson” and Critical Management Studies “I” is .......................................................................................................................................... numbered head or not. Labor Process Theory (LPT) is conventionally and rightly listed as one of the analytical resources for Critical Management Studies (CMS). Yet, the relationships between the two have been, in the words of a classic of the former, a contested terrain. This is hardly surprising. Even if we set aside the inevitable multiplicity of perspectives, there is a tension in potential objects of analysis. Before CMS burst on to the scene, LPT was being criticized at its peak of influence in the 1980sforpaying too much attention to management and too little to capital(ism) and labor. This was sometimes attributed to the location of many of the protagonists (in the UK at least) in business schools, but was, more likely a reflection of wider theoretical and ideological divides. Throughout the 1990s a battle took place—“the labor process debate”—between what some would regard as the materialist and poststructuralist participants inside and outside the annual UK-based conference. The emergence of a separate CMS conference and related initiatives was shaped, in part, by the nature and outcomes of those debates. Where do we stand now—to what extent is LPT part of, separate from or hostile to CMS? It is important to make one qualification about the debates discussed below. As social theory so clearly indicates, institutions matter. The existence and location of an annual and successful labor process conference and book series based in the UK has meant that a particular weight is given to theorizing and research within its boundaries. Yet clearly the conference, critical theory and research and LPT are not the same things. For example, there are lively traditions of LP scholarship in North America that have proceeded on overlapping but often very distinctive paths (e.g. Shalla and Clement 2007). Whilst some effort will be made to refer to a wider set of debates, in a short review of this kind, the scope for doing so will inevitably be limited and our focus must be the LPT–CMS interface. The Theory: Territory, Tensions, and Tantrums What is LPT and what does its “field” consist of? It is convention to refer to a number of “waves” of development (see Thompson and Newsome 2004). The first wave is seen as Braverman and supportive arguments, the second as the major studies from Richard Edwards, Friedman, Burawoy, Littler, and others that followed in its wake from the late 1970s to the late 1980s. Perhaps more controversially, we could identify an overlapping third wave over the following decade characterized largely by a series of paradigm wars between, on the one hand, LPT and a number 978–0–19–953532–105-Alvesson-Ch-05 OUP072-Alvesson-et-al (Typeset by SPi, Chennai) 101 of 122 December 18, 2008 18:31 perspectives on labor process theory 101 of “new production and society” perspectives such as flexible specialization and post-Fordism, and on the other within those attending the annual conference about territory and tasks. It is in the second category of the third wave that the UK-based “labor process debate” took place. This debate was initially between consolidators and reconstructionists. The former saw the second wave as consisting of a number of common concepts vital for analyzing the trajectories of capitalist economies and work systems, but in danger of being drowned in a welter of seemingly contra- dictory empiricist case studies about skill, control, and related issues. The main proposed solution was the development of a core theory that synthesized and extended the insights of post-Braverman research with a view to producing more or less coherent statements of what the contemporary labor process looked like and the conceptual tools to understood it. In the influential Labour Process Theory volume published at the end of the decade (Knights and Willmott 1990), this was the clear intent of a number of the contributors—notably myself, Paul Edwards, and Craig Littler (all 1990). In my case, that involved the elaboration of a core theory based on a number of propositions about the structural characteristics of the capitalist labor process that shaped and constrained workplace relations. Part of the purpose was to distin- guish between identification of strong tendencies deriving from those structures and mechanisms and particular outcomes, such as deskilling and Taylorism, with which LPT had become associated because of the influence of Braverman. So for example, the core referred to a control imperative given that market mechanisms alone cannot address the indeterminacy of labor (the conversion of labor power into profitable work), rather than specifying a particular control strategy. The core theory became a reference point for many later studies and we will return to its character and status later. However, in that same volume, the two editors, in separate but mutually supportive chapters, put forward a very different conception ofterritoryandtask:“thesystematicreconstructionoflabourprocesstheory...to develop a more adequate, materialist theory of subjectivity” (Willmott 1990: 337). Thus was born the “the missing subject” debate, There was some common ground between consolidators and reconstructionists. Both agreed that Braverman’s preference for analyzing only the objective character- istics of the capital—labor relationship had left a hole where agency and subjectivity should have been, but differed sharply on how it should be filled, Consolidators tended to believe that (re) inserting resistance, the capacity of creativity in labor power and the importance of consent (Burawoy 1979)aspartoftherangeof worker responses to its commodity status was a substantial, if not wholly sufficient contribution to a revised LPT. For Knights, Willmott, and their collaborators, such developments, particularly Burwaoy’s emphasis on consent, was an advance on objectivism, but nowhere near enough. At first this was framed in terms of “complementing” a structural analysis through a focus on the subjective conditions that facilitate the reproduction of capitalism. 978–0–19–953532–105-Alvesson-Ch-05 OUP072-Alvesson-et-al (Typeset by SPi, Chennai) 102 of 122 December 18, 2008 18:31 102 paul thompson & damian p. o’doherty In itself, this is uncontroversial, but there are three problems. First, are the chosen means. It may have been “materialist,” but the raw material was a discussion of existential problems of identity and power located in the general human condition. Second, there was a substantive displacement effect through the rejection of all of the available resources of LPT and search for new ones, initially in critical theory and then, increasingly in Foucault and post-structuralism. Every critique more or less followed the same path—well-known labor LPT texts would be picked over and critiqued with same ultimate punchline—the absence of an adequate theory of subjectivity. Third, though issues of subjective reproduction of capitalism and work relations are a sub-plot, they are not the plot. It is necessary to address and explain the changing political economy of capitalism, something that poststructuralists have generally shown little interest in. Whilst Marx, Braverman, and others were extensively and knowledgeably dis- cussed in papers by Knights and Willmott, this was reconstruction without building on or from any prior empirical or theoretical foundations. As a result of these problems, the 1990s debate was not actually about the labor process. That it was presented as the “labor process debate” was an accident of history—a convergence of two factors. The first, that the Labor Process Conference was the focal point for most critical scholarship on work,
Recommended publications
  • Redalyc.SOCIOLOGY of INNOVATION: SOCIAL
    AD-minister ISSN: 1692-0279 [email protected] Universidad EAFIT Colombia YOUSEFIKHAH, SARA SOCIOLOGY OF INNOVATION: SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION OF TECHNOLOGY PERSPECTIVE AD-minister, núm. 30, enero-junio, 2017, pp. 31-43 Universidad EAFIT Medellín, Colombia Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=322349942004 How to cite Complete issue Scientific Information System More information about this article Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative 31 AD -MINISTER AD-minister Nº. 30 january-june 2017 pp. 31 - 43 · ISSN 1692-0279 · eISSN 2256-4322 SOCIOLOGY OF INNOVATION: SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION OF TECHNOLOGY PERSPECTIVE SOCIOLOGÍA DE LA INNOVACIÓN: CONSTRUCCIÓN SOCIAL DE LA PERSPECTIVA TECNOLÓGICA SARA YOUSEFIKHAH ABSTRACT SARA YOUSEFIKHAH This theoretical paper describes the effect of social action on technological artifacts and explores how innovation may flourish or be diminished in society. Using the Social Construction of Technology JEL: M, O (SCOT) perspective, three main elements namely, flexibility of interpretation, relevant social groups and technological frame are described and their impact on innovation is discussed. The paper proposes that Received: 5-09-2016 in developing societies, flexibility is hardly pressed by technological frames and concrete social norms Modified: 23-11-2016 do not allow the alternative designs and the useage of artifacts. This paper proposes that innovation Accepted: 22-12-2016 might flourish in a society if technological frame change, and entrepreneurship become technological frames that can change the fixed meaning of artifacts and create a path for alternative designs and interpretations.
    [Show full text]
  • The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond
    Working Paper No. 822 The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond by Riccardo Bellofiore* University of Bergamo December 2014 * [email protected] This paper was prepared for the project “Financing Innovation: An Application of a Keynes-Schumpeter- Minsky Synthesis,” funded in part by the Institute for New Economic Thinking, INET grant no. IN012-00036, administered through the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Co-principal investigators: Mariana Mazzucato (Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex) and L. Randall Wray (Levy Institute). The author thanks INET and the Levy Institute for support of this research. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2014 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X Abstract An understanding of, and an intervention into, the present capitalist reality requires that we put together the insights of Karl Marx on labor, as well as those of Hyman Minsky on finance. The best way to do this is within a longer-term perspective, looking at the different stages through which capitalism evolves.
    [Show full text]
  • Socialization of Risks Without Socialization of Risks
    RESEARCH INSTITUTE POLITICAL ECONOMY Socialization of Risks without Socialization of Investment: The Minsky Paradox and the Structural Contradiction of Big Government Capitalism Minqi Li September 2009 Gordon Hall 418 North Pleasant Street Amherst, MA 01002 Phone: 413.545.6355 Fax: 413.577.0261 [email protected] www.peri.umass.edu WORKINGPAPER SERIES Number 205 Socialization of Risks without Socialization of Investment: The Minsky Paradox and the Structural Contradiction of Big Government Capitalism Dr. Minqi Li, Assistant Professor Department of Economics, University of Utah Salt Lake City, Utah E-mail: [email protected] Webpage: www.econ.utah.edu/~mli September 2009 Abstract A big government sector is indispensable for the normal operations of modern capitalist economy. However, the very success of the big government institutions encourages private investors to engage in excessive risk-taking activities, leading to growing financial fragility and frequent financial crises. The crises necessitate government interventions, forcing the government to run large deficits during recessions. These deficits, however, are not offset by surpluses during expansions. As a result, there is a tendency for the government debt to rise in relation to GDP. The government debt-GDP ratios cannot keep rising indefinitely. Beyond certain point, the debt-GDP ratio could be so high that the government’s ability to intervene with and stabilize the economy would be severely undermined. This may be characterized as the structural contradiction of big government capitalism. JEL Codes E12; E30; E60; H60 1 The current economic crisis has generated renewed interest in the works of Hyman Minsky (Papadimitriou and Wray 2008).
    [Show full text]
  • Labour Process Theory: an Evaluation and Extension
    © ephemera 2005 articles ISSN 1473-2866 e phemera www.ephemeraweb.org theory & politics in organization volume 5(1): 5-25 Marxian Critiques of Thompson’s (1990) ‘core’ Labour Process Theory: An Evaluation and Extension Stephen J. Jaros abstract During the 1990s and into the 2000s, a substantial body of Labour Process Theory (LPT) research emerged around a ‘core’ concept of LPT initially outlined by Thompson (1990) and reiterated by Thompson and Smith (2001). While this research programme has yielded detailed case studies that shed light on labour process dynamics in a variety of workplaces, industries and governmental sectors, it has been a target of criticism by analysts of both postmodernist and traditional-Marxian persuasions, who argue that core LPT is theoretically flawed and politically inert (O’Doherty and Willmott, 2001; Tinker, 2002). This paper evaluates the Marxian critiques that challenge elements of LPT’s conceptual core, and then leverages the evaluations to outline some future directions for LPT research. These include proposals for addressing the ‘value’ problem, the political problem, and the global political-economy problem in LPT research. In conclusion, a revised core for LPT is recommended so as to enhance the framework’s ability to address work-related issues in contemporary global capitalism. Introduction: Core LPT and its Critics In an effort to bring together disparate strands of research influenced by Braverman’s (1974) analysis of the labour process under monopoly capitalism, Thompson (1990) outlined four elements that he believed constituted a proper, and coherent, ‘core’ for Labour Process Theory (LPT). During the 1990s and into the early 2000s, researchers influenced by this core LPT concept developed an emphasis on describing how capital- labour dynamics unfold in a variety of specific workplaces and disparate labour processes (e.g., Smith, Knights, and Willmott, 1991; Jermier, Knights, and Nord, 1994; Warhurst and Thompson, 1998).
    [Show full text]
  • Where Did Braverman Go Wrong? a Marxist Response to the Politicist Critiques
    Where did Braverman go wrong? A Marxist response to the politicist critiques Onde está errado Braverman? A resposta marxista às críticas politicistas Eduardo Sartelli1 Marina Kabat2 Abstract Braverman is considered an unquestionable reference of Marxist labour process. The objective of this paper is to show that despite Braverman’s undeniable achievements he forsakes the classical Marxist notions related to work organization, i. e. simple cooperation, manufacture and large-scale industry and replaces them with the notion of Taylorism. We also intend to show that because of this abandonment, Braverman cannot explain properly how the deskilling tendency operates in different historical periods, and in distinct industry branches. Finally, we try to demonstrate that those Marxist concepts neglected by Braverman are especially useful to understand labor unrest related to job organization. Braverman overvalues the incidence of labor fragmentation and direct forms of control and disregards the impact of mechanization achieved with the emergence of Large-scale industry and the new forms of control associated with it. Whereas Braverman’s allegedly Marxist orthodoxy is considered responsible for this, in fact, exactly the opposite can be asserted: the weaknesses of the otherwise noteworthy work of Harry Braverman are grounded in his relinquishment of some crucial Marxist concepts. We state that labor processes conventionally considered Taylorist or Fordist can be reconceptualized in Marxist classic terms allowing a better understanding of the dynamic of conflicts regarding labor process. Keywords: Labor process. Politics. Marxism. Regulationism. Workers’ Struggles. Resumo Braverman é considerado uma referência inquestionável do processo de trabalho marxista. O objetivo deste artigo é mostrar que, apesar das contribuições inegáveis de Braverman ele abandona as noções marxistas clássicas relacionadas à organização do trabalho, a saber, cooperação simples, manufatura e grande-indústria e substituí-las com a noção do taylorismo.
    [Show full text]
  • Liberalism, Marxism and Democratic Theory Revisited: Proposal of a Joint Index of Political and Economic Democracy
    brazilianpoliticalsciencereview ARTICLE Liberalism, Marxism and Democratic Theory Revisited: Proposal of a Joint Index of Political and Economic Democracy Angelo Segrillo Department of History, University of São Paulo Liberalism and Marxism are two schools of thought which have left deep imprints in sociological, political and economic theory. They are usually perceived as opposite, rival approaches. In the field of democracy there is a seemingly in- surmountable rift around the question of political versus economic democracy. Liberals emphasize the former, Marxists the latter. Liberals say that economic democracy is too abstract and fuzzy a concept, therefore one should concentrate on the workings of an objective political democracy. Marxists insist that political democracy without economic democracy is insufficient. The article argues that both propositions are valid and not mutually exclu- sive. It proposes the creation of an operational, quantifiable index of economic democracy that can be used alongside the already existing indexes of political democracy. By using these two indexes jointly, political and economic democracy can be objectively evaluated. Thus, the requirements of both camps are met and maybe a more dialogical approach to democracy can be reached in the debate between liberals and Marxists. The joint index is used to evaluate the levels of economic and political democracy in the transition countries of Eastern Europe. Keywords: democratic theory; transition countries; economic democracy Introduction iberalism and Marxism are two schools of thought which have left deep imprints Lin political, sociological and economic theory. Both have been very fruitful in il- luminating a wide range of common issues across these fields and yet are usually perceived 8 bpsr Liberalism, Marxism and Democratic Theory Revisited: Proposal of a Joint Index of Political and Economic Democracy as opposite, rival approaches contradicting each other in general.
    [Show full text]
  • Marxist Philosophy and Organization Studies: Marxist Contributions to the Understanding of Some Important Organizational Forms by Paul S
    1 Marxist philosophy and organization studies: Marxist contributions to the understanding of some important organizational forms by Paul S. Adler Dept. of Management and Organization Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles 90089-0808 Draft chapter for: Research in the Sociology of Organizations, Special Volume on Philosophy and Organization Theory, 2010, Guest editors: Haridimos Tsoukas and Robert Chia Version date: Feb 2, 2010 Author bio: Paul S. Adler is currently Harold Quinton Chair in Business Policy at the Marshall School of Business, University of Southern California.. He received his PhD in economics and management at the University of Picardie, France. His research and teaching focus on organization design, with a particular focus on technical, professional, and manufacturing operations. Acknowledgments Earlier drafts benefited from research assistance from Jade Lo and from comments by Michael Burawoy, Richard Delbridge, Steve Jaros, Martin Kenney, David Levy, Richard Marens, Mark Mizruchi, Craig Prichard, Mick Rowlinson, Paul Thompson, and Matt Vidal, even if there is much with which they still disagree. 2 Marxist philosophy and organization studies: Marxist contributions to the understanding of some important organizational forms Abstract This essay aims to how Marx’s ideas and subsequent Marxist-inspired scholarship have contributed to the analysis of the various forms of work organization. It summarizes Marx’s basic philosophy, theory of history, and critique of political economy; it distinguishes more critical and more optimistic variants of Marxist theory; and it then shows how these ideas have been used in the analysis of key organizational forms, contrasting Marxist versus non-Marxist approaches and critical versus optimistic versions of Marxism.
    [Show full text]
  • Educational Philosophy: from Classical Marxism to Critical Pedagogy
    Marxian Perspectives on Educational Philosophy: From Classical Marxism to Critical Pedagogy By Douglas Kellner (http://www.gseis.ucla.edu/faculty/kellner/) It is surely not difficult to see that our time is a time of birth and transition to a new period. The spirit has broken with what was hitherto the world of its existence and imagination and is about to submerge all this in the past; it is at work giving itself a new form. To be sure, the spirit is never at rest but always engaged in ever progressing motion.... the spirit that educates itself matures slowly and quietly toward the new form, dissolving one particle of the edifice of its previous world after the other,.... This gradual crumbling... is interrupted by the break of day that, like lightning, all at once reveals the edifice of the new world. Hegel 1965 [1807]: 380. The theory associated with Marxism was developed in mid-19th century Europe by Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels. Although Marx and Engels did not write widely about education, they developed theoretical perspectives on modern societies that have been used to highlight the social functions of education and their concepts and methods have served to both theorize and criticize education in the reproduction of capitalist societies, and to support projects of alternative education. In this study, I will first briefly sketch the classical perspectives of Marx and Engels, highlighting the place of education in their work. Then, I lay out the way that Marxian perspectives on education were developed in the Frankfurt School critical theory, British cultural studies, and other neo- Marxian and post-Marxian approaches grouped under the label of critical pedagogy, that emerged from the work of Paulo Freire and is now global in scope.
    [Show full text]
  • Sociology of Innovation: Social Construction of Technology Perspective Sociología De La Innovación: Construcción Social De La Perspectiva Tecnológica
    Nº 30 AD-MINISTER universidad eafit · medellín - colombia · january-june 2017 · ISSN 1692-0279 · e-ISSN: 2256-4322 SARA YOUSEFIKHAH JEL: M15, O35 DOI: 10.17230/ad-minister.30.2 www.eafit.edu.co/ad-minister 31 AD-MINISTER AD-minister Nº. 30 january-june 2017 pp. 31 - 43 · ISSN 1692-0279 · eISSN 2256-4322 SOCIOLOGY OF INNOVATION: SOCIAL CONSTRUCTION OF TECHNOLOGY PERSPECTIVE SOCIOLOGÍA DE LA INNOVACIÓN: CONSTRUCCIÓN SOCIAL DE LA PERSPECTIVA TECNOLÓGICA SARA YOUSEFIKHAH1 ABSTRACT SARA YOUSEFIKHAH1 This theoretical paper describes the effect of social action on technological artifacts and explores how innovation may flourish or be diminished in society. Using the Social Construction of Technology JEL: M15, O35 (SCOT) perspective, three main elements namely, flexibility of interpretation, relevant social groups and technological frame are described and their impact on innovation is discussed. The paper proposes that Received: 5-09-2016 in developing societies, flexibility is hardly pressed by technological frames and concrete social norms Modified: 23-11-2016 do not allow the alternative designs and the useage of artifacts. This paper proposes that innovation Accepted: 22-12-2016 might flourish in a society if technological frame change, and entrepreneurship become technological frames that can change the fixed meaning of artifacts and create a path for alternative designs and interpretations. DOI: 10.17230/ad-minister.30.2 www.eafit.edu.co/ad-minister Creative Commons (CC BY-NC- SA) KEYWORDS Innovation; Sociology of Technology; Social Construction of Technology; Innovation policy; Entrepreneurship Promotion. RESUMEN Este artículo académico de tipo teórico describe el efecto que tiene la acción social sobre los artefactos tecnológicos y explora cómo la innovación puede florecer o reducirse en la sociedad.
    [Show full text]
  • The Analytical Foundations of Contemporary Political Economy: a Comment on Hunt
    THE ANALYTICAL FOUNDATIONS OF CONTEMPORARY POLITICAL ECONOMY: A COMMENT ON HUNT Herbert Gintis I do not disagree with E. K. Hunt's admirable description of analytical Marxism, nor do I differ strongly with his characterization of its differences with traditional Marxism. These differences are deep and fundamental, to the point that rational choice Marxism can indeed be considered hostile to many of traditional Marxism's most basic tenets. In this essay I will neither attempt to defend analytical Marxism against Hunt's critique nor will I endorse this critique. I am not analytical Marxist, although I have sympathy with some of its positions. Nor am I a traditional Marxist, having made my peace with Marxism in my joint work with Samuel Bowles, Democracy and Capitalism: Property, Community, and the Contradictions of Modern Social Thought (1986). Marxism, I believe, has given us many important insights into the operation of society, but has no monopoly on truth. Rather than take sides, I propose here to elucidate the differences between the two, and offer an perspective missing in Hunt's critique: the venerable opposition between neoclassical and Marxian economic theory is antiquated and is increas­ ingly of purely historical interest This is true because both Marxism and neoclas­ sical economics are disintegrating in the face of contemporary political and theo­ retical concerns. Coming years will involve vast changes in all of economic theory, blurring the old distinctions, validating some concerns traditionally held by Marx­ ists, others
    [Show full text]
  • From Labor Process to Activity Theory
    FROM LABOR PROCESS TO ACTIVITY THEORY Paul S. Adler Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles CA 90089-0808 Email: [email protected] Version: May 26, 2004 Forthcoming in P. Sawchuk, M. Elhammoumi, abd N. Duarte, eds., Critical Perspectives on Activity Theory, Education and Work: An International Collection, Cambridge University Press 2 FROM LABOR PROCESS TO ACTIVITY THEORY ABSTRACT Starting with Braverman (1976), labor process theory has been an influential school of thought in the critical analysis of work. However, it has recently lost momentum. One reason for this loss of momentum is its inability to deal with evidence of a long-term upgrading trend in skill requirements. This inability results from the truncated reading of Marx that underpins labor process theory. It has ignored the fundamental contradiction Marx saw between the progressive socialization of the labor process and the persistence of capitalist profitability constraints. Activity theory provides a framework in which we can trace the various locii of the contradiction between socialization and profitability. I use this framework to analyze the rationalization of software development, and show how socialization has been simultaneously stimulated, retarded, and distorted by profitability pressures. 3 FROM LABOR PROCESS TO ACTIVITY THEORY As new technologies and new organizational forms proliferate, work is moving back to the center of organizational research (Barley, 1996; Barley and Kunda, 2001). And as interest in work grows, so too does the corresponding theoretical challenge: how best can we apprehend the nature of work itself and its links to both the organizational structure and to the lived experience of work? This essay returns to the roots of one of the more prominent theories of work organization, Labor Process Theory (LPT) (see Thompson, 1989; Wardell et al., 1999; Jermier, 1998).
    [Show full text]
  • Economics and Political Economy: Marx, Keynes, and Schumpeter Author(S): Robert L
    Economics and Political Economy: Marx, Keynes, and Schumpeter Author(s): Robert L. Heilbroner Source: Journal of Economic Issues, Vol. 18, No. 3 (Sep., 1984), pp. 681-695 Published by: Association for Evolutionary Economics Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4225467 . Accessed: 15/11/2013 23:53 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Association for Evolutionary Economics is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Economic Issues. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Fri, 15 Nov 2013 23:53:07 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions J; JOURNAL OF ECONOMICISSUES Vol. XVIII No. 3 September1984 Economics and Political Economy: Marx, Keynes, and Schumpeter Robert L. Heilbroner The centenaryconnection of the death of Karl Marx and the birth of J. M. Keynes and JosephSchumpeter is an historicalaccident that poses an unusualchallenge. One would think the occasion would provide an excusefor exploringthe lines of influenceemanating from Marx to Keynes and to Schumpeter,and the mutual interactionof the latter two. But that, I fear, would be disappointing.Marx exerteda profoundeffect on Schumpeter,as we all know.So far as Keyneswas concerned,Marx might as well have neverlived-at least that is the conclusionto whichI come whenreflecting on Keynes'sstatement that "the futurewill have more to learn from the spirit of Gesell than from that of Marx,"' a judgmentI attributeto the fact that Keyneshad probablyread more of Silvio Gesell thanof Marx.
    [Show full text]