5. Credit Constraints and Investment Finance: Some Evidence from Greece

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

5. Credit Constraints and Investment Finance: Some Evidence from Greece n 0 3 3 ro � Fund. Not for Redistribution Table 3. Financing of the Public Sector Deficit: Nominal flows Annual Rate of lnflatiofl o percent so percent 100 percent Last Month Year as Last Mooth Year as Last Month Year as Economic Indicator of Year a Whole of Year a Whole of Year a Whole Tolal ftnandng needs -o.0/330 -1.000 1.057 9.775 2.499 20.729 External debt Domestic liability Non-Interest-bearing 0.432 4.41 3 0.793 7.466 Interes t-bearing 0.097 10.000 2.245 20.000 Changes In reserves 0.08.30 1.000 0.332 ©International Monetary 4.538 0.539 5..736 Memorandum items: Changes Inresewes (in foreign currency! O.OB30 1.000 0.248 3.755 0.269 4.724 Note: Figures are arbitrary, reflecting approxrmarions to cases such as Mexrco and BraziL The figures were selectedso that 1 00 = GOP bef()(e inflation. 144 Ricardo Arriazu shown under the same inflationaryassumptions. This table should be interpreted in the following way. The country's financing needs, which are shown in the first line of the table, were obtained from the flows in Table 1. Since inflation also influences the nominal demand of economic agents for different financialassets, this element should be reflected in the economic policy assumptions. The assumptions used here reflect the desire of economic agents to maintain a constant real stock of interest-bearing debt instruments and a declining real stock of non-interest -bearing debt instruments. Under a fixed exchange rate, any difference between the financial needs of the public sector and the flow demand for financial assets of the private sector is adjusted through changes in reserves. In Table 3, accumulation of reserves is shown to increase with inflation, a result that seems incompatible with the absorption identity. A careful evaluation of the data, however, shows that this is not the case, as can be seen in Table 4. Table 4. Fiscal Imbalance, Inflationary Taxes, and Reserve Changes IEnd-of-penod nominal stocksl Annual Rate of Inflation Fund. Not for Redistribution Economic Indicator o percent so percent 100 percent Assets 1000 5.633 9.446 Reserves 1.000 5.633 9.446 Liabilities 80.000 119.413 157.466 Domestic Non-interest-bearing 10.000 14.413 17.466 Interest-bearing 20.000 30.000 40.000 External 50.000 75.000 100.000 Nominal net financial wealth -79.000 -113.780 -148.018 Inflation-adjusted net financial wealth -79.000 -75.853 -74.009 Changes In net financial wealth ©International Monetary At old prices 1.000 4.147 5.991 At new prices 1.000 6.220 11.982 Note: Figures are arbitrary, reflecting approximations to cases such as Mexico and Brazil. The figures were seleaed so that 100 = GOP before Inflation. Table 4 depicts the country's financial structure after the fiscal flows of the period and the changes in net financial wealth measured in terms of the new prices and the old prices have been taken into account. As this table shows, net financial wealth has improved somewhat during the period, a result that can only be consistent with a fiscal surplus. This improvement is consistent with the Comment 145 reserve accumulation shown in Table 2, and also exhibits the same tendency to increase with inflation. This apparent contradiction arises because Table 2, which is based exclusively on flows, does not take into account the decline in the real value of the domestic debt derived from inflation (the so-called inflationary tax). A brief analysis of these figures allows us to draw the following conclusions. There are several definitions of fiscal imbalances, and each has its particular usefulness. The most useful definitions are: (1) nominal flow imbalances (Table 2), which are a counterpart of the financing needs of the public sector; (2) total nominal deficit, which is the counterpart of the nominal changes in net financial wealth; (3) inflation-adjusted deficit, which is the counterpart of the "real" changes in net financial wealth (that is, the correct measurement of imbalances from a net wealth point of view; (4) dollar-adjusted deficit, which is a counterpart of variations in net financialwealth measured in dollar terms and is useful in the measurement of imbalances leading to current and balance of payments dis­ equilibria; and (5) zero-inflation deficit. This last concept, which measures the size of fiscal imbalances under the assumption of price stability, is perhaps the most important measurement for assessing the characteristics of a disequi­ librium for adjustment purposes. It should not be used in combination with the inflation-adjusted concept, which attempts to measure the size of the imbalance Fund. Not for Redistribution after allthe distortions in troducedby inflation have been eliminated, whereas the zero-inflation deficit includes all these di stortions and, in addition, includes under revenues the amount of inflationary tax collected. In a sense, the zero­ inflation deficit is an ex-ante concept that measures the magnitude of the adjustment required to eliminate inflationary and external sector pressures, whereas the inflation-adjusted deficitis an ex-post concept that incorporates the real resource transfers originating in inflation. Inflation tends to increase the nominal flow deficit. These increases tend to be large; the larger the interest-bearing domestic debt, the larger the fiscal lag. Inflation also tends to be higher, the larger the size of the zero-inflation deficit, the smaller the non-interest-bearing debt, the larger the fiscal lags, and the ©International Monetary faster the run out of a currency. Reconciliation of nominal flow figures with the changes in nominal net financial wealth is feasible, but it requires elaborate measurements of the inflationary tax and other inflation-induced distortions. Table 5 shows, as an example, these calculations for the year as a whole, under the assumption of a 50percent rate of inflation. Inthis table, the gross inflationary tax was measured not only in relation to the original stock of non-interest-bearing domestic debt (10 x 0.5), but also in terms of the monthly flow demand for this asset. The effects of inflation on taxation (fiscal lags) were measured by comparing the amount of perceived taxes in the 146 Ricardo Arriazu Table 5. Changes In Net Financial Wealth, Inflationary Taxes, and Nominal Flow component Change Changes In net financial wealth at new prices 6.220 Zero-inflation surplus at new prices 1.500 Gross inflationary tax 5.870 Fiscal lags -1.137 Cross effects and interest compounding -0.010 Note: Figures are arbitrary, reflecting approximations to cases such as Mexico and Brazil. The figures were selected so that 100 = GOP before 1nflat10n. case of fullindexation with the fl.ows shown in Ta ble 2. The zero-inflation surplus corresponds to the financial needs figure under the heading "zero inflation," measured at the new prices. The last item ("cross effects") originates in the compounded effects of real interest rates and inflation. Gross, Net, and Effective Net Inflationary Taxes The analysis in the previous paragraphs shows that there are at least three Fund. Not for Redistribution relevant concepts associated with inflationary taxation. Gross inflationary tax corresponds to the concept traditionally used in the literature. It measures the decline in the real value of public sector non-interest­ bearing debt It is normally measured in terms of liquid monetary assets (Ml), but from a fiscal point of view should be measured in terms of the public sector debt. It should include not only the initial stock but also the effects of inflation on the real value of the fl.ow demand of this instrument. In circumstances when negative real interest rates prevail, the measurements should also include these effects. Net inflationary tax is defined as the difference between the gross inflationary tax and the other effects of inflation on the public sector budget (fiscal lags, all ©International Monetary effects on real interest rates, etc.). It should be clear that changes in net financial wealth equal zero-inflation budget plus net inflationary tax. Net effective inflationary taxmeasures the effects of inflation on the financing possibilities of the public sector. It is equal to the net inflationary taxminus the "runout of domestic debt instruments." As economic agents try to avoid paying the inflationary tax, the decline in the real demand for domestic debt instruments reduces the financing possibilities of the public sector. In the extreme case when the net effective inflationary taxturns negative, even though inflation will tend to improve the net financial wealth of a country, the improvement will beof no help in satisfying the financial needs of the public sector. In these circumstances, Comment 147 inflation is a very inefficient adjustment mechanism, since the financing needs will grow faster than the financing sources and will be initially reflected in reserves losses and eventually in hyperinflation. Negative net effective inflationary taxes wi ll tend to be present in countries with persistent inflationary pressures where the stock demand for public sector debt instruments is very low and fiscal lags tend to be very large. Fund. Not for Redistribution ©International Monetary Comment Richard Portes As in so much of recent macroeconomics, the stock-flow distinction lies at the heart of this excellent treatment of the macroeconomic basis of International Monetary Fund (IMF) adjustment programs for indebted less-developed coun­ tries. In particular, the relations between fiscal deficits, domestic public debt, external debt, and debt service must be elucidated. This requires a clear intertemporal perspective as well as an understanding of the complexities of actual adjustment programs. The precise characteristics of adjustment will determine whether a current flow imbalance translates over time into a stock maladjustment, carrying its own consequences for flows.
Recommended publications
  • Reaganomics and the Welfare State
    The Journal of Sociology & Social Welfare Volume 10 Issue 4 November Article 4 November 1983 Reaganomics and the Welfare State Mimi Abramovitz Hunter College Tom Hopkins Fordham University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.wmich.edu/jssw Part of the American Politics Commons, Economic History Commons, and the Social Work Commons Recommended Citation Abramovitz, Mimi and Hopkins, Tom (1983) "Reaganomics and the Welfare State," The Journal of Sociology & Social Welfare: Vol. 10 : Iss. 4 , Article 4. Available at: https://scholarworks.wmich.edu/jssw/vol10/iss4/4 This Article is brought to you by the Western Michigan University School of Social Work. For more information, please contact [email protected]. REAGANOMICS AND THE WELFARE STATE Mimi Abramovitz, DSW Hunter College School of Social Work Tom Hopkins, DSW Fordham University Graduate School of Social Services ABSTRACT Supply-side tax and spending policies have intensified poverty, unemployment and inequality, especially for women, minorities and organized labor. At the same time Reaganomics is shrinking and weakening the welfare state. To better understand and resist this conservative assault it is necessary to demystify the "eco- nomics" and "politics" of supply-side doctrine. This paper (a) defines the basic assumptions of supply-side economics; (b) iden- tifies some of its problems and contradictions; (c) discusses its impact on the welfare state; and (d) analyzes it as part of a broader plan for coping with the current economic crisis. It argues that the supply-side tax cut not only lowers government revenues, but provides a justification for cutting domestic pro- grams. Domestic cutbacks, in turn, are achieved by new laws that change program rules and regulations, transfer federal social welfare responsibility to the states, that weaken the political support for the programs themselves.
    [Show full text]
  • Report Card on Reaganomics Stanley Antoniotti Bridgewater State College
    Bridgewater Review Volume 2 | Issue 1 Article 11 Oct-1983 The Last Word: Report Card on Reaganomics Stanley Antoniotti Bridgewater State College Recommended Citation Antoniotti, Stanley (1983). The Last Word: Report Card on Reaganomics. Bridgewater Review, 2(1), 28. Available at: http://vc.bridgew.edu/br_rev/vol2/iss1/11 This item is available as part of Virtual Commons, the open-access institutional repository of Bridgewater State University, Bridgewater, Massachusetts. • • • The Last Word. uring the 1980 presidential In January of 1981, the unemployment rate or a decrease of greater than two percent. campaign, then candidate Reagan was 7.4 percent of the labor force. This was During this period the GNPdipped as low as D asked if we were "better off now about 7,847,000 people who were out of $1.4707 trillion. This is negative economic than we were four years ago." It is now 1983 work. The unemployment rate for June of growth. In other words, we were producing and we are more than half way through his 1983 was 9.5 percent. This was more than less goods and services during this period of term in office. It, therefore, seems 11,000,000 people. In terms of change this the Reagan Administration. appropriate that we look at the American was an increase of two percent or over In January of 1981 an annual interest rate . economy and see if we are indeed better off 3,000,000 people in the unemployment lines on a regular home mortgage in the Boston as a result of President Reagan's economic since the President took office.
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • THE EMERGING WORLDVIEW: How New Progressivism Is Moving Beyond Neoliberalism a Landscape Analysis
    THE EMERGING WORLDVIEW: How New Progressivism Is Moving Beyond Neoliberalism A Landscape Analysis REPORT BY FELICIA WONG JANUARY 2020 ABOUT THE ROOSEVELT INSTITUTE Until the rules work for every American, they’re not working. The Roosevelt Institute is a think tank and student-driven national network that believes in an economy and democracy by the people, for the people. The few at the top—corporations and the richest among us— hold too much wealth and power today, and our society will be stronger when that changes. Armed with a bold vision for the future, we want our work to move the country toward a new economic and political system: one built by many for the good of all. ABOUT THE AUTHOR ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Felicia Wong is the president and CEO of the Roosevelt This report draws on research Institute, which seeks to reimagine the social and economic and analysis conducted by Nell policies of Franklin and Eleanor Roosevelt for the 21st century. Abernathy, Ariel Evans, Mike She is the coauthor of Hidden Rules of Race: Barriers to Konczal, and Katy Milani. The an Inclusive Economy (Cambridge University Press, 2017). author thanks Joelle Gamble, She holds a PhD in political science from the University of Angela Hanks, Jennifer Harris, California, Berkeley. Chris Hughes, Michael Linden, JW Mason, Julie Margetta Morgan, Lenore Palladino, Brishen Rogers, K. Sabeel Rahman, Ganesh Sitaraman, Dorian Warren, and Tracy Williams for their comments and insight. Roosevelt staff Kendra Bozarth, Matt Hughes, Jeff Krehely, Tayra Lucero, and Victoria Streker all contributed to the project. This report was made possible with the generous support of the Hewlett Foundation and the Omidyar Network.
    [Show full text]
  • The Return of Deregulation and Trickle-Down Economics in the Age of Trump: Why the Efficient Market Hypothesis Refuses to Die and the Implications for U.S
    THE RETURN OF DEREGULATION AND TRICKLE-DOWN ECONOMICS IN THE AGE OF TRUMP: WHY THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS REFUSES TO DIE AND THE IMPLICATIONS FOR U.S. ECONOMIC POLICY AT LARGE Matthew Glass Abstract The 2008 market collapse created economic devastation not seen in the United States since the Great Depression. More than a decade later, the reappearance of a fiscal agenda rooted in deregulation and trickle-down economics risks a return to the boom and bust cycles that have unfailingly wrought great economic pain on the American people. The ever-increasing inequality gap between the rich and poor is particularly concerning. I. Introduction As more than a decade has passed since the height of the 2008 financial crisis, it seems many of the prevailing views that dominated Wall Street before the market’s collapse are beginning to return in vogue, most notably, deregulation and trickle- down economics. At the heart of the belief that massive regulation is what ails the U.S. economy, there seems to be a recurrence of the hyperbolic rhetoric that mirrors the prior peaks of the Efficient Market Hypothesis (“EMH”) gone awry.1 Believing that highly efficient markets are great for a country’s economy is far different from believing in “perfectly rational” markets. Time and time again, this philosophy has proven to be correlated with the massive financial crises in the United States and around the world.2 Underlying this phenomenon is the crux of the issue—a blanket faith in wholly rational markets almost always is accompanied by a deregulation J.D., with a specialized concentration in international law, 2018, Shepard Broad College of Law at Nova Southeastern University; B.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Neoliberalism, Capital Accumulation, and Austerity in Academia, the Term
    Neoliberalism, Capital Accumulation, and Austerity Mehdi S. Shariati, Ph.D. Professor, Economics, Sociology and Geography Kansas City Kansas City Community College Abstract Recent crisis in global capitalism has once again brought to the fore major structural contradictions and the consequences of these contradictions are reflected in the massive dislocation of the economy, growing number of (the) poor, concentration of wealth in the hands of a few around the globe, indebtedness, rampant speculation and an unprecedented concentration of financial capital at the expense of productive sector of the economy. The austerity program by which the global working class must endure has generated much social protests including "occupy Wall Street," but with very little discussion of an alternative to the current global system. In academia, the term descriptive of finance capital’s policy prescription is “neoliberalism.” Yet the term not only has created confusion since in the North American context, liberals and neoliberals have always been viewed as left leaning people and not the free marketers and market fundamentalists. Neoliberalism often refers to a set of economic policies designed for intense and accelerated capital accumulation. Rarely the discussion of the process of intense capital accumulation includes a restructuring of society and social institutions as a precondition for the successful implementation of the policies. This paper is an attempt to add to the discussion by pointing out the indispensability of the practice of social imperialism in the process of reproducing the hegemonic structure and effective implementation of the policy. Reaction to the evolving socio-economic and political events has been one of the greatest preoccupation in the social and political sciences as a habit and of necessity.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Pynchon's Vineland and the Neoliberal Shift in America Daniel Williams, Adrienne Hayes, and Hunter Atkins, Researchers and Authors; Dr
    “Impossibly Complicated Tales of Dispossession and Betrayal”: Thomas Pynchon's Vineland and the Neoliberal Shift in America Daniel Williams, Adrienne Hayes, and Hunter Atkins, Researchers and Authors; Dr. Todd Hoffman Faculty Advisor CURS Summer Scholars Program, Georgia Regents University, Augusta, Georgia Abstract Context CONCLUSIONS The 1970s were characterized by the ascendancy of a particular breed of right wing conservatism that Neoliberalism in Pynchon’s Vineland What is Neoliberalism? Thomas Pynchon presents a snapshot of neoliberalism’s rise in America through depictions of: Neoliberalism is an anti-interventionist economic theory that incorporates advanced neoliberal reforms and precipitated the 1980 election of Ronald Reagan. As an economic theory, • the use of the media (“the Tube”) to alter ideological modes of thought traditional laissez-faire values into the schema of a highly modernized economy. Historically, in American politics, the theory has been implemented by right wing neoliberalism proposes that the government de-regulate markets and ease financial burdens on • the disenfranchisement of a generation of left-wing thinkers and the dilution of authenticity surrounding America´s collective perception of foreign cultures political parties, starting with President Ronald Reagan and continuing through • various branches of law enforcement which represent growing martial power and infringement upon the rights of the working class to today. The stance mainly consists of: corporations thus enabling wealth to be evenly distributed
    [Show full text]
  • Decoupling Neoliberal Ideologies with American Governance and Civics
    University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana Undergraduate Theses, Professional Papers, and Capstone Artifacts 2021 Decoupling Neoliberal Ideologies with American Governance and Civics Henry J. DeLuca University of Montana, Missoula, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umt.edu/utpp Part of the Agricultural and Resource Economics Commons, American Politics Commons, Civic and Community Engagement Commons, and the Environmental Studies Commons Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation DeLuca, Henry J., "Decoupling Neoliberal Ideologies with American Governance and Civics" (2021). Undergraduate Theses, Professional Papers, and Capstone Artifacts. 353. https://scholarworks.umt.edu/utpp/353 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by ScholarWorks at University of Montana. It has been accepted for inclusion in Undergraduate Theses, Professional Papers, and Capstone Artifacts by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks at University of Montana. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Henry DeLuca, Peter McDonough Decoupling Neoliberal Ideologies with American Governance and Civics Neoliberalism is commonly defined as a political ideology rooted in the belief of free market competition, laissez-faire economics and federal deregulation. Though the purpose and intent of neoliberalism is debated, it is largely agreed upon that the driving principle of neoliberal economics are associated with the belief that continual economic growth is inherent to human wellbeing, and markets are the best means of achieving this goal. Neoliberalism can be understood as a derivative between liberalism and capitalism. Fundamentally, each is reliant upon free markets and an individual’s ability to act independently from the economic restraints of their political institution.
    [Show full text]
  • Was This Recession Different?
    GEORGE L. PERRY Brookings Institution CHARLES L. SCHULTZE Brookings Institution Was This Recession Dij,ferent? Are They All Dij,ferent? THE RECENT RECESSION and disappointingrecovery have renewed in- terest in the cyclical behaviorof the economy. The latest recession was the eighth in the last forty years. Each has involved massivejob losses and sharplyreduced rates of capital formation.Each has also reduced the inflationrate, althoughnot always for long. The leadingcandidates for explainingthese episodes are variationsin fiscal and monetarypoli- cies, shocks to the economy from exogenous developmentsapart from policy, the internaldynamics of the economy, andcombinations of some or all of these factors. In this paper we attemptto answer a numberof questions about the recent recession and its predecessors. Are recessions generically spe- cial in the sense that economic relationsare differentin some systematic way? If they are differentfrom nonrecessionperiods, what are the fam- ily resemblancesamong recessions and in what ways have they differed from each other? In particular,how was the latest recession different from others, either in how economic activity unfolded and reacted to policy, in how policy changed in reaction to economic developments, in what broughton the recession, or in what made the initial stages of recovery so weak? Have financialdevelopments played a special role in the latest recession and the weak recoveryfrom it? How potent are fiscal andmonetary policies aroundrecessions, how much of the variationsin outputdo they explain, and how much is left to be explainedby shocks? The paper has three main parts. First, we undertakea comparative analysisof the behaviorand interactionof the main componentsof out- 145 146 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1993 put and majorpolicy variables aroundrecessions.
    [Show full text]
  • President Reagan's Economic Legacy: the Great Expansion
    President Reagan’s Economic Legacy: The Great Expansion October 2000 Joint Economic Committee Staff Report Office of the Chairman, Connie Mack President Reagan’s Economic Legacy: The Great Expansion The Reagan Legacy: A Personal View by Senator Connie Mack....... 1 I. The Conditions for Strong Economic Growth ................................ 11 A. Property Rights and Political Stability............................................................. 12 B. Price Stability ................................................................................................... 12 C. Competitive Markets ........................................................................................ 13 D. Openness to International Trade and Investment............................................. 14 E. Limited Government......................................................................................... 14 II. The Prelude to Reagan: The U.S. Economy in the 1970s ............. 17 A. High Inflation ................................................................................................... 17 B. A High and Rising Tax Burden........................................................................ 18 C. Energy Shortages and Regulatory Failures ...................................................... 18 III. The Reagan Program...................................................................... 20 A. Price Stability................................................................................................... 20 B. Tax Cuts ..........................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Reaganomics Or Financial Innovation?
    Financial Meltdown from Atlantic to Pacific: Reaganomics or Financial Innovation? S. N. JEHAN and Minh Phuong HUYNH Ritsumeikan Asia Pacific University Abstract Financial markets from New York to London and Tokyo are still reeling from the most severe crisis since the Great Depression of the 1930s. At the center of the crisis are complex structured credit products and innovative financial instruments which have enjoyed a boom during the deregulation era of the last ten years. Deregulation was first promoted in President Ronald Reagan’s economic policy, known as “Reaganomics,” in the 1980s. Since then, there has been less government oversight of the financial markets. This lack of regulatory oversight has not only been restricted only to the U.S.; markets across Europe and Asia have also enjoyed the “hay-ride” without caring about the long-term consequences. A decade of deregulation has resulted in more opaque financial markets in many respects, with lightly regulated or nearly unregulated innovative investment instruments. This paper shows that the growth of unregulated financial innovation, facilitated by reckless deregulation, has made the markets less transparent and less stable, leading to the recent financial crisis. It discovers the link between Reaganomics deregulation and the growth of financial innovation. It explains how financial innovation in the markets, without an adequate supervisory and monitoring system, led to the meltdown in global financial markets, including Asia- Pacific markets. Keywords: deregulation, financial crisis, financial innovation, Reaganomics, structural finance Introduction The most recent financial crisis, spearheaded by defaults in the U.S. mortgage market in 2007, has caused widespread disruption to the global financial system.
    [Show full text]
  • Interpretations of Globalisation
    CHAPTER 1 INTERPRETATIONS OF GLOBALISATION Globalisation, either as a concept or a phenomenon, has not yet been precisely defined. It appears differently in neoliberalism, neo-Marxism and Giddens’ ‘Third Way’. The differences arise from the different foci of the theories and evolve with these theories development. For the purpose of analysis, a definition of globalisation is given in this chapter. This analysis requires an understanding of the different interpretations on globalisation by the three theories. In order to better understand the basic principles embedded in neoliberalism, this chapter also investigates the role of world institutions and the state. A SURVEY OF NEOLIBERALISM, NEO-MARXISM AND GIDDENS’ THIRD WAY Neoliberalism Neoliberalism has prevailed around the globe for over two decades. Historically speaking, neoliberalism was at its peak during the period of trans-Atlantic cooperation between then American President Ronald Reagan and then British Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher in the 1980s (and pre-eminent in New Zealand under Finance Ministers Roger Douglas in the mid- to late-1980s and Ruth Richardson in the early 1990s). It is still influential, indeed prevalent, even though it has lost some of its dominance since the 1990s because of growing awareness of, and resistance to, its negative consequences, such as widening the divide between rich and poor nations and rich and poor within nations, and curtaining ecological consciousness. The WB, the IMF, the WTO, the Asia Development Bank (ADB), the OECD, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and the GATS have promoted neoliberal policies like privatisation, free trade, lowering labour costs and shrinking public expenditure (Peters, 2001b; Bourdieu, 1998; MRTA, 2000).
    [Show full text]