Financing Productive Local Public Goods

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Financing Productive Local Public Goods European Regional Science Association 36th European Congress ETH Zurich, Switzerland 26-30 August 1996 Gilles Duranton London School of Economics London, UK [email protected] Stéphane Déo CEME, Université Paris I Paris, France [email protected] FINANCING PRODUCTIVE LOCAL PUBLIC GOODS Abstract: Local public economics typically assumes that local public goods only affect the utility of consumers. We assume on the contrary that local public goods are purely productive. The implications of this assumption are analyzed within standard dynamic growth models. Investment in the public good is enhancing productivity only in the jurisdiction where it takes place. Capital as well as people are perfectly mobile. After characterizing the first-best equilibrium, we show that its decentralization is more demanding than with consumptive local public goods. In particular, efficient decentralization cannot be obtained with competing land developers providing the public good through a simple land capitalization scheme. I. INTRODUCTION How can an economy achieve optimal provision of local public goods (LPG)? Traditional public economics, originating from Samuelson [1954], stresses the difficulty of the question. Basically, a decentralized scheme cannot be implemented because of a standard free-rider problem. Moreover, the first order conditions for the central planner to achieve first-best require him to observe the consumers' marginal rates of substitution. So, even with a benevolent planner, the optimum is difficult to reach. However, Tiebout [1956] came with a clever alternative solution. His answer to the pivotal question raised above was to rely on the local aspects of some public goods. The idea is to use competition among the jurisdictions. In his original paper, assuming an optimal number of jurisdictions led by profit-maximizing developers, people by voting with their feet, can choose between different levels of provision for the public good and the associated head-taxes. Then the equilibrium attained in a perfectly competitive framework is the first-best. Yet the assumption of an ex-ante optimal number of jurisdictions and the possibility of head- taxes are rather restrictive. However, the subsequent literature (see Wildasin [1987] or Mieszkowski and Zodrow [1989] for complete surveys on this issue) managed to relax them elegantly1. The Tiebout idea relies on the strong analogy between fiscal competition and the competition to supply private goods. Consequently free-entrance of developers leads to the first-best just as free-entrance of producers can achieve the first welfare theorem for private goods. As for the head-tax, the idea is to replace it by using the land market. Implementation of the first-best just requires the developer to be able to take advantage of the differential land rent in her jurisdiction since public spendings are capitalized in the land value. This differential2 land rent stems from the agents' competition for space. The profit function of each developer in the most direct case is equivalent to total differential land rent (TDR) minus expenses for the public good (G). Then an immediate implication of the zero-profit condition is TDR = G. This result is known as the Henry George Theorem (George [1879]). Then the only informational requirement to implement the first-best in a decentralized way is the observation of the land market. This result appears in Flatters, Henderson and Mieszkowski [1974], Vickrey [1977] or Arnott and Stiglitz [1979] among others. Of course it relies on strong assumptions. It is not valid with: - Imperfect competition, see Scotchmer [1986] and Duranton [1996]. - Imperfect geography (if the land-rent is not well-defined at the border of the city), see Arnott and Stiglitz [1979] and Pines [1991]. - Congestion, see Scotchmer [1986] and Fujita [1989]. 1 - Imperfect taxation (if only a property tax is available instead of a land tax), see Mieszkowski [1972] or Hoyt [1991]. - Imperfect mobility (if agents cannot vote with their feet at zero cost). - Economy-wide externality, see Henderson and Abdel-Rahman [1991]. Despite all this, Tiebout's idea seems to receive some empirical support: Oates [1969], Edel and Sclar [1974], Hamilton [1976], Meadows [1976] or more recently Wassmer [1993] all draw favorable conclusions. Moreover, some important projects are explicitly funded by land capitalization schemes. One can think for instance of the railways in Tokyo (Kanemoto [1984], Kanemoto and Kiyono [1993], Midgley [1994]) or the public transports in Hongkong (Midgley [1994]). Strange as it might be, most potential applications of the capitalization hypothesis (i.e., financing the public goods with the differential land rent) are dealing with infrastructures (which are 'productive public goods'3), whereas the theoretical analysis seems to focus mainly on 'consumptive' public goods (which enter directly the utility function). It is possible to stress that user-charges can usually provide convenient albeit not always simple pricing schemes for infrastructures. A general synthesis on these aspects is provided by Laffont and Tirole [1993]. But, the stylized fact we want to put forward here is that public infrastructures do matter and do matter locally. So, the main problem is that for most infrastructure, distances seem to matter (be it a road network, an airport facility or even electricity or water distribution), whereas perfect spatial discriminatory pricing is seldom available. Consequently producers tend to favor some localizations at the expense of others (see World Bank [1994]). Hence, the local aspect is hard to ignore. Our aim in what follows is to assess in what measure the land market can contribute to the financing of productive local public goods. Another possible perspective is to consider that most local public goods usually treated as consumptive public goods also have a productive aspect. Indeed, only purely recreational public goods such as parks and museums can be considered as purely consumptive public goods. Even in these extreme cases, it may be argued that they have some productive aspects: museums can improve education, whose productive role is obvious4. The quality of leisure has also an impact on production. A last motivation is that local public economics typically recommends that local expenses should be financed through land taxation or property taxation. However property taxes represent only a fraction of local public finances (see Prud'Homme [1987] and Henderson [1995] for evidences). The problem is to know why non land-based instruments are used at the public level with such a pervasive insistence. For consumptive public goods, the economic analysis is one of partial equilibrium by nature. 2 We just need to consider an exogenous income, which generates a demand for the public good mediated by the land markets. Then, the problem is to see how the public good can be financed through the land market. On the contrary, in our case of productive public good, the initial income generates a demand for private goods, for land and for savings. Using the demand for land, it is possible to finance local public goods but the story does not end here, since the savings and the amount of public good determine the production at the next period. A dynamic general equilibrium model is thus a natural tool. In other words, the analysis of productive public goods is inherently dynamic, because public capital can be accumulated and influences further production. Since we can reasonably assume that private producers operate with constant returns to scale, taking into account public capital which increases their productivity amounts to considering increasing returns at the aggregate level. For these reasons, our dynamic model embodies increasing returns. Then we test whether the classical results are still valid as the productive aspect of all public goods is taken into account. It is shown that although Tiebout style (i.e., first-best) results can be obtained, they are very demanding and must rely on strong assumptions. The Henry George Theorem does not hold in the usual sense. Simple capitalization schemes do not work because the marginal product of public investment benefits to both the workers who live in the jurisdiction and also to capital holders who need not live where their savings are invested. Land rent capitalizes the increase in wages caused by public investment only up to the share of housing in expenditures. On the contrary, increased public investments raise the interest rate and thus the income of everyone and the demand for land in all jursidictions. In section II, we propose a simple framework of a competitive production economy with productive public goods. In section III, we analyze various decentralized frameworks. Finally the last section ends the analysis with some considerations concerning the provision of local public goods. II. ECONOMIES WITH PRODUCTIVE PUBLIC GOODS: THE FIRST-BEST We consider a large economy of surface S populated by individuals of mass N such that S > N L* , where 1 L* is the minimal amount of land to be consumed in order to enjoy a positive instantaneous utility. According to standard assumptions, we consider that each unit of land can be considered as a separate island. Our individuals are infinitely-lived or finitely- lived with a dynastic utility function and they supply continuously one unit of labor inelastically : 3 1−σ +∞ (u ) −ρ U = ∫ t e tdt 0 1−σ = x ≥ * with ut zt.st if st 1 L (1) = < * ut 0 if st 1 L σ > 1 Instantaneous utility is a Cobb-Douglas function5 of z, the consumption of the good and s, the quantity of land. For each 'island' of surface one, we face the production function: β 1−α α α ≥β> Yt = A.Gt . Kt .Lt with x (2) Note that s = 1 L since we suppose that people should live and work on the same unit of land. For the sake of simplicity any unit of capital (K), labor (L) or public spending (G) can be used only in one island (there is no overlap6) and we ignore depreciation.
Recommended publications
  • Taxation of Land and Economic Growth
    economies Article Taxation of Land and Economic Growth Shulu Che 1, Ronald Ravinesh Kumar 2 and Peter J. Stauvermann 1,* 1 Department of Global Business and Economics, Changwon National University, Changwon 51140, Korea; [email protected] 2 School of Accounting, Finance and Economics, Laucala Campus, The University of the South Pacific, Suva 40302, Fiji; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +82-55-213-3309 Abstract: In this paper, we theoretically analyze the effects of three types of land taxes on economic growth using an overlapping generation model in which land can be used for production or con- sumption (housing) purposes. Based on the analyses in which land is used as a factor of production, we can confirm that the taxation of land will lead to an increase in the growth rate of the economy. Particularly, we show that the introduction of a tax on land rents, a tax on the value of land or a stamp duty will cause the net price of land to decline. Further, we show that the nationalization of land and the redistribution of the land rents to the young generation will maximize the growth rate of the economy. Keywords: taxation of land; land rents; overlapping generation model; land property; endoge- nous growth Citation: Che, Shulu, Ronald 1. Introduction Ravinesh Kumar, and Peter J. In this paper, we use a growth model to theoretically investigate the influence of Stauvermann. 2021. Taxation of Land different types of land tax on economic growth. Further, we investigate how the allocation and Economic Growth. Economies 9: of the tax revenue influences the growth of the economy.
    [Show full text]
  • A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Mattauch, Linus; Siegmeier, Jan; Edenhofer, Ottmar; Creutzig, Felix Working Paper Financing Public Capital through Land Rent Taxation: A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem CESifo Working Paper, No. 4280 Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Mattauch, Linus; Siegmeier, Jan; Edenhofer, Ottmar; Creutzig, Felix (2013) : Financing Public Capital through Land Rent Taxation: A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem, CESifo Working Paper, No. 4280, Center for Economic Studies and ifo Institute (CESifo), Munich This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/77659 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Financing Public Capital through Land Rent Taxation: A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem Linus Mattauch Jan Siegmeier Ottmar Edenhofer Felix Creutzig CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO.
    [Show full text]
  • Final RSF Digest October 2019
    O C T O B E R 2 0 1 9 , V O L . 1 RSF DIGEST N E W S L E T T E R O F T H E R O B E R T S C H A L K E N B A C H F O U N D A T I O N WHAT'S INSIDE? RSF'S NEXT CHAPTER 2 DIRECTORS' PERSPECTIVES 2 FEATURED PROJECTS 3 ANNOTATED WORKS RAFFLE 6 WHAT IS RSF? The Robert Schalkenbach Foundation (RSF) is a private operating foundation, founded in 1925, to promote public awareness of the social philosophy and economic reforms advocated by famed 19th century thinker and activist, Henry George. Today, RSF remains true to its founding doctrine, and through efforts focused on education, communities, outreach, and publishing, works to create a world in which all people are afforded the basic necessities of life and the natural world is protected for generations to come. MEN LIKE HENRY GEORGE ARE RARE UNFORTUNATELY. ONE CANNOT IMAGINE A MORE BEAUTIFUL COMBINATION OF INTELLECTUAL KEENESS, ARTISTIC FORM AND FERVENT LOVE OF JUSTICE. EVERY LINE IS WRITTEN AS IF FOR OUR GENERATION. THE SPREADING OF THESE WORKS IS A REALLY DESERVING CAUSE, FOR OUR GENERATION ESPECIALLY HAS MANY AND IMPORTANT THINGS TO LEARN FROM HENRY GEORGE. - ALBERT EINSTEIN Who was Henry George? Born in Philadelphia in 1839, Henry unjustly captured as rent by land owners Although Henry George is no longer a George was raised in a lower middle and monopolists, rather than made household name, his policy prescriptions class, devout Episcopalian home.
    [Show full text]
  • A Search-Theoretic Critique of Georgism
    A Search-Theoretic Critique of Georgism Zachary Gochenour Bryan Caplan George Mason University George Mason University [email protected] [email protected] February 14, 2012 Abstract We develop a critique of the single-tax proposal of Henry George. We present a simple search-theoretic model for the discovery of natural resources and show that a tax on the unimproved value of land is distortionary. We then consider the time inconsistency and regime uncertainty problem created by even incremental Georgist policy. We discuss historical cases of land reform and the subsequent challenge to re-establish a credible commitment to property rights in land and natural resources. Keywords: Henry George, search theory, property rights, natural resources, regime uncertainty JEL Classification Numbers: H21, Q15 1 1 Introduction \It is too narrow an understanding of production which confines it merely to the making of things. Production includes not merely the making of things, but the bringing of them to the consumer." Henry George, Progress and Poverty, Book I, Ch. 2 Nearly all of the literature in public finance involves analysis of existing policy or marginal changes, ignoring fundamental or radical reform.1 How- ever, as the governments of developed nations struggle with budget deficits2 and their counterparts in the developing world3 look for ways to get ahead, re- form advocates are making their case to policymakers interested in alternative solutions. The reform proposal which we critique here is the single-tax on the unimproved value of land, first developed by 19th Century American economist Henry George (1879). George claims that not only is a single-tax on land so- cially just, but that it does not distort economic activity because it taps the rent of land4 and not productive activity.
    [Show full text]
  • Henry George: Footnote in the History of Economic Thought Kris Feder, Ph.D
    SCI LIBRARY Henry George: Footnote in the History of Economic Thought Kris Feder, Ph.D. [A paper presented at the History of Economics Society, Babson College Conference, 12 June, 1994. Revised by the author for publication, July 1994. All Rights Reserved. Reprinted here with permission of the author] 1. THE SINGLE TAX COMPLEX A. "THE FORGOTTEN MAN" In graduate school I had the good fortune to study with Professor Ingrid Rima, author of one of the most widely-read texts on the history of economic thought. [ Rima, 1986] When I asked to write a term paper on George, she indulged my wish with a word of caution. "Henry George," she gently explained, "is merely a footnote in the history of economic thought." This took me somewhat by surprise, since I had heard that no economic writer had ever sold more books than had George. I had assumed that there must be some reasonable basis for his popularity, and that the profession would not have overlooked It. True, George never won acceptance within academia during his lifetime, largely by his own doing; he openly doubted the intellectual honesty of the professors, and even suggested that ordinary citizens could study political economy without the guidance of books and teachers. Surely by now, however, emotion will have long since cooled, and scholarship taken its place. Economists will have picked George clean, exploiting whatever useful ideas they can find, while carefully exposing the nature of his errors. Historians of thought will have searched beneath the particulars of personality, religion, class, and language to identify George's lasting contributions -- if any there are -- to economic science.
    [Show full text]
  • Henry George - Wikipedia, the Free Encyclopedia
    Henry George - Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Henry_George Henry George From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia Henry George Henry George (September 2, 1839 – October 29, 1897) was an American writer, politician and political Classical economics economist, who was the most influential proponent of the land value tax, also known as the "Single Tax" on land. He inspired the philosophy and economic ideology known as Georgism, that holds that everyone owns what they create, but that everything found in nature, most importantly land, belongs equally to all humanity. His most famous work is Progress and Poverty written in 1879; it is a treatise on inequality, the cyclical nature of industrial economies and possible remedies. Contents 1 Biography Henry George 2 Policy proposals 2.1 Monopolies Birth September 21, 1839 2.2 Chinese immigration Death October 29, 1897 (aged 58) 2.3 The Single Tax on Land 2.4 Free Trade Nationality American 2.5 Secret Ballots Contributions Georgism; studied land as a factor in 3 Political career economic inequality and business 4 Subsequent influence cycles; proposed land value tax 5 Economic contributions 6 Notes 7 References 8 Bibliography 9 See also 10 External links Biography George was born in Philadelphia, Pennsylvania to a lower-middle class family, the second of ten children of Richard S. H. George and Catharine Pratt (Vallance) George. His formal education ended at age 14 and he went to sea as a foremast boy at age 15 in April 1855 on the Hindoo, bound for Melbourne and Calcutta. He returned to Philadelphia after 14 months at sea to become an apprentice typesetter before settling in California.
    [Show full text]
  • Policy Paper on Tax Reform (Pdf)
    CSI Policy Study Civil Society Institute • Santa Clara University 500 El Camino Real • Santa Clara, CA 95053 • [email protected] • 408/554-6931 January 2006 The Ultimate Tax Reform: Public Revenue from Land Rent by Fred E. Foldvary** The U.S. tax system is widely perceived as too complex, too intrusive, and too demanding of workers’ paychecks. Taxes today claim a greater share of the average family’s budget than food, clothing, housing, and transportation combined.1 In 2005, the average American had to work 107 days just to pay taxes, compared to 44 days in 1930.2 Tax reform proposals, not surprisingly, are popular among voters and the politicians who If land value is taxed, the land will not represent them. President George W. Bush flee, shrink, or hide. A tax on land created an advisory panel on tax reform. value has no deadweight loss. Some economists and institutes have proposed reforms to flatten and simplify the income tax, or to replace it entirely with a national sales or consumption tax or value-added tax. These would be an improvement, but if we seek to reform taxes, we should consider all the possibilities and choose, as Milton Friedman puts it, the “least bad” tax. Even a relatively flat income tax imposes what economists call a “deadweight loss” or “excess burden” on society. Taxes on productive activity increase the price of labor or goods beyond economic costs, and so reduce the quantity provided. This reduction in production, income, and * Fred Foldvary received his Ph.D. in economics from George Mason University in Virginia.
    [Show full text]
  • A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem
    Financing Public Capital through Land Rent Taxation: A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem Linus Mattauch Jan Siegmeier Ottmar Edenhofer Felix Creutzig CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 4280 CATEGORY 1: PUBLIC FINANCE JUNE 2013 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded • from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com • from the RePEc website: www.RePEc.org • from the CESifo website: www.CESifoT -group.org/wp T CESifo Working Paper No. 4280 Financing Public Capital through Land Rent Taxation: A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem Abstract Financing productive public capital through distortionary taxes typically creates a trade-off: the optimal investment is determined as a compromise between efficiency-enhancing public investment and perturbing market efficiency, but is never socially optimal. In contrast, such a trade-off can often be avoided if public capital is financed by taxing rents of a fixed production factor, such as land. Here, we provide a macroeconomic version of the Henry George Theorem. Specifically, we prove that the socially optimal level of the public capital stock can be reached by a land rent tax, provided land is a more important production factor than public capital. JEL-Code: H210, H400, H540, Q240. Keywords: land rent tax, public investment, Henry George Theorem, social optimum. Linus Mattauch Jan Siegmeier Mercator Research Institute on Global Technical University of Berlin Commons and Climate Change Berlin / Germany Torgauer Str. 12-15 [email protected] Germany – 10829 Berlin [email protected] Ottmar
    [Show full text]
  • Making Markets Just: Reciprocity Violations As Key Intervention Points
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Richters, Oliver; Siemoneit, Andreas Working Paper Making markets just: Reciprocity violations as key intervention points ZOE Discussion Papers, No. 7 Provided in Cooperation with: ZOE. institute for future-fit economies, Bonn Suggested Citation: Richters, Oliver; Siemoneit, Andreas (2021) : Making markets just: Reciprocity violations as key intervention points, ZOE Discussion Papers, No. 7, ZOE. Institut für zukunftsfähige Ökonomien, Bonn This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/235556 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ www.econstor.eu Making Markets Just: Reciprocity Violations as Key Intervention Points Oliver Richters, Andreas Siemoneit ZOE Discussion Papers | No.
    [Show full text]
  • INTRODUCTION Reviving the Work of America's Most Original Economist
    INTRODUCTION Reviving the Work of America's Most Original Economist Andrew Mazzone and I collaborated on a project to review the work of the 19th-century American economist Henry George, especially his landmark book Progress and Poverty (1879) to see how George's work stood up in the light of modern economics and to determine what could be brought up to date and ap- plied to the contemporary world. We wanted to establish that George's work was relevant and also to criticize American aca- demic economics for having overlooked or rejected George both in his own time—when his work was a worldwide sensation— and afterward, even today. Andrew died suddenly in the middle of the project. This book is a tribute to him and completes what we began. George began his career as an author and public personality with Progress and Poverty, arguing that progress brought poverty in its wake and that poverty might even outpace progress—an important, original point of view that has not lost any of its relevance since George's time. In fact, in our age of burgeoning inequality it may be more relevant today than ever. The grounds for this paradoxical interlinking of progress and poverty lay in the effects of rising rents. For George, rents were payment—not for the use of land in the usual sense, but for pure access to specific spaces and locations. But why should some people have the right to limit others' access to the use of the earth; surely it belongs to us all? Worse, the limiting of access---by demand'- ing payment—would undermine the benefits of innovation and hard work.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics of Efficient Taxes on Land*
    The Economics of Efficient Taxes on Land* Nicolaus Tideman 1. Introduction Land can be taxed in a number of different ways. It can be taxed according to its area. It can be taxed according to estimates of its sale value, as occurs under the property tax of the U.S. and other countries. It can be taxed according to estimates of its rental value. Sales of land can be taxed according to selling price, or according to the difference between selling price and the previous selling price. This review is concerned with taxes on land that have little or no detrimental effects on economic incentives. Therefore it concentrates on taxes on land according to estimates of sale value or rental value. Taxes on land according to area discourage the use of marginal land. Taxes on land sales, whether the base is the full sale price or the increase in price since the previous sale, encourage people to hold on to land when someone else could use it more productively. These taxes are therefore excluded from this review. The review also excludes taxes on depletable minerals. Section 2 deals with classical views of taxes on land, covering the ideas of François Quesnay, Adam Smith, David Ricardo, James Mill, John McCulloch, John Stuart Mill and Henry George, and influences and controversies among these writers. The two issues that provoked the greatest disagreement were whether it was possible to separate the value of land from the value of improvements for tax purposes and whether or to what extent a tax on land could be fair.
    [Show full text]
  • A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem
    Financing public capital when rents are back: a macroeconomic Henry George Theorem Linus Mattauch,∗ Jan Siegmeier, Ottmar Edenhofer, Felix Creutzig January 30, 2018 Abstract By taxing rents, governments can avoid a trade-off between productivity- enhancing public investment and efficiency losses from raising funds. However, it is unclear whether the rents present in a growing econ- omy are sufficient to finance its socially optimal level. We prove that the social optimum can be attained if the income share from a fixed factor, such as land, exceeds the public investment requirement. We thus translate the Henry George Theorem from urban economics to neoclassical and endogenous growth settings: here, the socially opti- mal land rent tax rate is below 100 %. Our finding may address the underfunding of national infrastructure investments. JEL classification: H21, H54, Q24 Keywords: land rent, public investment, infrastructure, Henry George The- orem, optimal growth ∗Mattauch: Institute for New Economic Thinking at the Oxford Martin School and Environmental Change Institute, School of Geography and the Environment, Uni- versity of Oxford and Mercator Research Institute on Global Commons and Cli- mate Change, Eagle House, Walton Well Road, OX2 6ED Oxford, United Kingdom. ([email protected]). Siegmeier: Mercator Research Institute on Global Commons and Climate Change, Torgauer Strasse 12-15, D-10829 Berlin, Germany. ([email protected]). Edenhofer: Mercator Research Institute on Global Com- mons and Climate Change, Technical University of Berlin and Potsdam Institute for Cli- mate Impact Research, Torgauer Strasse 12-15, D-10829 Berlin (ottmar.edenhofer@pik- potsdam.de). Creutzig: Mercator Research Institute on Global Commons and Climate Change and Technical University of Berlin.
    [Show full text]