<<

Famine and Reform in North

Famine and Reform in *

Marcus Noland Abstract Institute for International North Korea has been in a food emergency for more than a dec- Economics

1750 Massachusetts Avenue ade and in the experienced a famine that may have claimed Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 N.W. one million lives. The crisis is distinguished by its protracted na- Washington, DC 20036 USA ture, and although conditions have eased somewhat in recent [email protected] years, the situation remains precarious, and the country could lapse back into famine. This paper reviews the origins of the North Korean food crisis, the impact of the 1990s famine, and the prospects for resolution of the emergency in light of economic re- forms initiated in 2002 and the subsequent diplomatic confronta- tion over the country’s nuclear weapons program.

1. Introduction

The Democratic People’s of Korea (DPRK), or North Korea, has been experiencing an ongoing food crisis for more than a decade. A famine in the late 1990s resulted in deaths of an estimated 600,000 to 1 million people out of a prefamine population of roughly 22 million.1 Since then, a combination of humanitarian food and development assistance has ameliorated the situation somewhat, but

* Nick Eberstadt, Gordon Flake, Aidan Foster-Carter, Ruediger Frank, Mark Manyin, Bill Newcombe, and Scott Snyder pro- vided helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper, as did the participants at seminars at Harvard University and the Asian Development Bank, the conference “Famine: Interdisci- plinary Perspectives from the Past and the Present,” sponsored by the European Science Foundation at Fondation des Treilles, and the meeting of the Asian Economic Panel held on 9–10 October 2003 in , . Scott Holladay and Paul Karner provided research assistance. 1 The issue of excess deaths is analyzed in more detail in section 5. Noland (2000) summarizes contemporaneous estimates of ex- cess deaths, which range from 220,000 to 3.5 million. On the difªculty of assessing North Korea’s population statistics, see Eberstadt and Banister (1992) and Eberstadt (2000).

Asian Economic Papers 3:2 © 2005 Institute for International Economics Famine and Reform in North Korea according to ofªcials of the Food Programme (WFP) and other observers, as of 2003 the country was on the precipice of yet another famine.

By standard statistical measures, North Korea is the world’s most militarized soci- ety, and its domestic incessantly proclaims the virtues of the country’s “military-ªrst” politics.2 Internally, all aspects of North Korean society are suffused with politics; externally, politics thoroughly permeates not only the country’s diplo- matic ties but also its economic relations. If there were comparable standards for the measurement of “politicization,” North Korea would likely rank ªrst in this cate- Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 gory as well.

Given the extreme preference of the current regime in North Korea for guns over butter, the North Korean economy does not produce enough output to sustain its population, and population maintenance is aid-dependent. Yet the October 2002 revelation of a nuclear weapons program based on highly enriched uranium (in ad- dition to a plutonium-based program acknowledged a decade earlier), undertaken in contravention of several international agreements, and North Korea’s subsequent withdrawal from the Nuclear Nonproliferation have put continued interna- tional assistance in doubt.

The food crisis is further complicated by internal economic policy changes initiated by the North Korean government in mid-2002. These reforms include marketization of the economy, a large increase in the overall price level, the promotion of special economic zones, and diplomatic overtures that signal willingness to normalize rela- tions with and ultimately aim to secure billions of considered “post- colonial claims.” These initiatives are expected to affect the availability of food on both the supply and demand sides. On the supply side, the government hopes that the procurement price increases it has initiated will spur the production of addi- tional supply. Because North Korean agriculture is highly input-intensive (e.g., it makes extensive use of chemical and insecticides and relies heavily on electrically powered irrigation systems), the ultimate impact of the reforms on agri- cultural yields could be strongly inºuenced by economic changes in the industrial sector. On the demand side, the government may be trying to ensure survival ra- tions by maintaining the public distribution system (PDS), the system by

2 During its war with Ethiopia, the percentage of ’s population under arms and its mili- tary expenditure as a share of GDP exceeded the comparable ªgures for North Korea, but with the cessation of hostilities in the , North Korea has reasserted its historic primacy on these measures. See www.kcna.co.jp for a sample of North Korean domestic dis- course.

2 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea which most North historically obtained food, and by allowing citizens to purchase food in the market to supplement these rations.

The increase in agricultural procurement prices was presumably undertaken to in- crease the amount of food entering the PDS. However, PDS prices have remained largely unchanged since 1 July 2002, and market prices have increased signiªcantly, so whatever the motivation for the price increases, it is unclear whether the policy is having its intended effect. Given the growing inequality in the distribution of income and wealth within North Korea, which could accentuate differences in Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 access to food and exacerbate the already highly stressed nature of North Korean society, it would not be surprising to observe increases in mortality rates in the future.

2. Historical background

Prior to the of the Korean peninsula at the end of the War, most Korean industries were located in the north; the south was the country’s . In the period immediately following the Second World War and the ex- pulsion of Japanese colonialists, the Korean peninsula was partitioned into zones of Soviet and American military occupation in the north and south, respectively. In the Soviet-occupied zone, land belonging to Korean landlords and Japanese colonialists was seized and redistributed to the peasantry during 1945–46. This land reform was accompanied by a dramatic fall in agricultural output, and urban areas experienced food shortages. The new socialist administration prohibited private trade in food and conducted compulsory grain seizures in the rural areas during the winter of 1945–46.

In 1950, North Korea invaded South Korea. Armies on both sides traversed nearly the entire length of the peninsula twice and destroyed most of the physical capital stock. Considerable population movement occurred as well, mostly from the north to the south. It is impossible to ascertain with any degree of certainty the economic capacities of the two countries at the end of the hostilities in 1952. Under Soviet tute- lage, North Korea set about establishing a thoroughly orthodox centrally , remarkable only in the degree to which markets were suppressed. House- holds obtained food and other items through a rationing system calibrated on the age and occupation of the individuals in the household. In 1955, founding leader Il-sung proclaimed (self-reliance) to be the national . Under his leadership, North Korea developed into the world’s most autarkic economy: it never joined the Council of Mutual Economic Assistance () and even went so

3 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea far as to time its central plans out of phase with those of allied socialist states to frustrate linkages to other economies.

Following the , North Korea’s agriculture was collectivized, quantitative planning in production was introduced, state marketing and distribution of grain were established, and private production and trade were prohibited. Two types of farms were established legally: cooperatives and state farms, with the latter consid- ered ideologically more advanced. The country experienced food shortages in 1954– 55 as these changes were undertaken. Beginning in 1959, motivated by military se- Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 curity concerns, food security was pursued through self-sufªciency, not only at the national level, but also at the provincial and even the levels ( 2000; S. Lee 2003).

Collectivization was accompanied by an increase in irrigation and the use of indus- trial inputs such as chemical fertilizers, pesticides, tractors, and electrically operated irrigation systems. During the 1960s, the country pursued the “four moderniza- tions” of “mechanization, electriªcation, irrigation, and chemicalization,” eventually establishing what might have been at the time the world’s most input-intensive ag- ricultural system, exceeding even that of Japan. The authorities altered previous planting patterns: speciªcally, traditional food crops such as tubers, , and pota- toes were replaced with . Yields were increased but were highly susceptible to declines in inputs (e.g., shortages of , pesticides, or electricity).

In response to food shortages in 1970–73, the degree of centralization of North Ko- rea’s agricultural planning was intensiªed, and local authorities were increasingly marginalized. Food production was subject to the same input-output standardiza- tion as any other economic activity, and instructions were speciªed down to the level of fertilizer usage by individual cooperative farm households. In 1973, a Cul- tural Revolution–type movement was instigated, and young communists were dis- patched to initiate ideological, cultural, and technical education of farm households. New rural educational institutions were established, and existing rural ofªcials and staff were reassigned and required to enroll in these juche curriculum programs. This social engineering eroded knowledge of, respect for, and the inºuence of tradi- tional farming techniques. Rural life was thoroughly regimented by the state, and any sort of individual initiative was stiºed (S. Lee 2003).

The social engineering reached its apogee (or nadir, depending on one’s perspec- tive) with the “nature re-making program” launched in 1976, which literally bull- dozed “in a sweeping manner” the North Korean countryside into ªelds of “regular shapes like a checkerboard,” with the intent of severing the connection between for-

4 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

mer landowners and the land by changing its physical contours “beyond recogni- tion” (Kim 2000, 2). This effort was reportedly intensiªed in 1998, and it remains a component of North Korean agricultural policy (Foster-Carter 2001; Kim 2003).

3. Origins of North Korea’s present food crisis

The present crisis has its origins in a multifaceted set of factors and events from the late 1980s, but the precise causal relationships among these drivers are unclear. De- spite its juche-inspired declarations of self-reliance, North Korea has depended on Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 outside assistance throughout its entire history, with ªrst the , and later , playing the role of chief benefactor or patron. The North Koreans have com- pensated for their “subordinate” position by ferociously denouncing it,3 portraying the aid received as “tribute” paid to the ideologically pure North Korean state (Eberstadt 1999),4 or trying to play patrons off against each other to maximize the assistance they would receive. Eventually, frustrated by the North Korean govern- ment’s unwillingness to repay accumulated debts, the Soviets withdrew support, and according to U.S. Central Intelligence Agency ªgures, in 1987 the net ºow of re- sources to North Korea turned negative.

The same year, 1987, the government initiated several somewhat contradictory poli- cies in the agricultural sector, including the expansion of state farms, tolerance of private garden plots, expansion of grain-sown areas, transformation of crop compo- sition in favor of high-yield items, maximization of the use of industrial inputs (sub- ject to availability), and the intensiªcation of double cropping and dense planting. Continuous cropping led to soil depletion, and the overuse of chemical fertilizers contributed to the acidiªcation of the soil and eventually to a reduction in crop yields. As yields declined, hillsides were cleared to bring more and more marginal land into production, which contributed to soil erosion, river silting, and ultimately,

3 For example, directly after South Korea began shipping US$100 million of assistance to the DPRK in 2000, and while various UN organizations urged international donors to commit to new aid to avert catastrophe, , the ofªcial newspaper of the North Korean government, ran a commentary which read, in part, “The imperialists’ aid is a tool of aggres- sion . . . a dangerous toxin which brings about poverty, famine, and death, not prosperity” (“North Korea Warns against Outside Aid,” 5 October 2000, CNN, available at http:// archives.cnn.com/2000/ASIANOW/east/10/04/nkorea.foreignaid.ap/). (Such aid might well have been a dangerous toxin in one case, the beef potentially tainted with bovine spongiform encephalopathy donated by Switzerland and Germany in 2001.) 4 In a somewhat different context, Gordon Flake (2003, 39) describes a similar set of attitudes toward other patrons: “DPRK ofªcials were successfully able to come across not as the beg- gar, but instead as the recipient of entreaties from the outside world. In contrast, the would- be donors, the NGOs, became the supplicants, asking the DPRK for the ‘privilege’ of helping the North Korean people.”

5 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea catastrophic ºooding in 1995 and 1996. Isolation from the outside world reduced the genetic diversity of the North Korean seed stock, making plants more vulnerable to disease.

These negative effects on agriculture were compounded by the tremendous trade shocks, starting in 1990, that hit the North Korean economy as the Soviet Union dis- integrated and the collapsed. The Soviets had supplied North Korea with most of its and reªned oil and with one-third of its steel. Trade with the Soviet Union accounted for more than half of North Korea’s two-way trade. The fall Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 in imports from in 1991 was equivalent to 40 percent of all North Korea’s - ports, and by 1993, imports from Russia were only 10 percent of the average value they had been during 1987–90 (Eberstadt, Rubin, and Tretyakova 1995). North Korea proved incapable of reorienting its commercial relations in the face of this massive trade shock. Its industrial economy imploded, and as the industrial inputs needed by the agricultural sector became scarce or nonexistent, agricultural output plummeted.

4. Domestic availability of food in North Korea

Like most other social, political, or economic data for North Korea, the precise tim- ing and magnitude of the changes in agricultural production over the last two de- cades are somewhat controversial.5 Figure 1 shows four series of estimations of North Korean grain production for 1982–2001: the sources for the estimations are the Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the (UN), the South Korean Ministry of Uniªcation, the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), and North Korean ofªcials. Each of the four estimations shows a decline in grain pro- duction in the 1990s compared with that of the previous decade. The data from the FAO, however, exhibit an odd spike in the early 1990s not seen in the other data se- ries.6 The consensus is that during 2000 and 2001 North Korean grain production was less than 4 million metric tons.

North Korea’s imports of food and aid during 1990–2002 are shown in ªgure 2. Total food aid to North Korea as a percentage of its total imports of food increased from around 33 percent in 1995 to approximately 88 percent in 2002. In the period imme- diately following the collapse of the Soviet Union, China increased its exports of

5 Former U.S. Vice President Walter Mondale once observed that anyone who claimed to be an expert on North Korea was either a liar or a fool. My corollary is that no one should trust any datum on North Korea that comes with a decimal point attached. 6 Smith (1998) discusses the difªculties of estimating supply and demand for North Korean grains and harshly criticizes the FAO’s estimation methods.

6 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Figure 1. Estimates of North Korean grain production, 1982–2001 Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021

Sources: Food and Agriculture Organization statistics database (FAOSTAT) (data available at http://apps.fao.org/default.jsp); Department of Agriculture Foreign Agricultural Service (data available at http://www.fas.usda.gov/pecad2/highlights/2002/06/ nKorea/index.htm); South Korean Ministry of Uniªcation (data available at http://www.unikorea.go.kr/data/eng0302/000047/attach/ eng0302_47A.pdf).

food to North Korea (ªgure 3), offsetting some of the fall in trade with the Soviet Union and emerging as North Korea’s primary supplier of imported food, most of it reportedly on concessional terms.7 But in 1994 and 1995 a disillusioned China dra- matically cut back on this trade with North Korea. If there was a single proximate trigger to the , it was probably this sudden reduction of food imports. (In response, the North Koreans called the Chinese “traitors to the socialist cause,” which probably did not help matters.)

By 1994, North Korean radio broadcasts had admitted the existence of hunger. In May 1995, South Korean President Kim Young-sam made a public offer of uncondi- tional food assistance. Later that month the North Korean government conceded that the country was experiencing a food shortage and asked the Japanese govern- ment for help. Such a request was politically palatable because assistance from

7 For unknown reasons, the data on Chinese grain shipments to North Korea reported by the South Korean Ministry of Uniªcation and the United Nations International Food Aid Infor- mation System (INTERFAIS) diverge signiªcantly after 1998.

7 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Figure 2. North Korean food imports and aid, 1990–2002 Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021

Sources: National Uniªcation Board, Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) Special Reports, various issues (available at http://www.fao.org/WAICENT/faoinfo/economic/giews/English/alert/index.htm). Note: The data on which ªgure 2 are based should be taken with huge grains of salt. In all probability, the ªgures for “Imports on commer- cial terms” do not include food obtained through barter transactions on the Chinese border and food provided by Chinese provincial gov- ernments. Both sources became important in the late 1990s as the famine intensiªed and the North Korean control system began to fray. Nor do the aid ªgures include aid from China, which reportedly reached 500,000 metric tons in 1996. See Noland (2000) for more details. “Volume of aid” is food given to North Korea, which includes cereals and equivalents, including potatoes in cereal equivalents, measured in millions of metric tons.

Japan could be justiªed within North Korea as reparations; aid from rival South Ko- rea, however, could not be rationalized so easily. In June 1995, the North Korean government in reached agreements with the Japanese and South Korean governments on the procurement of emergency food aid, and in July it announced to its public that it was receiving external assistance, although failing to mention the aid given by South Korea. In August 1995 North Korea formally requested emer- gency assistance from the United Nations and immediately began receiving aid from a variety of UN organizations, indicated in ªgure 2 by the large increase in the volume of food aid given to North Korea between 1996 and 1997. The food aid pro- vided to North Korea bilaterally by China outside the UN system from 1991 through 2002 is shown in ªgure 3.8

8 See J. Lee (2003) for an overview of the public and private sector humanitarian assistance provided to North Korea.

8 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Figure 3. North Korea’s food imports from China, 1991–2002 Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021

Sources: Lim (1997); Korean Uniªcation Bulletin, April 2002; the International Food Aid Information System database of the United Nations (INTERFAIS).

Catastrophic ºoods in July and August 1995 exacerbated the plight of the North Ko- rean population. The government announced that 5.4 million people had been dis- placed, 330,000 hectares of agricultural land had been destroyed, and 1.9 million tons of grain had been lost. The government estimated that the total cost of the ºood damage was US$15 billion. The ºooding was considerable, but most outside observ- ers believed that the government’s claims were exaggerated (e.g., Smith 1998). For example, a UN survey concluded that the ºooding displaced 500,000 rather than 5.4 million people. Regardless of the precise ªgures, the ºooding played an important public relations role in North Korea’s ability to request and receive aid: the govern- ment was able to portray the famine as a product of a natural disaster rather than the result of misguided policies. The government unit charged with obtaining inter- national assistance was renamed the Flood Damage Rehabilitation Committee (FDRC), a guise that a number of foreign relief agencies also found advantageous.9 In short, the ºoods not only enabled the North Korean government to save face

9 A notable exception in this regard was the regional director of the WFP, John Powell, who correctly observed, “the major problem facing the DPRK in food supply and food pro- duction is structural. It is not natural disasters” (, 2 December 2001, Seoul).

9 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea while requesting aid but also helped the donors to deºect concerns about support- ing a repressive regime that was itself the primary cause of the problem.

More ºooding, though less severe, followed in July 1996, and the North Korean gov- ernment renewed its appeals for help. As the international aid campaign took off, rising aid inºows crowded out food imports on commercial terms (ªgure 2) and in effect functioned as balance of payments support.10 As shown in table 1, the primary suppliers of food assistance were the United States, South Korea, Japan, and the Eu- ropean Union.11 The provision of aid was highly politicized and reºected the inter- Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 ests of the main donors. North Korea emerged as the largest Asian beneªciary of U.S. aid, receiving more than US$1 billion in food and energy assistance between 1995 and 2002. The provision of this assistance was often used to induce the North Korean government to participate in diplomatic negotiations.12

The possible diversion of aid to military uses has been an ever-present issue since relief efforts ªrst began in the mid-1990s. In February 2001, the UN special rappor- teur for food rights, Jean Zeigler, wrote that “it gradually became clear that most of the international food aid was being diverted by the army, the secret services, and the Government” (United Nations Economic and Social Council 2001, 11). The in- cumbent director of the WFP, , angrily responded that Zeigler’s statement was “unsubstantiated, not referenced, and not based on ªrst- hand observations” and demanded that it be struck from the report (Agence - Presse, 7 June 2001). In a sense, this argument about military diversion of aid is a red herring: food aid is fungible (though imperfectly so), and as the WFP’s John Powell testiªed before the U.S. Congress, “the army takes what it wants from the national harvest upfront, in full. And it takes it in the form that Koreans prefer: Korean ” (Powell 2002). Another WFP ofªcial with ªrst-hand experience, on the condition of anonymity, claimed that the DPRK military takes receipt of bilateral aid from China and thus preserves the WFP’s claim that its food does not go directly to the military.

10 A careful analysis of trade “mirror statistics” indicates that although commercial imports of bulk grains dropped considerably during the 1990s, North Korea continued to import small quantities of “bread or biscuits,” “cakes or pastries,” and even “diet infant cereal prepara- tion,” which were presumably consumed by the political elite and their offspring (Eberstadt 1998). 11 The UN ªgures include small amounts of nonfood assistance. 12 Table 5.2 of Noland (2000) provides nine examples of “food for talks.” A recent example is the February 2003 U.S. government announcement, in the run-up to diplomatic talks over the North Korean nuclear weapons program, that it would provide 40,000 metric tons of grain to North Korea, despite North Korea’s noncompliance with the June 2002 aid trans- parency and monitoring conditions that had been reafªrmed the previous month (January 2003) by USAID Administrator Andrew S. Natsios.

10 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Table 1. Food aid to North Korea, by donor (US$ million) 2003 (through Source of food aid 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 27 April) Australia Through UN 0.5 0.4 4.8 1.3 2.3 6.7 2.9 3.4 1.8 Total 5.5 2.0 4.8 2.5 2.3 6.7 2.9 3.4 1.8 Canada Through UN n.a. n.a. 3.3 3.5 3.4 1.7 1.7 2.5 1.8 Total n.a. n.a. 3.3 3.5 3.4 1.7 1.7 2.7 2.1 South Korea Through UN 0.2 3.4 25.5 10.9 n.a. 0.5 15.8 16.2 19.2

Total n.a. 3.4 25.5 27.8 38.5 0.5 68.5 82.0 19.2 Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 South Korean government 232.3 4.6 47.2 31.9 46.9 113.8 135.4 n.a. n.a. ªgurea United States Through UN 0.2 7.2 45.5 171.9 160.7 29.2 102.7 63.5 31.1 Total n.a. 9.1 57.4 173.1 160.7 29.2 102.7 63.5 31.1 U.S. government ªgureb 0.2 8.3 52.4 72.9 222.1 74.3 102.8 82.4 n.a. European Unionc Through UN 4.0 2.6 49.7 16.3 15.2 4.8 12.4 12.4 21.4 Total n.a. 11.9 68.0 53.3 17.5 14.3 17.9 29.4 22.0 Japan Through UN 0.1 6.0 27.0 n.a. n.a. 95.7 104.9 n.a. n.a. Total n.a. 6.0 27.0 n.a. n.a. 95.7 104.9 n.a. n.a. Private/NGO Through UN n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 2.4 1.0 16.3 1.1 Total n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 2.4 68.8 76.8 2.9 Total food aid Through UN n.a. 34.4 158.4 215.9 189.9 153.1 248.0 120.7 78.7 Total 272.4 50.3 292.5 335.1 235.9 153.7 375.2 261.4 82.1

Sources: UN-OCHA Financial Tracking System (data available at http://ocha.unog.ch/fts/index.asp); Korean Uniªcation Bulletin, January 2002; Manyin and Jun (2003). Note: n.a. not available. a. The South Korean Ministry of Uniªcation ªgures include both public and private food and nonfood assistance. They do not include payments made prior to the 2000 North-South summit or other ofªcial meetings, however, and consequently the ªgures in table 1 un- derstate the true magnitude of South Korean assistance. b. The UN system’s annual estimations of the food aid to North Korea from the United States differ from those of Manyin and Jun (2003), who derived their estimates from USAID and U.S. Department of Agriculture data, for several reasons. The United States uses a ªscal year, whereas since 1998 the UN system has used a calendar year; the United States dates the contribution according to when it is disbursed, whereas the WFP dates it when it is pledged; and there might also be differences attributable to currency conversions, cargo insurance freight/free-on-board charges, and aid pledged but ultimately not disbursed. It is also unclear how the UN handled the alteration in accounting practice in 1998, that is, the change from an April to March ªscal year to a calendar year. c. Figures for the EU include the donations from the European Commission and member countries.

If international assistance has contributed to the ongoing North Korean military buildup, it has been through the channel of implicit balance of payments support, rather than through diversion of aid per se.13

13 That said, it has been frequently alleged that the North Korean authorities have diverted aid intended for humanitarian uses for other purposes. In one such example, a Thai senate com- mittee concluded that rice sold to North Korea on concessional terms had been diverted to West Africa (Joongang Ilbo, 22 May 2002).

11 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Table 2. North Korean cereal balance sheet for 2002–2003 (thousands of metric tons) Total utilization 4,921 Food use 3,893 Feed use 178 Seed requirements 160 Other uses and postharvest losses 691 Domestic availability (total) 3,837 Stock drawdown 0 Domestic production 3,837 Main season production 3,451 Winter/spring production 386 Import requirement 1,084

Commercial import capacity 100 Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 Concessional imports 300 Uncovered deficit 684 Of which emergency food aid is pledged or anticipated 126

Source: Food and Agricultural Organization database (available at http://www.fao.org/documents/show_cdr.asp?url_file=/docrep/005/ y7843e/y7843e00.htm). Note: Cereals included are paddy rice, wheat, barley, and potatoes (in cereal equivalents).

Although ºooding undoubtedly contributed to the food crisis in North Korea, agri- culture, like the rest of North Korea’s economy, has been in secular decline since the beginning of the decade. Based on econometric analyses of North Korean agricul- tural production, Smith and Huang (Forthcoming, 2) conclude that “the dominant triggering factor in the crisis was the sharp loss of supplies of agricultural inputs fol- lowing the disruption of the trade with the socialist bloc from the late 1980s. . . . The contribution of climatic factors to the agricultural crisis, as stressed by North Ko- rea’s policy-makers, was at most a secondary cause.” This conclusion is supported by simulations conducted by Noland, Robinson, and Wang (2001) using a comput- able general equilibrium model. The simulations indicate that a hypothetical resto- ration of ºood-affected land and capital would have had only a minor impact on the availability of food in North Korea. Under the assumption that the WFP’s estimates of human needs are correct,14 and ignoring the impact of the ºoods, the model sug- gests that North Korea would have entered the mid-1990s with a substantial, readily apparent food deªcit. As shown in table 2, the most recent FAO/WFP food balance assessment suggests that the provision of aid has mitigated suffering, but the funda- mental situation has changed little in the intervening years. North Korea still has a substantial need to import food and, in the absence of greater imports on commer- cial terms, a continuing “uncovered deªcit.”

5. Distribution of misery

As a consequence of the extraordinary isolation of North Korea and the secretive- ness of its political regime, there is considerable uncertainty about the timing of the

14 See Smith (1998) for a devastating critique of the WFP’s methodology for estimating de- mand.

12 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Figure 4. Map of the ’s North Korea operations as of January 2003 Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021

Source: World Food Programme, Map Resources. Adapted by Congressional Research Service (M. Chin, January 2003).

famine and its social and geographical incidence. Even today, with somewhat im- proved transparency and monitoring conditions, outside observers do not have ac- cess to some , where roughly 15 percent of the North Korean population re- sides (see ªgure 4). Moreover, prenotiªcation is required for site visits, and ofªcial relief agencies are not permitted to use Korean-speaking personnel or to monitor aid shipments continuously from port of entry to ªnal distribution (Manyin and Jun 2003; Snyder 2003b). Since 1997, ofªcial agencies such as USAID and WFP have threatened to make continued assistance conditional on improved monitoring, but rarely has a relief organization actually followed through in response to North Ko- rean noncooperation. When aid has been cut off, as in the case of the cessation of Japanese assistance in 2002, it has been for diplomatic rather than programmatic reasons. In short, despite more than a decade of an ongoing food crisis, we still have remarkably little systematic information about conditions inside North Korea, and much of the data we do have is of uncertain quality.

13 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

5.1 What do we know and how do we know it? Our understanding of North Korea is severely constrained by state secrecy and lack of access. Even in the few cases in which professionals have been allowed signiªcant access to conduct surveys, the results have been of questionable validity. For exam- ple, a nutritional survey conducted jointly by the , the United Na- tions Children’s Fund (UNICEF), and the WFP indicates that 16 percent of the sur- veyed children were severely malnourished based on their weight-for-height (i.e., they were characterized as “wasted”), 62 percent were acutely malnourished based on their height-for-age (i.e., they were “stunted”), and 61 percent were underweight Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 based on weight-for-age (WFP 1998). These results imply that the incidence of wast- ing among children in North Korea was more than double the ªgure for children in Angola (6 percent), a country in the midst of a 30-year civil war, and more than 50 percent worse than the incidence of wasting among children in Sierra Leone (9 per- cent), a country that had collapsed into anarchy.

Another survey, conducted by the North Korean Central Bureau of Statistics in 2002 and also in collaboration with UNICEF and the WFP, suggests that there have been extraordinary improvements in nutritional status since the WFP (1998) survey. The percentage of children who were underweight fell from 61 to 21 percent; the per- centage of children who were stunted fell from 62 to 42 percent; and the incidence of wasting dropped from 16 to 9 percent. Moreover, according to this 2002 North Ko- rean survey, the proportion of babies with low birth weight was 6.7 percent, which is lower than the ªgure for the United States (7.6 percent).

There are at least two possible explanations for the stunning improvements in nutri- tional status suggested by the second survey. The North Koreans, UNICEF, and the WFP ascribe these gains to food aid (Central Bureau of Statistics 2002; WFP 2003a). Another (admittedly speculative) explanation, however, is that the ªrst survey (WFP 1998) obtained extremely high percentages of stunted and underweight children, both in an absolute sense and relative to the much lower percentage of children who were wasted, because the ages of the children surveyed were recorded using the tra- ditional Korean method, in which the date of birth is the date of conception. The UNICEF/WFP enumerators who conducted the ªrst survey could not speak Korean and therefore may have misinterpreted the responses to questions about the chil- dren’s ages. This would had led to a systematic overestimation of the ages of the children and hence of the number of children who appeared to be underweight or very small (stunted) for their age. The second survey was conducted by the North Koreans, who presumably measured the children’s ages in the standard way, so that the improvements seen in age-related nutritional status were disproportionately large and not entirely attributable to an improved food supply.

14 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Even if one were to accept this explanation for the striking improvements in the age- related measures of nutritional status, another result of the second survey remains puzzling. It is clearly questionable that the percentage of North Korean babies with low birth weights appears to be lower than that of the United States, but at the same time the incidence of wasting reported by the survey puts North Korea in a league with Sierra Leone. In response to a query, the WFP provided results for every year between 1997 and 2002, although there is no record of any surveys’ having been conducted in 1999 or 2001. Subsequent correspondence has not clariªed these incon- sistencies. Finally, because the North Korean authorities excluded Chaggang and Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 Kangwon provinces from the study (two provinces that still remain largely beyond WFP access), the results may not correctly represent the true extent of the malnutri- tion suffered by North Koreans.

5.2 PDS ration cuts, grain conªscation, and economic fragmentation When Soviet aid was terminated in 1987, daily grain rations distributed through the PDS were cut by 10 percent. Before the cut, these rations ofªcially had been 600 to 700 grams for most urban dwellers and 700 to 800 grams for high ofªcials, military personnel, and heavy laborers (table 3). In 1991, as North Korea’s economic difªculties worsened, the government launched a “let’s eat two meals a day” cam- paign, and in the following year rations were cut by 10 percent again.15 By 1993, there were rumors that that PDS rations were delayed or temporarily suspended in some northern areas, and there were persistent (though unconªrmed) reports of food riots. In 1994 the North Korean government implemented what some observ- ers would describe as “triage”: it ended PDS shipments to four provinces (North and South Hamgyong, Yanggang, and Kangwon) and prohibited internal shipments to these regions. PDS daily rations were cut to 400–450 grams, and refugees reported that rations had fallen to 150 grams (admittedly, a disproportionate number of these refugees were from the most heavily affected northern provinces). By 1997 the daily ration had fallen to 128 grams before rising in subsequent years.

In 1995 the government also launched a campaign of coercive seizures of rural grain and reduced the annual retained farm allotment from 167 to 107 kilograms per per- son. Given the government’s history of conªscating grain, rural households re- sponded by hoarding, increasing their reliance on illegal private plots, and relatively neglecting production on the ofªcially recognized farms and cooperatives. The ef-

15 Persistent rumors concerning recent data on defecting North Korean soldiers suggest that the average size of the North Korean soldier has decreased, which implies that the onset of the food crisis was in the 1980s. The Korean People’s Army reportedly has lowered its mini- mum height requirement for male conscripts from 150 cm to 125 cm.

15 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Table 3. Per capita daily rations of rice and corn in North Korea Ratio of rice to corn Occupation and age group Per capita daily ration (grams) Pyongyang Other areas High-ranking government ofªcials 700 10:0 10:0 Regular laborers 600 6:4 3:7 Heavy-labor workers 800 6:4 3:7 Ofªce workers 600 7:3 3:7 Special security 800 6:4 3:7 Military 700 6:4 3:7 College students 600 6:4 3:7 Secondary school students 500 6:4 3:7 Primary school students 400 6:4 3:7 Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 students 300 6:4 3:7 Children under 3 years 100–200 6:4 3:7 Aged and disabled 300 6:4 3:7

Source: Kim, Lee, and Sumner (1998). fect was to constrict the supply of food available to the PDS even further. (See Noland 2000, Natsios 2001, Kim 2003, and J. Lee 2003 for details.)

As the North Korean economic crisis deepened, fuel shortages and deterioration of the transportation infrastructure contributed to the fragmentation of North Korea’s internal markets, the social compact ruptured further as the state was largely unable to supply food through the PDS, and food was increasingly obtained through infor- mal markets instead. Although the state tolerated certain survival strategies (such as barter trade managed by local ofªcials), it simultaneously intensiªed coercion to stop ordinary citizens from taking coping action; for instance, it established special camps and prisons for those found illegally foraging for food. By the mid-1990s, these forces, together with the pre-existing social differentiation, meant that, accord- ing to eyewitness accounts, conditions varied enormously across geographic regions and social groups, with perceived political loyalty to the state affecting access to hu- manitarian relief (Noland 2000; Natsios 2001; Hawk 2003).

5.3 Estimations of the death toll Given the secrecy of the North Korean regime, it is not surprising that contempora- neous estimates of the excess death toll vary enormously, ranging from 220,000 to 3.5 million (Noland 2000). Among the more well known is a statement made by a North Korean ofªcial in May 1999, which could be interpreted as indicating that 220,000 people, or roughly 1 percent of the pre-crisis population, had died as a result of the famine. (This ªgure was conªrmed by another ofªcial in 2001.) Robinson et al. (1999), on the basis of 771 refugee interviews conducted in 1998 and 1999, recon- structed mortality rates for a single heavily affected province and concluded that be- tween 1995 and 1997 nearly 12 percent of that province’s population had died. The

16 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Korean Buddhist Sharing Movement (1998), a South Korean nongovernmental orga- nization, extrapolating to the entire country from a similar analysis of refugee inter- views and observations on the ground, produced estimates of famine-related deaths on the order of 2.8 to 3.5 million.

In 2003, USAID Administrator Andrew S. Natsios testiªed that “2.5 million people, or 10 percent of the population” had died in the famine (Natsios 2003). This is al- most surely an exaggeration, for the following reasons. If the population of North Korea was approximately 22 million, and one assumes that there were no excess Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 deaths among the privileged populations of the armed forces (about 1 million) or in the population in the capital city, Pyongyang (around 3 million), this leaves a total nonprivileged or “exposed” population of around 18 million people. Robinson et al. (1999) indicate that the excess mortality rate in the province of North Hamgyong, acknowledged to be the hardest hit by the food crisis, was roughly 12 percent. Ap- plying this 12 percent ªgure to the “exposed” total pre-crisis population of 18 mil- lion yields an estimate of excess deaths of just over 2 million, which should be con- sidered an upper bound. Put another way, if one accepts the Robinson et al. (1999) estimate of 245,000 excess deaths in North , out of a pre-crisis population of approximately 2 million, then Natsios’s statement implies that there must have been roughly 2.25 million deaths among the remaining 16 million “ex- posed” people. This amounts to a rate of 14 percent for the country as a whole, which is 15 percent higher than the excess mortality rate Robinson et al. calculated for what was, by consensus, the worst-affected province.

Taking 1994 as the base year, demographers Daniel Goodkind and Lorraine West (2001) use ofªcial DPRK statistics on crude death rates, together with an age-speciªc death rate model, and estimate that 236,900 excess deaths occurred between 1995 and 2000. Using the same model and assuming the much higher mortality rates im- plied by the Robinson et al. (1999) interviews generated an estimate of 2,648,939 ex- cess deaths during 1995–2000, which is more than 10 times the estimate derived from the ofªcial DPRK statistics. Of all alternative estimates generated in their 2001 study, Goodkind and West prefer those based on data from the 1998 WFP nutritional survey and calibrated with crude death rates for the period of China’s Great Leap Forward. These estimated excess deaths for the period 1994–2000 are 1,042,021 based on the Chinese crude death rates and 605,458 adjusted for nutritional status, from the 1998 WFP survey.

Based on a close analysis of ofªcial statistics, S. Lee (2003) argues that a signiªcant increase in mortality rates occurred in 1994, which implies that the famine was well

17 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea under way before the ºooding of June 1995. Using a sex- and age-speciªc model of death rates, Lee estimates that between 1 January 1994 and 31 August 1999 North Korea experienced 668,000 excess deaths. Lee does not account for the population losses resulting from refugee ºows into China, and consequently his analysis may misattribute some of these “disappearances” as famine-related deaths. Interestingly, if Lee’s conclusion is correct, and the North Korean famine really started in 1994, then Goodkind and West’s (2001) model generated underestimates of the impact of the food crisis, because they used the already elevated crude death rate in 1994 as their baseline. Another way in which the famine’s impact might be underestimated Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 by Goodkind and West, and by Lee as well, is through the assumption that fertility rates did not change: their estimations do not take account of births foregone.

In summary, the timing and impact of the famine are not well understood. The most recent and sophisticated attempts (i.e., Goodkind and West, and Lee) to measure the excess deaths attributable to the famine suggest that roughly 600,000 to 1 million people died, or approximately 3 to 5 percent of the pre-crisis population.

5.4 Humanitarian relief or abetting a totalitarian regime? Terms of engagement According to one close observer with a long personal his- tory of dealing with DPRK authorities, “the interaction between the FDRC and in- ternational humanitarian aid organizations was adversarial from its inception” (Snyder 2003a, 6). And the unwillingness of some charitable groups (especially those motivated by religious ideals) to walk away encouraged some DPRK ofªcials to “hold their own populace hostage to their demands and conditions” (Flake 2003, 38). A detailed appraisal of the experience of European nongovernmental organiza- tions (NGOs) in North Korea by Michael Schloms (2003) also supports these essen- tial judgments.

In 1998, while the WFP was proclaiming conditionality, Médicins Sans Frontières (MSF) (Doctors without Borders), which at that time was the largest relief agency operating in North Korea, discontinued its operations in North Korea on the grounds that the government denied the agency access to sick and malnourished children and channeled relief supplies to the children of the politically well- connected. MSF has remained particularly vocal in its denunciations of North Ko- rean practices since 1998, arguing that there is “no humanitarian space whatsoever” for work in the DPRK. In 1999, World Concern, a U.S.-based NGO, halted shipments of relief supplies to North Korea after food destined for an orphanage and hospital disappeared. pulled its ªve-member team out in December 1999, citing inter- ference by North Korean authorities. They were followed in March 2000 by the French NGO Action Contre la Faim (ACF) (Action against Hunger). ACF President

18 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Roger Godino claimed similar interference by the North Korean authorities: “the massive UN aid effort, principally run by the World Food Programme and the United Nations Children’s Fund (UNICEF) with signiªcant U.S. funds, is essentially a political and diplomatic operation. The United Nations is providing food aid, but not humanitarian aid” (Agence France-Presse, Paris, 7 March 2000). Less than 1 month later, the American NGO Cooperative for American Relief to Everywhere (CARE) pulled out, and its president, Peter D. Bell, stated that “despite a nearly four-year di- alogue with the North Korean government regarding the importance of access, transparency and accountability, however, the operational environment in North Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 Korea has not progressed to a point where CARE feels it is possible to implement ef- fective rehabilitation programs” (CARE 2000, 1).

Other NGOs that have remained engaged with North Korea, such as Caritas Inter- national and German Agro Action, believe that improvements in access and moni- toring justify continued involvement. A statement by a staff member of Children’s Aid Direct (CAD) is representative of this view: CAD regards “the minimum condi- tions for humanitarian involvement in the DPRK as an evolving situation. We accept that to date these conditions have not fully been met, but we see a slow but continu- ing move toward meeting these conditions. Our levels of access, a fundamental is- sue, have increased during the time that we have worked in the DPRK, as has the level of cooperation that we have received from the FDRC” (quoted in Smith 2002, 11). (CAD withdrew from North Korea as a result of ªnancial difªculties in 2002.) Snyder (2003a, 12) concludes that “although changes and gradual accommodations have been achieved by NGOs on the ground as they develop closer relationships and understanding with their counterparts, considerable internal bureaucratic resis- tance and suspicion of outside efforts remain, which greatly hamper the effective- ness of humanitarian work inside Korea.”

Access to food and control of aid As North Korea’s PDS failed and the famine intensiªed, food was increasingly allocated through informal markets,16 and the sit- uation more closely resembled past in market economies, as described by Sen (1981), Ravallion (1987), and others. For North Koreans, access to food mainly depends on their geographic location (area of food surplus or deªcit), occupation (urban or rural work), and access to foreign exchange (money obtained either through ofªcial employment or nonofªcial economic activities, or remittances, prin- cipally through relatives in Japan and, increasingly, China). In short, access to food

16 The North Korean authorities subsequently regularized these informal (farmers’) markets: they constructed physical facilities, established regulations, and provided policing and other services.

19 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea in North Korea varies positively with one’s physical proximity to its cultivation and one’s access to foreign exchange.

Under these circumstances, control of aid potentially conveys astronomical rents, a situation abetted by the inability of ofªcial relief agencies to monitor the distribution of supplies. Suspicions that aid ºows have been diverted for private use have been reinforced by consistent testimonies from refugees that they had not received aid be- fore ºeeing the country and by eyewitness reports of grain in bags with interna- tional relief agency markings being sold in the farmers’ markets.17 Given the North Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 Korean state’s long history of illicit commercial activity (e.g., drug trafªcking, smug- gling, and counterfeiting) and the decade-long fraying of its communist system, it is plausible that private individuals and groups have managed to capture these rents to a substantial degree. The implicit marketization of the economy in the absence of any real institutions has led to an increasingly gangsterish form of apparatchik capi- talism and growing social differentiation. Indeed, some analysts argue that interna- tional aid agencies should circumvent the government distribution channels en- tirely, inasmuch as providing aid through the government simply strengthens the power of the totalitarian North Korean state relative to nascent non-state actors. As Scott Snyder observes, “the amount of food distributed through the PDS is no longer an accurate indicator of imminent distress within the North Korean system, yet it has remained the WFP’s primary indicator of distress and the primary vehicle through which the WFP distributes food inside the country. In this respect, the WFP is an ally of the government in its efforts to reestablish control over the ” (Snyder 2003b, 119). Or in the words of MSF researcher Fiona Terry, “by channeling [aid] through the regime responsible for the suffering, it has become part of the system of oppression” (“Feeding the ,” , 6 August 2001).

Disenchantment with North Korean behavior, together with emerging food crises elsewhere, caused the WFP in 2002 and 2003 to miss its assistance targets and reduce (in principle) the number of North Koreans it is assisting, from 6.4 million (almost a third of the population) to 3.5 million.18 As the crisis continued in North Korea, a va- riety of foreign governmental and private organizations, concerned about political sustainability and donor fatigue, attempted to reorient their programs from the

17 These reports are not conclusive, because the bags may have been recycled. One should note, however, that the North Korean authorities go to great lengths to deny foreigners access to these markets. See Manyin and Jun (2003) for a more extensive discussion of aid diversion. 18 Natsios, for example, explained that “there are other needs in other areas of the world. If I have a choice to make, it’s going to provide the food aid where we can assure that it’s going

20 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

provision of food aid toward agricultural development assistance, with mixed success.19

6. Policy changes in North Korea

In July 2002, the government of North Korea announced changes in economic policy that could be regarded as having four components: changes in microeconomic pol- icy, changes in macroeconomic policy, establishment of special economic zones, and aid seeking.20 These initiatives followed moves begun in 1998 to encourage adminis- Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 trative decentralization (Oh 2003). A September 2003 cabinet reshufºe holds forth the promise of younger, and perhaps more technocratic, leadership.

6.1 Microeconomic policy With respect to food, the North Korean government decided to increase both the procurement prices of grain (to increase the volume of food entering the PDS) and the PDS prices to consumers. In part, the increase in the procurement prices of grain was supposed to counter the supply response of the farmers, who, in the face of low prices, had been diverting acreage away from grain to tobacco and using grain to produce liquor for sale. The prices of grain rose by 40,000–60,000 percent in the space of 6 months during 2002 (table 4). Comparisons with U.S. wholesale and retail prices (taken as a proxy for world prices) suggest that the relative price structure in North Korea continued to be distorted in 2002.

Maintaining the PDS as a mechanism for distributing food is presumably an attempt to honor the social contract, that is, to conªrm the government’s intention to con- tinue its centralized provision of food for all citizens, while narrowing the disequi- librium between the market and plan prices. Residents are still issued monthly ra- tion cards, but if they lack sufªcient funds to purchase the monthly allotment, then it is automatically carried over to the next month. Wealthy households are not al- lowed to purchase more than the monthly allotment through the PDS. The system is

to those at risk” (Doug Struck, “Aid Used as Lever with Pyongyang,” Washington Post, 5 December 2002). 19 International Fund for Agricultural Development (2000) provides an analysis of three such agricultural development projects. 20 The discussion in section 6 is based on many sources, including press reports, diplomatic re- ports, and private conversations with diplomats and NGO workers based in North Korea. Note, again, that considerable uncertainty surrounds all knowledge of events in North Ko- rea. Moreover, ªrst-hand accounts from different regions of the country yield very different stories. For more details on the 2002 policy changes, see Lee (2002), Chung (2003), Frank (2003a), Kim (2003), Nam (2003), Newcombe (2003), and Oh (2003).

21 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Table 4. North Korean grain prices and implicit exchange rates Implicit won/US$ Price (won/kg) Price (US$/kg) exchange rate Before January–June After June Product Janary 2002 2002 2002 Retail Wholesale Retail Wholesale Rice 0.08 0.98 (0.88) 44 (40) 1.01 0.86 43.6 46.5 Wheat 0.06 0.71 28 — — — — Barley 0.06 0.71 26 — — — — Corn 0.04 0.60 (0.49) 24 (20) 0.10 0.07 240.0 285.7

Sources: For DPRK prices, WFP (2003b); for U.S. rice prices, Bureau of Labor Statistics Web site (www.bls.gov/mxp/home.htm) and Wall Street Journal; for U.S. corn prices, USDA Agricultural Research Service Web site (www.ars.usda.gov/main/main.htm). Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 Note: Procurement prices are shown in parentheses. organized to prevent arbitrage in ration coupons between rich and poor house- holds.21

Some observers question the extent to which the government’s decision to increase procurement prices is a real policy change rather than an unacknowledged ratiªca- tion of a fraying system. There is considerable evidence that most food was already being distributed through markets rather than through the PDS. The motivation for allowing the increases in producer prices, however, might be to repair rather than ratify the system’s ºaws: the government realized that with little supply entering the PDS, people increasingly obtained their food from nonstate sources, and if the government could increase the food supply into state-controlled channels, then it would be able to reduce the extent to which food is allocated solely on the basis of purchasing power. The state’s action may also be attributable to broader antimarket ideological considerations, discussed further in section 6.2. Yet another purpose of the increased procurement prices might be to reduce the ªscal strain imposed by the implicit subsidy provided to urban consumers.22 Anecdotal accounts suggest that despite the increases in procurement prices, the government’s policy has not been successful in coaxing domestic supply (as distinct from international aid) back into the PDS system. Indeed, some anecdotal reports indicate that the PDS is not operat- ing in all areas of the country.

In the industrial sector, the government appeared to be attempting to adopt a dual- price strategy similar to that implemented by China in its industrial sector.23 The

21 Oh (2003) claims that the rationing coupons have been abolished, and in theory, wealthy households can now buy unlimited supplies through the PDS. 22 However, the WFP (2003b) reports that since the July 2002 price changes, prices for grain in the farmers’ markets have risen signiªcantly, but the PDS prices have remained largely un- changed. 23 Oh (2003, 72) disputes this notion, arguing that the aim of the policy changes was “to shift the country’s economic control mechanism from one based on material balances in a tradi-

22 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Chinese instructed their state-owned enterprises to continue to meet the output re- quired by the central plan, but once planned production obligations were fulªlled, the enterprises were free to hire labor and capital and produce products for sale on the open market. In other words, the plan was essentially frozen in time, and mar- ginal growth occurred according to market dictates.

North Korean enterprises have been instructed that they are responsible for cover- ing their own costs. Managers have been authorized to make limited purchases of intermediate inputs and to make autonomous investments out of retained earnings. Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 They are also permitted to engage in international trade. Yet it is unclear what de- gree of power managers have been given to hire, ªre, and promote workers or to what extent remuneration will be determined by the market. Anecdotal evidence suggests that managers, faced with this dilemma, are creating offshoot ªrms to which they can transfer workers, thereby reducing the payrolls for which the parent ªrm’s managers are responsible. Amid these changes, there has been no mention of the military’s privileged position within the economy, although domestic propa- ganda continues to emphasize a military-ªrst political path.

The state has raised wage levels, and certain favored groups, such as military per- sonnel, party ofªcials, scientists, and coal miners, have received enormous increases. One report claims that the wage increases for military personnel and miners have been on the order of 1,500 percent, and those for agricultural workers may have been about 900 percent, but increases for ofªce workers and less essential employees have been smaller. These alterations in real wages across occupational groups could be interpreted as an attempt to enhance the role of material incentives in labor allocation.

The state continues to maintain an administered price structure, though state prices are being brought in line with market prices. As proven in other transitional econo- mies, this is problematic: the government insists that the enterprises must cover their costs, yet it continues to administer prices. Moreover, no formal bankruptcy or other exit mechanism exists for failing enterprises to cease operations, nor is there a

tional socialist mandatory planning system to one managed through a monetary mecha- nism. . . . The situation is quite different from that in China at the beginning of its reform process, where reform-minded leaders boldly argued that economic reform measures were imperatives, not policy options.” Newcombe (2003, 59) also emphasizes the shift from quan- titative planning to a monetized economy and reports a statement by one ofªcial that could also suggest a more limited aim of the policy changes: “this objective (or reform) will only be achieved by removing the last ‘vestiges’ of the Soviet system from the DPRK economy” (emphasis added by Newcombe). Frank (2003a) also a similar denunciation of “Soviet- type” practices. These statements could be interpreted as manifestations of a North Korean attempt to justify ideologically a uniquely North Korean “third way” policy package.

23 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea social safety net to help displaced workers survive (hence the dodge of setting up offshoots and telling these new ªrms to sink or swim). What is likely to occur is that the failing enterprises will be supported by implicit subsidies, either from national or local government budgets or from a reconstructed banking system. The North Koreans have sent ofªcials to China to study the Chinese banking system, which may have its virtues but is also the primary mechanism through which the country’s money-losing state-owned ªrms are kept alive.

One result of the changes in microeconomic policy has been a noticeable upsurge in Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 small-scale retail activity, at least in Pyongyang. Whether such growth will extend to a broader industrial revival is an open question. The consensus among most outside observers, as of 2003, is that marketization has not delivered as hoped.

6.2 Macroeconomic policy changes To grasp the magnitude of North Korea’s price changes, consider the case of China: at the start of China’s reforms in November 1979, the price of grains was raised about 25 percent, but in North Korea the prices of corn and rice have been raised by more than 40,000 percent. In the absence of huge supply responses, the result will be an enormous jump in the price level and possibly even hyperinºation.24

When China began its reforms in 1979, about 71 percent of the population was in the agricultural sector, and the same held true for when its reforms took place in the following decade (table 5). In contrast, North Korea had less than half that share employed in agriculture (about 33 percent). This difference has two profound implications. First, the share of the population that could directly beneªt from the increase in producer prices for agricultural goods is roughly half as big in North Ko- rea as it was in China and Vietnam. The new pricing policy in North Korea, com- pared with the cases of China or Vietnam, is therefore less likely to be Pareto- improving and more likely to create a large number of citizens who ªnd themselves to be the losers under the reforms. Second, the relatively smaller size of North Ko- rea’s agricultural sector means that the absolute magnitude of the positive supply response will likely be smaller compared with that of China or Vietnam. Again, this increases the likelihood that such reforms will not solve the basic food shortage problem, which will mean continued hunger and possible social unrest.

The North Korean authorities’ treatment of the external sector has lacked coherence. After announcing the dramatic price increases, the government claimed that it would not devalue the currency, even though refusing to devalue would have de-

24 See Frank (2003a) and Oh (2003) for price increases in nonagricultural goods.

24 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Table 5. Distribution of the labor force by sector in various countries (%) Country Year Agriculture Industry Service Czech Republic 1989 11a 39 50 Slovakia 1989 15a 34 51 Poland 1989 7a 37 56 Hungary 1990 15a 36 49 Soviet Union 1987 19a 38b 43 Ukraine 1990 20 40 40 Belarus 1990 20 42 38 Romania 1990 28a 38 34 Bulgaria 1989 19a 47 34 North Korea 1993 33 37 30 China 1978 71 15 14 Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 Vietnam 1989 71 12 17

Source: Noland (2000, table 3.7). a. Agriculture and forestry. b. Industry and construction.

stroyed whatever international price competitiveness the North Korean economy had at the time. In August 2002, however, about 2 weeks after making this claim, the authorities announced a currency devaluation from 2.1 won/US$ to 150 won/US$, a rate that approached the contemporaneous black-market rate of around 200 won/ US$. A second devaluation, this time to 900 won/US$, again approaching the black- market rate, was announced in October 2003. Access to foreign currency could act as insurance against inºation, and in fact the black-market value of the has dropped steadily since the reforms were announced, with one report put- ting it at approximately 1,200 won to the in April 2003.25 Tariffs on consumer products such as textiles, soap, and shoes have doubled from 20 percent to 40 per- cent, increasing the degree of relative price distortion (Oh 2003).

Table 4 shows the implicit purchasing power exchange rates of the procurement (wholesale) prices and PDS (retail) prices for rice and corn in 2002. These rates range enormously, from 44 won/US$ (for rice at retail) to 286 won/US$ (for corn at whole- sale). The contemporaneous ofªcial exchange rate was 150 won/US$ (which, as noted previously, has since been adjusted). Table 4 also indicates that if U.S. prices are taken as a proxy for world prices, then the state prices in the DPRK still embody considerable relative price distortion. As exchange indicators, these estimates should be taken with large grains of salt, however. Quality differences in the rice and corn consumed in the United States and the DPRK may be so large as to swamp any true signal emerging from the price comparisons.

In any event, the inconsistent attitude toward the external sector is also manifested in the government’s continued insistence that foreign-invested enterprises pay

25 James Kynge and Andrew Ward, “Back to the Table: Why -il’s Failing Economy May Be the Key to Halting His Nuclear Program,” Financial Times, 23 April 2003.

25 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea wages in hard currencies (at wage rates that exceed those of China and Vietnam). For a labor-abundant economy, this curious policy appears to be the very deªnition of a contractionary devaluation. It blunts the competitiveness-boosting impact of the devaluation by aborting the adjustment of relative labor costs while raising the do- mestic resource costs of imported intermediate inputs. Hard-currency wages mean that North Korean enterprises will have high (noncompetitive) labor costs, and de- valuation increases the real costs of the intermediate imported inputs these enter- prises require. Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021

Inºation and the process of marketization will exacerbate existing social inequalities in North Korea. North Koreans with access to foreign exchange (such as senior party ofªcials) will be relatively insulated from the effects of inºation, and agricultural workers might beneªt from “automatic” pay increases as the price of grain rises, but salaried workers without access to foreign exchange will fall behind. The implica- tions for the losers could be quite severe. According to a WFP survey (2003c), most urban households in North Korea are food insecure, spending more than 80 percent of their incomes on food. In December 2003 the United Nations’ humanitarian relief coordinator in North Korea, Masood Hyder, informed the world press that the food problem was concentrated among nearly 1 million urban workers, a view echoed by Rick Corsino, head of the WFP’s local operation.26

Although there is a consensus among analysts that marketization is a necessary component of North Korea’s economic revitalization, the inºationary part of the package appears to be both unnecessary and destructive. If one wanted to increase the relative wages of coal miners by 40 percent, one could simply give them a 40 percent raise—one does not need to increase the overall price level by a factor of 10, and the nominal wages of coal miners by a factor of 14, to effect the same real wage increase.

There are at least three possible explanations for the North Korean government’s initiation of inºationary policies. The ªrst argument is the most benign: by creating inºation, the government hopes to provide a short-run jump start to the economy. Given the extremely low levels of capacity utilization in the North Korean economy, this argument is superªcially plausible, but the problems of the North Korean econ- omy go far deeper than underutilized resources. The economy is largely geared to produce goods for which there is only limited demand (e.g., televisions and radios without tuners, Scud missiles). Unless the composition of output is signiªcantly re-

26 Jonathon Watts, “How North Korea Is Embracing Capitalism,” The Guardian, 3 December 2003. See also Kim (2003) for an analysis of food insecurity issues.

26 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea oriented, it is unlikely that inºation alone will generate a sizeable supply response. Even North Korea’s agricultural sector is problematic in this regard: because agri- culture is highly dependent on industrial inputs, increases in output that theoreti- cally might result from higher procurement prices might not be possible if in prac- tice farmers are unable to procure these inputs.

A second possibility is that the inºation policy is a product of Kim Jong-il’s reputed antipathy toward private economic activity beyond state control. One effect of inºation is to reduce the value of existing won holdings. Historically, socialist gov- Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 ernments have used state-administered inºation and its cousin, currency reform, to wipe out currency overhangs (i.e., excess monetary stock claims on goods in circula- tion), often to target black marketers and others engaging in economic activity out- side state strictures or holding large stocks of the domestic currency. In a currency reform, residents are literally required to turn in their existing holdings—subject to a ceiling, of course—and exchange them for newly issued notes. In July 2002 the North Korean government announced that the won (“foreigner’s won”) for- eign-exchange certiªcates would be replaced by the normal brown won (“people’s won”), although it was left unclear whether the latter would be convertible into for- eign currency. The other shoe dropped in December 2002, when the authorities an- nounced that the circulation of U.S. dollars was prohibited and that all residents, foreign and domestic alike, would have to turn in their dollars and exchange them for , which the central bank did not have.

The problem is that such attempts to punish black marketers and others engaging in private economic transactions may do real damage to the economy while having a limited impact on the intended targets. Having gone through this experience several times in the past (including as recently as the mid-1990s [Michell 1998]), North Ko- rean traders are not gullible: they quickly get out of won in favor of dollars, yen, and . Indeed, even North Koreans working on cooperative farms reportedly prefer trinkets over the local currency as a store of value. Consequently, the blows aimed at traders may fall more squarely on the North Korean masses, especially those in regions and occupations in which opportunities to obtain foreign currency are limited.

In yet another attempt to extract resources from the population, in March 2003 the government announced the issuance of People’s Life Bonds, which, despite their name, seem to resemble lottery tickets rather than bonds as conventionally under- stood. These instruments have a 10-year maturity, and the principal is repaid in an- nual installments beginning in year 5. There does not appear to be any provision for interest payments, and no money for such payments has been budgeted. For the

27 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

ªrst 2 years of the People’s Life Bonds, there will be semiannual drawings (annually thereafter), and the winners will receive their principal plus prizes. No information has been provided on the expected odds or prize values other than the drawings will be based on an “open and objective” principle. The government’s announce- ment states, without irony, that “the bonds are backed by the full faith and credit of the DPRK government.” Committees have been established in every province, city, county, institute, factory, village, and town to promote the scheme and have stated that citizens who purchase these “bonds” will be performing a “patriotic deed.”27 Both the characteristics of the People’s Life Bonds and the mass campaign to sell Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 them suggest that politics, not personal ªnance, will be the main selling point.28 In- deed, when the North Korean government has resorted to lottery-like instruments in the past to deal with monetary overhang problems, they have been unpopular (Kim 1998).

As an economist it is only with reluctance that I propose arguments that presume ig- norance, but personal experience in China leads me to suggest a third explanation for North Korea’s recent inºationary economic policies. Conversations with Chinese ofªcials during the ªrst stage of the marketizing reforms in the early to mid-1980s revealed a widespread, fundamental misunderstanding of the nature of markets, es- pecially among older ofªcials who had spent many years in a planned economy. Many lacked the knowledge that, in a market economy, demand and supply are not quantities or points, but schedules indicating quantities as a function of prices, and market-determined prices are thus a signal of scarcity value that reºects underlying demand and supply. Similarly, the North Korean policies may be, in part, a result of ignorance of the relationship between monetary policy and the price level. The North Korean authorities have indicated that they are trying to unify (or at least re- duce the differences between) state prices and those of the farmers’ markets. In one press report, an unnamed ofªcial laid out the logic of the price reform: the adminis- tered price of rice would be raised to the farmers’ market price, but since no one could afford rice at the market price, everyone’s nominal wages would be increased commensurately. The ofªcial did not seem to understand that the amount of won in

27 Bong-uk Chong (2003) suggests that purchases of the bonds may be compulsory. According to another account, purchases are not mandatory, but the authorities will use purchases as “a barometer of the buyers’ loyalty and support for the party and the state” (Itar-Tass, 23 May 2003, Korea Trade-Investment Promotion Agency translation). 28 Frank (2003a) argues that the issuance of these instruments is a response to the large expan- sion in expenditures associated with the increased procurement price for grains, and in- deed, North Korean government expenditures appear to have increased by double digits in 2003. However, the rise in outlays associated with the increase in the procurement price for grain ought to be offset by a similar increase in revenues from the expanded PDS sales.

28 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea circulation would be increased instantly by a factor of 10 as a result of the wage in- crease, and unless the rice supply increased immediately, the government would ef- fectively cause a 900 percent jump in the price level. And in fact, the North Koreans have been slow to adjust the state prices in the face of the inºation that predictably materialized in the market.

6.3 Special economic zones Rajin-Sonbong region The third component of the North Korean economic policy change is the formation of various sorts of special economic zones. The ªrst such Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 zone was established in 1991 in the Rajin-Sonbong region, which is in the extreme northeast of the country. It proved to be a failure for a variety of reasons, including geographic isolation, poor infrastructure, onerous rules, and interference in enter- prise management by party ofªcials. The one major investment has been the estab- lishment of a combination hotel/casino/bank. Given the obvious scope for illicit ac- tivity associated with such a horizontally integrated endeavor, the Rajin-Sonbong region ended up resembling North rather than Kong.

Kaesong industrial park A 1998 agreement between North Korea and Hyundai that established the tourist venture also provided for the establish- ment of an industrial park to be managed and operated by Hyundai. The tourism project was the centerpiece of this agreement, but the industrial park, which would permit South Korean small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) to invest in North Korea, with Hyundai’s implicit protection, was potentially more important to the revitalization of North Korea’s economy. In the long run, South Korean SMEs would be a natural source of investment and technology transfer to North Korea. In the absence of physical or legal infrastructure, however, such SMEs would be un- likely to invest. The four economic cooperation agreements subsequently made be- tween North Korea and Hyundai on issues such as taxation and foreign exchange transactions could be regarded as providing a legal infrastructure for future eco- nomic activity by South Korean SMEs.

The North Korean government and the South Korean ªrm then negotiated for 18 months over the location of the zone. The North Koreans wanted the industrial park in , a city of some symbolic political importance, located in the northwest on the Chinese border, and Hyundai wanted to build it in the district, a more easily accessible area for South Korea. Kaesong was the compromise site. As of mid-2003, the industrial park at Kaesong had not fulªlled its promise. The North Koreans inexplicably failed to open the necessary transportation links to South Korea on their side of the .

29 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Sinuiju special administrative region: Adventures in fantasyland In September 2002 the North Korean government announced the establishment of a special ad- ministrative region (SAR) at Sinuiju. Although the location of the new SAR was not surprising, the details of the project were extraordinary. The proposed zone would exist completely outside North Korea’s usual legal structures; it would have its own ºag and issue its own ; and the land within the zone could be leased for 50 years. Shortly after the North Korean government announced that the Sinuiju SAR would be run by Yang Bin, a Chinese-born entrepreneur with Dutch citizenship, he was arrested by the Chinese authorities.29 At the time of Yang Bin’s appointment as Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 administrator of the Sinuiju SAR, he was under investigation for tax evasion in China. He had reportedly ºed to North Korea (although he does not speak Korean) during two previous investigations. Among his various business interests, Yang op- erated a Dutch-style village in Shenyang, complete with a windmill and imitations of Amsterdam buildings, which Kim Jong-il had visited. At the time of Yang’s ap- pointment, trading in shares of his ªrm, -Asia Agriculture Holdings, had been suspended on the stock exchange after the shares collapsed on the sus- picion of fraud.

In yet another example of physical and social engineering on a grand scale, plans were announced, in Yang’s words, to “ºatten” Sinuiju, relocate its 500,000 current residents, and replace them with 200,000 hand-picked substitutes. Euro-Asia Agri- culture Holdings would build and operate 100,000 greenhouses. A governing coun- cil of 15 that included 8 foreigners would be established. The SAR would be sur- rounded by a giant wall, and foreigners could enter visa-free, but North Koreans would require permission. In a somewhat humorous mishap, the border guards were not informed of these entrance rules, and the day after they were announced, South Korean journalists were denied entry because, according to the North Kore- ans, they were not foreigners, and foreign journalists were denied entry as well, be- cause, well, they were foreigners. Despite the Sinuiju project’s awkward start, the North Koreans claim that it will proceed as planned and the ªrst population re- moval and physical reconstruction projects will commence in 2004. However, in October 2004 press stories began reporting that the project had been abandoned.

29 Subsequently the press ªrst touted Park Tae-joon, former South Korean general, head of the Pohang Iron and Steel Corporation (POSCO) and prime , and later Eric Hotung, a Hong Kong philanthropist, as Yang’s successor. It was subsequently claimed that Jong Song-thaek, the brother-in-law of Kim Jong-il, would manage the project. Later the former Republican mayor of Fullerton, California, Julie Sa, also known as Sa Rixing, a South Korean–born ethnic Chinese American woman, was reportedly picked to head the Sinuiju SAR.

30 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

How important might the Sinuiju SAR prove to be for the North Korean economy? It is a disadvantage that the most economically dynamic zones in China are the southern coastal areas, far from North Korea. Nevertheless, it is likely that economic integration with China, even if it is only with a comparative backwater such as , could be a boost for North Korea. A more important question is whether the Sinuiju SAR will generate any spillovers in the long term. In conventional terms, this will depend on whether any lessons from the Sinuiju SAR experiment are gen- eralized to the rest of the economy.30 More subtly, the SAR might have a positive im- pact if it is regarded internally as a strong sign that Kim Jong-il’s unimpeachable im- Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 primatur has been given to the reform process. Bureaucrats and factory managers who have been reluctant to get ahead of the leadership might conclude that change is safe. Conversely, by taking the SAR completely outside of the normal North Ko- rean governing structures, Kim Jong-il can circumvent the party and the bureau- cracy and manage the zone directly out of his ofªce.

Ultimately, the planned industrial park at Kaesong, which is oriented toward South Korea, is likely to have a bigger impact on North Korea’s economy than either the Rajin-Sonbong region or the Sinuiju SAR.

6.4 Aid seeking The fourth component of North Korea’s economic policy changes has amounted to passing the hat. In September 2002, during the ªrst-ever meeting between the heads of government of Japan and North Korea, Chairman Kim managed to extract from Prime Minister Koizumi, despite the shaky state of Japanese public ªnance, a com- mitment to provide a large ªnancial transfer to North Korea as part of the diplo- matic normalization process to settle postcolonial claims.31 Each leader then ex- pressed regrets for their countries’ respective historical sins and agreed to pursue diplomatic normalization. Then Kim’s bald admission that North Korean agents had kidnapped 12 Japanese citizens, most of whom were dead, set off a political ªrestorm in Japan. This revelation, together with North Korea’s April 2003 admis-

30 One ray of hope is the recent removal of the 50 percent limit on foreign ownership of joint ventures. 31 Japanese ofªcials did not deny formulas reported in the press that yielded a total estimated value of approximately US$10 billion for a multiyear package in the form of grants, subsi- dized loans, and trade credits. Taking inºation, changes in the value of the yen, differences in population size, and other factors into account, this sum is comparable to the transfer that Japan made to South Korea in 1965 when the two countries normalized relations. Compared with the size of the present North Korean economy, it is a gigantic sum. See Manyin (2003) for further discussion.

31 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea sion that it possesses nuclear weapons (in violation of multiple international agree- ments), effectively killed the diplomatic rapprochement and with it the prospects of a large capital infusion from Japan. It also destroyed the already dim prospects of admission to international ªnancial institutions such as the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank.

Around the time of the meetings, rumors circulated that the North Koreans in- tended to establish yet another special economic zone on the east coast, to be ori- ented toward Japan. Discounting the failed zone at Rajin-Sonbong, this would give Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 the North Koreans three special economic enclaves, one oriented toward South Ko- rea, one toward China, and one toward Japan. Given the centrality of politics in North Korean thinking, the government may well envision playing the three coun- tries off against each other to obtain improved terms with respect to aid or develop- ment of the preferential trading zones. In the long run, however, it is integration with South Korea, rather than aid from Japan or other foreign sources, that will be critically important to the development of the North Korean economy.

7. Conclusions

North Korea’s famine in the 1990s may have resulted in the death of about 3–5 per- cent of the prefamine population. As the country enters the second decade of the food crisis, remarkably little has changed: grain production has not recovered, and inexpertly enacted policy changes, a deteriorating diplomatic environment, donor fatigue, and an utterly ruthless government have brought the country once again to the precipice of famine. This situation could have been avoided. Morocco, a country of similar size and, in certain respects, similar economic characteristics, suffered a comparable fall in domestic grain output in the late 1990s. By increasing its exports and relying more on foreign borrowing, however, it was able to cover its food deªcit through imports. Make no mistake: times were hard, but through these efforts the country avoided a famine.

The North Korean famine, unlike famines suffered in other communist countries, is less a product of recent misguided policies than of the cumulative effects of two generations of economic mismanagement and social engineering. Consequently the policies are so deeply imbedded in the social and political fabric of the country that they may well prove to be more difªcult to reverse than has been the case else- where. North Korea could improve food availability by freeing up resources cur- rently devoted to the military, but as long as the country pursues its military-ªrst politics, this is unlikely.

32 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Foreign aid is not a viable long-term solution to the North Korean food crisis be- cause the food gap is too large and the political sustainability of such aid is too pre- carious. Although international aid tied to market-conforming incentive reforms could contribute to productivity increases in agriculture, it is doubtful that the eco- nomic fundamentals of the DPRK could support a food security strategy based on domestic agricultural revitalization.32 North Korea’s high ratio of population to ara- ble land, its relatively high northern latitude, and the short growing season mean that trade-opening policies in the industrial sector and systemic reforms, not in- creased agricultural output, are the strategies most likely to meet human needs in Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 the long term and obviate the need for concessional assistance. The ultimate resolu- tion to North Korea’s food problem requires the revitalization of its industrial econ- omy. An expansion of industrial exports would allow North Korea to import bulk grains on a commercial basis.

Such radical changes would face domestic and external impediments. To under- stand what has occurred during 2002 one must assess the motivations behind North Korea’s policy changes. One argument is that Kim Jong-il has long understood that the North Korean system is irretrievably broken, but it has been a time-consuming process to consolidate power and implement these far-reaching changes. This is hard to believe. Kim Jong-il was reputedly running the country on a day-to-day ba- sis for 10 years before his father’s death; thus, at the time the policy changes were announced, he had in effect been running the country for 18 years and was the un- contested for 8 years. Given the extremely hierarchical political sys- tem of North Korea, it is difªcult to believe that it took him that long to consolidate his position. Indeed, the opposite interpretation would seem more plausible: Kim Jong-il has reluctantly concluded that the old methods are inadequate to revive the economy, and out of political necessity, he is embracing marketization, inºation, and the former colonial master in a desperate bid to revitalize (though not fundamen- tally change) a moribund system. If this interpretation is correct, then a slow and hesitant pace of reform can be expected, as well as a strong reliance on the interna- tional social safety net supplied by the rest of the world. In this respect, the outcome of the diplomatic maneuvering over the North Korean nuclear weapons program through initiatives such as the Six Party Talks is of critical importance.

32 Some aid agencies have advocated increasing North Korea’s agricultural efªciency as a means of alleviating the crisis. The North Korean government has played up this idea: for example, in 2000 it announced through the WFP that with good weather and an additional US$250 million it would be self-sufªcient in 2 years. For the most sophisticated rendition of an “agriculture-centric” strategy, see McCarthy (2001a).

33 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

It is not at all clear that the current North Korean leadership is willing to counte- nance the erosion of state control that would have to accompany the degree of marketization necessary to revitalize the economy. Even if a serious reform program were attempted, it is by no means preordained that such a program would be suc- cessful. The three robust predictors of success in reforming centrally planned econo- mies are the degree of macroeconomic stability at the time that reform is initiated, the legacy of a functional presocialist commercial legal system, and the size of the agricultural sector (Sachs 1995; Åslund, Boone, and Johnson 1996). North Korea is already experiencing signiªcant macroeconomic instability, and in terms of the sec- Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 toral composition of output and employment, the North Korean economy more closely resembles the economies of Romania and parts of the former Soviet Union than it does those of the agriculture-led Asian reformers, China and Vietnam.

Finally, the divided nature of the Korean peninsula and the dynastic nature of the North Korean regime present ideological and political problems for would-be re- formers: namely, how to reinterpret the juche ideology of their virtually deiªed founding leader, Kim Il-sung, as market-oriented , particularly when most of the resulting increased economic interdependence would be with the coun- try’s rival, South Korea, and its former colonial master, Japan, and how to justify the whole raison d’être of the regime as the country begins to evolve into something like a third-rate South Korea. One possibility is that the military-ªrst campaign could be regarded as a reinterpretation of juche that emphasizes modernization in the pursuit of military security over and thereby justiªes departures from past social- ist practices even if not abandoning socialism as a teleological ideal (Frank 2003b; Noland 2004).

Even if North Korea were able to navigate successfully these domestic shoals, it is doubtful that initiatives to increase the country’s economic interdependence will be taken or that reforms could be implemented as long as the country remains, in es- sence, a pariah state, brandishing its nuclear weapons and missiles and continually subject to diplomatic sanctions by the United States, Japan, and other powers. For- eigners will not invest in such an environment. There will be no permanent solution to the North Korean food crisis until there is a resolution of its profound diplomatic problems; indeed, the diplomatic disputes have already substantially impeded short-term humanitarian aid. If external tensions could be reduced, it would not only pave the way for expanded commerce but also potentially yield a sizeable peace dividend that would facilitate increased food imports.

Even this integration into the global economy would not be easy, however. North Korea is not a member of the International Monetary Fund or any of the multilateral

34 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea development banks, and to date, contact with these organizations has been minimal (i.e., limited to a couple of informational missions of brief duration). As multiple ob- servers have emphasized, the DPRK’s institutional capacity for managing develop- ment projects is woefully limited. In all likelihood, a prolonged period of technical assistance and capacity building would be needed before substantial lending could occur (Leipziger 1998; McCarthy 2001b, 2002; Babson 2001; J. Lee 2003). Once lend- ing was under way, a necessary precursor to expanded private investment would have to be the rehabilitation of North Korea’s badly deteriorated infrastructure; for example, the transportation links between mining areas and ports require improve- Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 ment. The upside, of course, is that the degree of isolation and distortion embodied in the North Korean economy is so profound that with policy reform, investment, technology transfer, and expanded ties to the outside world (or even to its immedi- ate neighbors), the potential efªciency gains are enormous (Noland, Robinson, and Wang 2000).

If the process of improving diplomatic relations, accepting technical assistance, building infrastructure, and attracting foreign investment is broadly successful, then over the remainder of Kim Jong-il’s life, it may generate enough systemic change in North Korea such that after his passing, North and South Korea can move forward with the kind of protracted, consensual process of economic, social, and political in- tegration that both countries claim to want.

And what if the diplomatic tumblers do not fall into place? The leadership of the DPRK regards “survival” as the ªrst in a lexicographic set of preferences, and the re- gime has a history of confounding predictions of its demise. Moreover, for the last decade it has been enabled by neighbors who, for their own reasons, prefer its con- tinued existence to its disappearance. The amount of external assistance necessary to keep it on “survival rations” is not large (Michell 1998): in economic terms, the DPRK is a relatively small Chinese province. Until recently, one could conªdently predict that neither China nor South Korea would stand by idly while their neigh- bor imploded. The latest iteration of the nuclear confrontation, however, has begun to test the limits of Chinese support for its neighbor. Ironically, South Korea, which for economically self-interested reasons fears North Korea’s collapse, has emerged as North Korea’s most reliable benefactor.

Considerable research suggests that in the absence of a ªrm ideological commitment to reform, the provision of aid impedes policy change by enabling governments to avoid difªcult and painful policy choices (see Noland 2004 and citations therein). There is little evidence that North Korea is seriously committed to reform; conse- quently, it is reasonable to suppose that the availability of outside assistance will en-

35 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea courage the perpetuation of a strategy of “muddling through.” Such a strategy in all likelihood will mean the continuation of the food crisis.

However, the initiatives undertaken since July 2002 are qualitatively different from the diplomatic initiatives that the North Koreans undertook over the preceding sev- eral years. Unlike diplomatic normalizations, marketization and inºation affect the entire population and alter the economic, political, and social relations on the ground. Moreover, the stakes are far, far higher: the upside potential may be great, but failure could mean the end of the regime. A reform that failed could lead to Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 splits within the ruling elite. The instinct for self-preservation could generate a pal- ace coup, similar to what occurred in Romania, although the centrality of Kim Jong- il to the regime would appear to augur against this scenario. Alternatively, a failed reform could unleash an uncontrollable mass mobilization that resulted in the end of the regime and, possibly, something much closer to the collapse and absorption that occurred in Germany. Other outcomes are possible: the point is that reform may contain the seeds of the regime’s destruction and, paradoxically, signal the begin- ning of the end.33

So what is to be done? The outside world has an ethical obligation to feed hungry North Koreans, but it has no obligation to do so in ways that strengthen a totalitar- ian regime that is itself the source of the problem. Speciªcally, if the world commu- nity is serious about addressing the humanitarian crisis in North Korea, it should be willing to fund a multilateral initiative to create temporary refugee feeding and re- settlement camps in China, modeled on the response to the Vietnamese “boat peo- ple” crisis two decades ago. Governments like those of the United States and Euro- pean Union, which censure North Korea for its violations of (United Nations Economic and Social Council 2003), should be willing to put their money (and their refugee resettlement policies) where the mouths are.34 China is under- standably wary of a ºood of North Korean refugees, and those who criticize China for its treatment of such refugees should be willing to go beyond mere criticism and formulate constructive solutions that would address both the underlying humani- tarian disaster in the DPRK and China’s understandable domestic political concerns.

When asked why he became a revolutionary, Argentine physician Ernesto “Che” Guevara reputedly responded with the following story. One day while working in a

33 See Noland (2004) for an analysis of the possible medium- to long-run economic and politi- cal trajectories of North Korea. 34 Regrettably, Japan and South Korea (the latter of which abstained from the UN human rights vote on North Korea) have the worst refugee resettlement records among OECD member countries.

36 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea clinic in Mexico, a campesino was brought to the clinic with a broken leg. While Che applied a splint, the man explained that he had been walking down the road, stum- bled on a pothole, and fell. The following day, another peasant was brought to the clinic with a broken leg. While Che applied the splint, the patient explained that he had been walking down the road, fallen into a hole, and broken his leg. The next day yet another peasant was brought into the clinic with a broken leg. Che turned to the nurse. “You apply the splint,” he said, “I am going to ªll the hole.”

References Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 Åslund, Anders, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson. 1996. How to Stabilize: Lessons from Post- communist Countries. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:217–313.

Babson, Bradley . 2001. Potential Future Role for the International Financial Institutions on the Korean Peninsula. Unpublished manuscript.

Central Bureau of Statistics, North Korea. 2002. Report on the DPRK Nutrition Assessment 2002. 20 November. Pyongyang: Central Bureau of Statistics.

Chong, Bong-uk. 2003. The Project of Issuing Bonds. Vantage Point 26 (5):14–18.

Chung, Yun Ho. 2003. The Prospects of Economic Reform in North Korea and the Direction of Its . Vantage Point 26 (5):43–53.

Cooperative for American Relief to Everywhere (CARE). 2000. Press release, 4 April 2000, available at www.careusa.org/newsroom/pressreleases/2000/apr/northkorea0404.asp

Eberstadt, Nicholas. 1998. North Korea’s Interlocked Economic Crises. Asian Survey 38 (3):203– 30.

———. 1999. The End of North Korea. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute.

———. 2000. Our Own Style of Statistics. Economics of Korean Uniªcation 5 (1):68–93.

Eberstadt, Nicholas, and Judith Banister. 1992. The Population of North Korea. Berkeley: Institute of .

Eberstadt, Nicholas, Marc Rubin, and Albina Tretyakova. 1995. The Collapse of Soviet and Russian Trade with North Korea, 1989–1993: Impact and Implications. Korean Journal of Na- tional Uniªcation 4:87–104.

Flake, L. Gordon. 2003. The Experience of U.S. NGOs in North Korea. In Paved with Good Inten- tions: The NGO Experience in North Korea, edited by L. Gordon Flake and Scott Snyder, pp. 15– 46. Westport, Conn.: Praeger.

Foster-Carter, Aidan. 2001. The Great Bulldozer. Far Eastern Economic Review, 19 April, p. 26.

Frank, Ruediger. 2003a. A Socialist Market Economy in North Korea? Systemic Restrictions and a Quantitative Analysis. Working paper. New York: Columbia University.

———. 2003b. The End of Socialism and a Wedding Gift for the Groom? The True Meaning of the Military First Policy. Available at http://www.nautilus.org/DPRKbrieªngbook/ transition/Ruediger_Socialism.html

37 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Goodkind, Daniel, and Lorraine West. 2001. The North Korean Famine and Its Demographic Impact. Population and Development Review 27 (2):219–38.

Hawk, David. 2003. The Hidden Gulag. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Committee for Human Rights in North Korea.

International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD), Asia and the Paciªc , Programme Management Department. 2000. A Review of IFAD Projects in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea. Rome: International Fund for Agricultural Development.

Kim, Jong-il. 2000. Improving the Layout of the Field Is a Great Transformation of Nature for

the Prosperity of the Country, a Paciªc Work of Lasting Signiªcance. People’s Korea (), 21 Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 December. Speech, 24 and 27 January 2000, “Juche 89.” Available at http://210.145.168.243/ pk/139th_issue/2000051702.htm

Kim, Pyung Joo. 1998. Monetary Integration and Stabilization in the Uniªed Korea. In Policy Priorities for the Uniªed Korean Economy, edited by Il Sa Kong and Kwang Suk Kim, pp. 33–47. Seoul: Institute for Global Economics.

Kim, Sungwoo. 2003. North Korea’s Unofªcial Market Economy and Its Implications. Interna- tional Journal of 7 (1):147–64.

Kim, Woon Keun, Hyunok Lee, and Daniel A. Sumner. 1998. Assessing the Food Situation in North Korea. Economic Development and Cultural Change 46 (3):519–35.

Korean Buddhist Sharing Movement. 1998. The Food Crisis in North Korea: Witnessed by 1,694 Food Refugees. Seoul: Korean Buddhist Sharing Movement.

Lee, Hy-sang. 2000. North Korea: Strange Socialist Fortress. Westport, Conn.: Praeger.

Lee, Jong-woon. 2003. Outlook for International Agency Assistance for North Korea. Korea Fo- cus 11 (5):77–93.

Lee, Jung-chul. 2002. The Implications of North Korea’s Reform Program and Its Effects on State Capacity. Korea and World Affairs 26 (3):357–64.

Lee, Suk. 2003. Food Shortages and Economic Institutions in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea. Doctoral dissertation, Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry, United Kingdom.

Leipziger, Danny. 1998. Thinking about North Korea and the World Bank. In Economic Integra- tion on the Korean Peninsula, edited by Marcus Noland, pp. 209–19. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.

Lim, Philip Wonhyuk. 1997. North Korea’s Food Crisis. Korea and World Affairs 21 (4):568–85.

Manyin, Mark E. 2003. Japan–North Korea Relations: Selected Issues. Congressional Research Service Report to Congress. 26 November. Library of Congress Congressional Research Ser- vice, Washington, D.C.

Manyin, Mark E., and Ryun Jun. 2003. U.S. Assistance to North Korea. Congressional Research Service Report to Congress. 17 March. Library of Congress Congressional Research Service, Washington, D.C.

McCarthy, Thomas F. 2001a. Agriculture, Cooperatives, and the Korean Peace Process: Time Matters. Paper presented at the North-South Institute workshop, The DPRK: Where From? Where To?, 9–10 April, Ottawa.

38 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

———. 2001b. Managing Development Assistance in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea. Peace and Security Network Special Report. 31 August. San Francisco: The Nautilus Institute.

———. 2002. Improving the Impact of Agricultural Development Assistance in North Korea. Background paper prepared for the meeting of the Atlantic Council North Korea Working Group, 29 May, Washington, D.C.

Michell, Anthony. 1998. The Current North Korean Economy. In Economic Integration on the Ko- rean Peninsula, edited by Marcus Noland, pp. 137–63. Washington, D.C.: Institute for Interna- tional Economics. Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 Nam, Sung-wook. 2003. Moves toward Economic Reform. Vantage Point 26 (10):18–22.

Natsios, Andrew S. 2001. The Great North Korean Famine. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Institute for Peace.

———. 2003. Testimony to U.S. Senate Committee on Foreign Relations, Subcommittee on East Asian and Paciªc Affairs, 5 June.

Newcombe, William. 2003. Reºections on North Korea’s Economic Reform. In Korea’s Economy 2003, vol. 19, pp. 57–60. Washington, D.C.: Korea Economic Institute of America.

Noland, Marcus. 2000. Avoiding the Apocalypse: The Future of the Two . Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.

———. 2004. Korea after Kim Jong-il. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.

Noland, Marcus, Sherman Robinson, and Tao Wang. 2000. Rigorous Speculation: The Collapse and Revival of the North Korean Economy. World Development 28 (10):1767–88.

———. 2001. Famine in North Korea: Causes and Cures. Economic Development and Cultural Change 49 (4):741–68.

Oh, Seung-yul. 2003. Changes in the North Korean Economy: New Policies and Limitations. In Korea’s Economy 2003, vol. 19, pp. 72–78. Washington, D.C.: Korea Economic Institute of Amer- ica.

Powell, John. 2002. Testimony before the Subcommittee on and the Paciªc, House International Relations Committee, 4 May. Available at http://wwwa.house.gov/ international_relations/107/powe0502.htm

Ravallion, Martin. 1987. Markets and Famines. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Robinson, W. Courtland, Myung Ken Lee, Kenneth Hill, and Gilbert Burnham. 1999. Mortality in North Korean Migrant Households: A Retrospective Study. Lancet 354 (July–December): 291–95.

Sachs, Jeffrey. 1995. Reforms in Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union in Light of the East Asian Experience. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 9 (4):454–85.

Schloms, Michael. 2003. The European NGO Experience in North Korea. In Paved with Good In- tentions: The NGO Experience in North Korea, edited by L. Gordon Flake and Scott Snyder, pp. 47–80. Westport, Conn.: Praeger.

Sen, Amartya K. 1981. Poverty and Famines: An Essay on Entitlement and Depression. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

39 Asian Economic Papers Famine and Reform in North Korea

Smith, Hazel. 2002. Overcoming Humanitarian Dilemmas in the DPRK (North Korea). Special report no. 90. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Institute for Peace.

Smith, Heather. 1998. The Food Economy: Catalyst for Collapse? In Economic Integration of the Korean Peninsula, edited by Marcus Noland, pp. 53–75. Washington, D.C.: Institute for Interna- tional Economics.

Smith, Heather, and Yiping Huang. Forthcoming. Trade Disruption, Collectivisation and Food Crisis in North Korea. In Achieving High Growth: Experience of Transitional Economies in East Asia, edited by Peter Drysdale, Yiping Huang, and Masahiro Kawai. and Sydney: . Downloaded from http://direct.mit.edu/asep/article-pdf/3/2/1/1688365/1535351044193411.pdf by guest on 30 September 2021 Snyder, Scott. 2003a. The NGO Experience in North Korea. In Paved with Good Intentions: The NGO Experience in North Korea, edited by L. Gordon Flake and Scott Snyder, pp. 1–14. Westport, Conn.: Praeger.

———. 2003b. Lessons of the NGO Experience in North Korea. In Paved with Good Intentions: The NGO Experience in North Korea, edited by L. Gordon Flake and Scott Snyder, pp. 111–22. Westport, Conn.: Praeger.

United Nations Economic and Social Council. 2001. Economic, Social, and Cultural Rights: The Right to Food. Document no. E/CN.4/2001/53. New York: United Nations.

———. 2003. Situation of Human Rights in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea. Document no. E/CN.4/2003/L.31. New York: United Nations.

World Food Programme (WFP). 1998. Nutritional Survey of the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea. November. Available at http://www.humanitarianinfo.org/DPRK/assessments/ others/Health%20and%20Nutrition/Report_on_the_DPRK_Nutrition_Assessment_1998.pdf

———. 2003a. Child Nutrition Survey Shows Improvements in DPRK but UN Agencies Con- cerned about Holding onto Gains. Press release, Pyongyang/Geneva, 20 February. Pyongyang, Geneva: World Food Programme/United Nations Children’s Fund/North Korean Central Bu- reau of Statistics. Available at http://www.reliefweb.int/w/RWB.NSF/S/ 43349EB94958082949256CD30005948E

———. 2003b. Public Distribution System (PDS) in DPRK. DPRK Country Ofªce, 21 May. Pyongyang: World Food Programme.

———. 2003c. The World Food Programme DPR Korea Review of Operations in 2002. Pyongyang, , Rome: World Food Programme.

40 Asian Economic Papers