Community Management of the Commons

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Community Management of the Commons COMMUNITY MANAGEMENT OF THE COMMONS I. Chapter Prologue 11. Introduction 111. How Does Resource Management Work in Small Communities? A. Characteristics of the Resource B. Characteristics of the Group C. Characteristics of Effective Rules D. The Role of Central Government in Community Management E. The Psychology of Community Management F. Community Management and Hardin's Model G. Other Benefits of Community Management IV. Applying Community Management Principles Beyond Small Groups A. Local Resource Dependence in Modern Societies B. Community Management without Resource Dependence V. Community Management as a Way of Life A. Community Management versus Development Policy B. Making Resources More Manageable VI. When Is Community Management Likely to Work? VII. Conclusion: What Can Community Management Accomplish? A. Advantages of Community Management B. Limitations of Community Management C. Promising Applications of Community Management CHAPTER PROLOGUE The village of Torbel, in the Swiss Alps, has managed decided that the forests and certain low-productivity its communally owned forest and grazing lands suc- lands, such as the high Alpine meadows, should be- cessfully for centuries, sustaining the resources and long to the community rather than private owners, and avoiding the tragedy of the commons. Written rules they had set the boundaries between private and com- for resource management go back at least to the thir- munity land. The community gave villagers rights to teenth century, and on February 1, 1483, the villagers graze their cattle on the mountain in summer, and to established an association to regulate Torbel's com- use timber from the forest, and it established rules to munally owned lands. The villagers had previously protect the resources. 126 PART I1 BEHAVIORAL SOLUTION STRATEGIES Cattle Grazing on an Alpine Pasture Some Swiss villages prevent overgrazing by establishing community ownership and control of such pastures. (Georgia Engelhard/Monkmeyer Press) The grazing rules, established in 1517 and still have the power of removal. Cattle owners contribute enforced, state that "no one is permitted to send more an annual fee, proportional to the number of cattle cows to the alps than he can [feed in] winter" (Net- they own, that pays a staff to maintain roads and paths ting, 1981, p. 61). The cows are sent to the alp all at on the mountain and rebuild corrals and huts damaged once, and are immediately counted, because each by avalanches. household is allocated cheese in proportion to the The forestry rules work as follows: Once a year, number of cows it owns. A local official is authorized the village forester marks the trees to be harvested. to levy fines on those who violate the rules against The families eligible to harvest logs form work teams overgrazing and other kinds of misuse of the common and equally divide the work of cutting and stacking resource. The official, in turn, is elected at the annual logs. The households are then assigned stacks of meeting of the association of local cattle owners, who wood by a lottery. This procedure assures a fair distri- 6 COMMUNITY MANAGEMENT OF THE COMMONS 127 bution of work and of logs, and since trees can be lobstering is best. Legally, any licensed lobsterman harvested only once a year, it is easy to spot rule can fish anywhere, but because of the effort of pulling violators. pots, it is more efficient for them to work in contained These systems have operated in Torbel for centu- territories near their homes. ries, and similar systems were developed in many Lobstermen have developed strong, unwritten other Swiss villages. The villagers' methods for rules for governing these territories and defending avoiding the tragedy of the commons have stood the them from outsiders. As Acheson describes it, test of time. In many villages, though not all, the rules To go lobster fishing, one must be accepted by the men have adapted well to changes such as population fishing out of a harbor. Once a new fisherman has growth and increases in the value of the villagers' gained admission to a "harbor gang, " he is ordinarily labor in the outside economy. (The resource manage- allowed to go fishing only in the traditional territory of ment system of Torbel was described in detail by the that harbor. Interlopers are met with strong sanctions, anthropologist Robert Netting, 1976, 1981 .) sometimes merely verbal but more often involving the destruction of lobstering gear. This system . contains The coast of central Maine is the leading lobster- no "legal" elements (Acheson, 1987, p. 40). producing area in the United States. Unlike many fisheries, where valuable species have been fished Along some parts of the Maine coast, the lobster- almost to extinction, the Maine lobster fishery has men enforce territories strictly, keeping all outsiders produced a nearly steady yield for many decades. The away and reserving certain areas for particular indi- State of Maine's government is partly responsible for viduals or families, for example, on the basis of their this success by setting legal limits on the size and sex ownership of nearby land on islands. Territories are of lobsters than may be caught, requiring licenses and marked by landmarks on the shore and are defended, patrolling lobstering areas. But most of the credit sometimes to the yard, by individuals who silently belongs to the lobstermen themselves. There are not sanction the interloper. First, the violator may be enough fishery wardens for adequate enforcement, warned, usually by having his traps opened or by having and it is so easy to get a license that licensing is no two half-hitches tied around the spindle of his buoys. If barrier to overfishing. The lobstermen sustain their he persists, some or all of his traps will be "cut off." livelihoods and the resource by their own informal That is, his traps will be pulled, the buoy, toggles, and means of control, based on assigning lobstermen to warp cut 08 and the trap pushed over in deep water particular territories, and in the places where the where he has little chance offinding it (Acheson, 1987, p. 41). strictest territoriality is maintained, both the resource and the lobstermen do best. The anthropologist James Far from shore, where the boundaries are harder to Acheson (1975, 1987) has studied the fishery in de- define, lobstermen from neighboring harbors may tail, and this account is taken from his work. share the same area. Along the Maine coast, lobstering is done in small Along other parts of the coast, it has become more boats by fishers who drop wooden traps or "pots" into difficult to defend well-defined territories. With the the water and pull them up regularly to collect any advent of motorized boats and depth-finding equip- legal lobsters inside. The law requires that each trap ment, lobstermen who could purchase larger boats and buoy be marked with the owner's license number, increased their effective range. But to pay for the making it possible to check that lobstermen are li- boats, they had to fish in all seasons and to invade censed. (This law also makes it possible to for a other lobstering territories, especially far offshore. lobsterman to know who is fishing where.) A typical The men in the invaded territories generally let mixed lobsterman owns 400 to 600 pots and uses them in a fishing occur rather than imposing sanctions because very small area near a home harbor, moving them they knew how much the interlopers had at stake and farther out in winter, close to the shore in summer, and feared a full-scale "war," with large financial losses to intermediate areas in spring and fall when the for all. 128 PART I1 BEHAVIORAL SOLUTION STRATEGIES Both types of territoriality establish forms of prop- how lightly such coercive means of behavior control erty rights in an area where the law does not recognize are used, compared to individual self-control and in- private property, and the effect has been to prevent formal social pressure. overfishing. The stronger the enforcement of territori- The examples of Torbel and the Maine coast are ality, the greater the benefit. In the tightly "perimeter- special in that they involve small groups of people defended" areas we described first, there were fewer who depend on local, renewable resources for a sig- boats per area of fishing grounds, with several salu- nificant part of their livelihoods. We will see that tary results. Each lobsterman could make a living with successful community management is most often ob- less effort, there were more lobsters per area of ocean, served in settings that have these and other character- and larger lobsters were caught. It is only in the pe- istics in common. We should emphasize that small rimeter-defended areas that lobstermen have been communities do not always maintain their natural re- successful in imposing conservation measures such as sources over the long term. As we will see, smallness closed seasons and limits on the number of traps a is an advantage only in combination with other quali- lobsterman can use. Such measures benefit every ties of the communities, the resources, and the ways lobsterman in the area, and put less stress on the the two interact. lobster population, but they do so only if the rules are The relevance of the success stories from Torbel observed. Lobstermen in the perimeter-defended ar- and Maine to the world's environmental problems is eas did the best job of enforcing the territories, so they limited by the fact that most of the world's serious were best able to prevent the tragedy of the commons environmental problems arise on too large a scale to and benefit themselves. But even in the territories be managed by villages, local fishers, and other small where control was much looser, the fishery and the community groups, no matter how careful they are lobstermen have survived.
Recommended publications
  • The Realized Benefits from Bioprospecting in the Wake of the Convention on Biological Diversity
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Washington University St. Louis: Open Scholarship Washington University Journal of Law & Policy Volume 47 Intellectual Property: From Biodiversity to Technical Standards 2015 The Realized Benefits from Bioprospecting in the Wake of the Convention on Biological Diversity James S. Miller Missouri Botanical Garden Follow this and additional works at: https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_journal_law_policy Part of the Ecology and Evolutionary Biology Commons, Environmental Law Commons, and the Plant Sciences Commons Recommended Citation James S. Miller, The Realized Benefits from Bioprospecting in the Wake of the Convention on Biological Diversity, 47 WASH. U. J. L. & POL’Y 051 (2015), https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_journal_law_policy/vol47/iss1/10 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law School at Washington University Open Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Washington University Journal of Law & Policy by an authorized administrator of Washington University Open Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Realized Benefits from Bioprospecting in the Wake of the Convention on Biological Diversity James S. Miller MISSOURI BOTANICAL GARDEN In the mid-1980s, the convergence of several technological advances led to a serious resurgence of interest in surveying plant species for drug development. The emergence of methods to miniaturize in-vitro bioassays (a test used to quantify the biological effect of a chemical compound or extract against a specific disease target) run the bioassays with robotic equipment, and isolate and identify active compounds with a speed and precision never before possible.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Bioprospecting: Can Indigenous Populations Benefit from the Search for Pharmaceuticals in Areas of High Biodiversity
    University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Environmental Studies Undergraduate Student Theses Environmental Studies Program Spring 5-2011 Understanding Bioprospecting: Can Indigenous Populations Benefit from the Search for Pharmaceuticals in Areas of High Biodiversity Emily Schwindt University of Nebraska-Lincoln Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/envstudtheses Part of the Agricultural and Resource Economics Commons, Biological and Physical Anthropology Commons, Environmental Health and Protection Commons, Ethnic Studies Commons, Natural Resource Economics Commons, Natural Resources and Conservation Commons, Natural Resources Management and Policy Commons, Other Environmental Sciences Commons, Place and Environment Commons, and the Sustainability Commons Disclaimer: The following thesis was produced in the Environmental Studies Program as a student senior capstone project. Schwindt, Emily, "Understanding Bioprospecting: Can Indigenous Populations Benefit from the Search for Pharmaceuticals in Areas of High Biodiversity" (2011). Environmental Studies Undergraduate Student Theses. 46. https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/envstudtheses/46 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Environmental Studies Program at DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. It has been accepted for inclusion in Environmental Studies Undergraduate Student Theses by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. UNDERSTANDING BIOPROSPECTING:
    [Show full text]
  • Relationships Among Biodiversity Dimensions of Birds in Nebraska Nadejda Mirochnitchenko University of Nebraska - Lincoln, [email protected]
    University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Dissertations & Theses in Natural Resources Natural Resources, School of Fall 12-2018 Relationships Among Biodiversity Dimensions of Birds in Nebraska Nadejda Mirochnitchenko University of Nebraska - Lincoln, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.unl.edu/natresdiss Part of the Biodiversity Commons, Ecology and Evolutionary Biology Commons, Natural Resources and Conservation Commons, Natural Resources Management and Policy Commons, Ornithology Commons, and the Poultry or Avian Science Commons Mirochnitchenko, Nadejda, "Relationships Among Biodiversity Dimensions of Birds in Nebraska" (2018). Dissertations & Theses in Natural Resources. 275. http://digitalcommons.unl.edu/natresdiss/275 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Natural Resources, School of at DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dissertations & Theses in Natural Resources by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. RELATIONSHIPS AMONG BIODIVERSITY DIMENSIONS OF BIRDS IN NEBRASKA by Nadejda Anatolievna Mirochnitchenko A THESIS Presented to the Faculty of The Graduate College at the University of Nebraska In Partial Fulfillment of Requirements For the Degree of Master of Science Major: Natural Resource Sciences Under the Supervision of Professors Erica F. Stuber and Joseph J. Fontaine Lincoln, Nebraska December 2018 RELATIONSHIPS AMONG BIODIVERSITY
    [Show full text]
  • Plant Genetic Resources As Commons: the Model of Fao’S International Treaty
    PLANT GENETIC RESOURCES AS COMMONS: THE MODEL OF FAO’S INTERNATIONAL TREATY Dr. María Iglesias Introduction After almost 7 years of negotiations, the International Treaty on Plant Genetic Resources for Food and Agriculture (hereinafter ITPGRFA) was adopted in November 20011. The Treaty already recognises in its Preamble that plant genetic resources for food and agriculture are a common concern of all countries, in that all countries depend very largely on plant genetic resources for food and agriculture that originated elsewhere. Thus, the main objectives of the ITPGRFA are the conservation and sustainable use of plant genetic resources for food and agriculture (hereinafter PGRFAs) and the fair and equitable sharing of the benefits arising out of their use, in harmony with the Convention on Biological Diversity, for sustainable agriculture and food security2. Although the Treaty covers all PGRs3, it establishes an international commons pool, the so called multilateral system, only for certain kinds of resources that will guarantee the access to these resources and the sharing of benefits 1 The ITPGRFA entered in to force in June 2004. In December 2008, 119 states had ratified it. 2 Art. 1. The ITPGRFA may be considered in fact as a special application of art. 15 (Access to Genetic Resources) of the Convention on Biological Diversity: “1. Recognizing the sovereign rights of States over their natural resources, the authority to determine access to genetic resources rests with the national governments and is subject to national legislation. 2. Each Contracting Party shall endeavour to create conditions to facilitate access to genetic resources for environmentally sound uses by other Contracting Parties and not to impose restrictions that run counter to the objectives of this Convention.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Commons: Between Cooperation and Competition by Gerald Stang
    17 2013 Photo by NASA / Rex Features (1568628a) Features / Rex NASA by Photo Global commons: Between cooperation and competition by Gerald Stang Rapid economic development and increasing inter- What exactly are the global commons? national trade are leading to a more crowded interna- tional stage and raising new challenges in the ‘global Security analysts generally identify four domains as commons’ – those domains that are not under the global commons: high seas, airspace, outer space control or jurisdiction of any state but are open for use and, now, cyberspace. From a security perspective, by countries, companies and individuals from around the primary concern is safeguarding ‘access’ to these the world. Their management involves increasingly domains for commercial and military reasons. complex processes to accommodate and integrate the interests and responsibilities of states, international It is important to highlight that this language differs organisations and a host of non-state actors. from the discourse on commons developed by envi- ronmental analysts: their arguments focus on dam- Shared rules regarding the usage of - and access to age to the ‘condition’ of the commons from overuse - the global commons encourage their peaceful and by actors who do not have to pay direct costs. They cooperative use. Over the last seven decades, the US worry about the depletion of shared resources such as has led in the creation of a liberal international order ocean fish stocks, or the damage to shared domains which has attempted to define these rules in such a such as Antarctica or the atmosphere. way as to make it easier and more beneficial to join the order and follow the rules than it does to operate A third strand of analysis looks not at the need for outside of (or undermine) it.
    [Show full text]
  • The "Tragedy of the Commons" in Plant Genetic Resources: the Need for a New International Regime Centered Around an International Biotechnology Patent Office
    Gulati: The "Tragedy of the Commons" in Plant Genetic Resources: The Need for a New International Regime Centered Around an International Biotechnology Patent Office Note The "Tragedy of the Commons" in Plant Genetic Resources: The Need for a New International Regime Centered Around an International Biotechnology Patent Office Chetan Gulati- The last several centuries have seen a transformation in the ways in which wealth is generated. As society has transformed itself in the post- industrial era, "knowledge" and "information," as opposed to land and physical property, have increasingly become the primary sources of wealth generation.1 For example, historically, it was ownership of the forest that was the principal channel for the derivation of riches. Today it is the possession of the patent in the pharmaceutical product derived from the leaves of the trees of the very same forest that is the fountain from which the greatest wealth springs. It is not surprising, therefore, that the strategy of wealth maximization has shifted from the desire to accumulate physical property to one in which the domination2 of intellectual property rights ("IPRs") has become preeminent. As already alluded to, the products derived from plant genetic resources ("PGRs")3 are major sources of wealth generation for developed t J.D., Yale Law School, expected 2002. I am grateful to Professor Gideon Parchomovsky for his guidance and valuable commentary. I should also thank my colleagues at the Yale Law School, especially Saema Somalya, Jean Tom and the other editors of the Yale Human Rights and Development Law Journal, without whose constant challenge to my ideas, this project would never have come to fruition.
    [Show full text]
  • An Introduction to the Digital Commons: from Common-Pool Resources to Community Governance Melanie Dulong De Rosnay, Hervé Le Crosnier
    An Introduction to the Digital Commons: From Common-Pool Resources to Community Governance Melanie Dulong de Rosnay, Hervé Le Crosnier To cite this version: Melanie Dulong de Rosnay, Hervé Le Crosnier. An Introduction to the Digital Commons: From Common-Pool Resources to Community Governance. Building Institutions for Sustain- able Scientific, Cultural and genetic Resources Commons, Sep 2012, Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium. http://biogov.uclouvain.be/iasc/index.php?page=fullpapers. halshs-00736920 HAL Id: halshs-00736920 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00736920 Submitted on 30 Sep 2012 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. An Introduction to the Digital Commons: From Common-Pool Resources to Community Governance Mélanie Dulong de Rosnay, Institute for Communication Sciences of CNRS, Paris Hervé Le Crosnier, University of Caen and Institute for Communication Sciences of CNRS, Paris Abstract This article proposes an introductory analysis of digital resources and commons-based peer production online communities with the framework of the common pool-resources. Trying to go beyond the classic economy dichotomy between physical resources scarcity and informational resources reproducibility, the approach allows to focus not only on the nature of the resources, but mostly on the governance by the communities to produce resources which remain available for all to share and build upon, while avoiding risks of pollution, degradation, underuse or enclosure by the market.
    [Show full text]
  • Commons Common Pool Resource
    Commons From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia Commons refers to the cultural and natural resources accessible to all members of a society, including natural materials such as air, water, and a habitable earth. These resources are held in common, not owned privately. The resources held in common can include everything from natural resources and common land to software. The commons contains public property and private property, over which people have certain traditional rights. When commonly held property is transformed into private property this process alternatively is termed "enclosure" or more commonly, "privatization." Common Pool Resource ‐ CPR DEFINITION A resource that benefits a group of people, but which provides diminished benefits to everyone if each individual pursues his or her own self interest. The value of a common‐pool resource can be reduced through overuse [or abuse] because the supply of the resource is not unlimited, and using more than can be replenished can result in scarcity. Overuse of a common pool resource can lead to the tragedy of the commons problem. From: http://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/common‐pool‐resource.asp From Ostrom, “Revisiting the Commons” We use the term common‐pool resources (CPRs) to refer to resource systems regardless of the property rights involved. CPRs include natural and human‐ constructed resources in which (i) exclusion of beneficiaries through physical and institutional means is especially costly, and (ii) exploitation by one user reduces resource availability for others. These two characteristics‐difficulty of exclusion and subtractability‐create potential CPR dilemmas in which people following their own short‐term interests produce outcomes that are not in anyone’s long‐term interest.
    [Show full text]
  • Past and Present Conditions of the Tri-State Mining District
    BearWorks MSU Graduate Theses Summer 2020 The Legacy of Mining in Southwest Missouri: Past and Present Conditions of the Tri-State Mining District Anastasia M C McClanahan Missouri State University, [email protected] As with any intellectual project, the content and views expressed in this thesis may be considered objectionable by some readers. However, this student-scholar’s work has been judged to have academic value by the student’s thesis committee members trained in the discipline. The content and views expressed in this thesis are those of the student-scholar and are not endorsed by Missouri State University, its Graduate College, or its employees. Follow this and additional works at: https://bearworks.missouristate.edu/theses Part of the Environmental Chemistry Commons, Environmental Health and Protection Commons, Environmental Monitoring Commons, Environmental Public Health Commons, Geochemistry Commons, Geology Commons, Natural Resources and Conservation Commons, Other Earth Sciences Commons, Other Environmental Sciences Commons, Soil Science Commons, Sustainability Commons, and the Water Resource Management Commons Recommended Citation McClanahan, Anastasia M C, "The Legacy of Mining in Southwest Missouri: Past and Present Conditions of the Tri-State Mining District" (2020). MSU Graduate Theses. 3556. https://bearworks.missouristate.edu/theses/3556 This article or document was made available through BearWorks, the institutional repository of Missouri State University. The work contained in it may be protected by
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Ostrom in the City: Design Principles and Practices for the Urban Commons Sheila R. Foster & Christian Iaione Forthcoming
    Ostrom in the City: Design Principles and Practices for the Urban Commons Sheila R. Foster & Christian Iaione forthcoming in the Routledge Handbook of the Study of the Commons (Dan Cole, Blake Hudson, Jonathan Rosenbloom eds.) Introduction If cities are the places where most of the world’s population will be living in the next century, as is predicted, it is not surprising that they have become sites of contestation over use and access to urban land, open space, infrastructure, and culture. The question posed by Saskia Sassen in a recent essay— who owns the city? —is arguably at the root of these contestations and of social movements that resist the enclosure of cities by economic elites (Sassen 2015). One answer to the question of who owns the city is that we all do. In our work we argue that the city is a common good or a “commons” — a shared resource that belongs to all of its inhabitants, and to the public more generally. We have been writing about the urban commons for the last decade, very much inspired by the work of Jane Jacobs and Elinor Ostrom. The idea of the urban commons captures the ecological view of the city that characterizes Jane Jacobs classic work, The Death and Life of Great American Cities. (Foster 2006) It also builds on Elinor Ostrom’s finding that common resources are capable of being collectively managed by users in ways that support their needs yet sustains the resource over the long run (Ostrom 1990). Jacobs analyzed cities as complex, organic systems and observed the activity within them at the neighborhood and street level, much like an ecologist would study natural habitats and the species interacting within them.
    [Show full text]
  • Considering Community-Based Co-Management for Sustainable Fisheries" (2013)
    Claremont Colleges Scholarship @ Claremont Pomona Senior Theses Pomona Student Scholarship 2013 A New Commons: Considering Community- Based Co-Management for Sustainable Fisheries Charlotte L. Dohrn Pomona College Recommended Citation Dohrn, Charlotte L., "A New Commons: Considering Community-Based Co-Management for Sustainable Fisheries" (2013). Pomona Senior Theses. Paper 81. http://scholarship.claremont.edu/pomona_theses/81 This Open Access Senior Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Pomona Student Scholarship at Scholarship @ Claremont. It has been accepted for inclusion in Pomona Senior Theses by an authorized administrator of Scholarship @ Claremont. For more information, please contact [email protected]. A NEW COMMONS: CONSIDERING COMMUNITY­BASED CO­MANAGEMENT FOR SUSTAINABLE FISHERIES Charlotte Dohrn In partial fulfillment of a Bachelor of Arts Degree in Environmental Analysis, 2012‐13 academic year, Pomona College, Claremont, California Readers: Dr. Nina Karnovsky Dr. Heather Williams Dohrn 2 Dohrn 3 Many thanks to my readers, Nina Karnovsky and Heather Williams, for their advice, support and confidence throughout my project. It was an honor to work with both of you. Many thanks to Char Miller, for being the heart and soul of the Environmental Analysis Department, for being an incredible resource, and for the tea and “recommended” writing sessions. Many thanks to my family for listening to me ramble, helping me edit and providing love and support over the phone. Many thanks to my fellow EA majors for the laughs, late nights and moral support. Many thanks to my non‐EA friends who I will now be able to enjoy spending time with. And many, many thanks to all of the people who spoke with me and taught me about their lives during this research process.
    [Show full text]
  • An Introduction to Ostrom's Eight Principles for Sustainable
    An Introduction to Ostrom’s Eight Principles for Sustainable Governance of Common-Pool Resources as a Possible Framework for Sustainable Governance of Space T. Chow, Secure World Foundation, [email protected] B. Weeden, Secure World Foundation, [email protected] Abstract This paper outlines the “tragedy of the commons,” reviews Nobel Prize Winner1 Elinor Ostrom’s principles for sustainable governance of common-pool resources (CPR), and relates both to outer space. Ostrom’s principles were distilled from decades of studies on dozens of CPR situations. They capture the best practices of CPRs that have been used sustainably for decades or even centuries, thus avoiding the famous “tragedy of the commons” without relying on privatization or a “Leviathan” authority. When viewed in the context of space sustainability and governance, these principles highlight some long- standing challenges and emerging issues. Over the past few years, achieving the long-term sustainability of space activities has become a central goal for many, both at the national and international level. However, while more policymakers and stakeholders are recognizing the importance of space sustainability, none have spelled out an effective governance strategy, and accompanying policies, for accomplishing it. This paper concludes that Ostrom’s principles can potentially inform those ongoing policy initiatives and highlight specific areas on which to focus initial space sustainability efforts. Introduction Over the last few years, the goal of space sustainability has become increasingly important within the field of space policy. Although many have long recognized the importance of outer space for national and international security and global business, there is a growing realization that the ability to use space for its benefits on Earth is not guaranteed forever.
    [Show full text]