Learning Strategies of New Chinese Entrants in the Mobile Telephone Handset Industry
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Faculty & Research Latecomer Strategies: Leveraging and learning by China’s Handset Makers by W. Xie and S. White 2005/03/ABCM Working Paper Series LATECOMER STRATEGIES: LEVERAGING AND LEARNING BY CHINA’S HANDSET MAKERS WEI XIE School of Economics and Management Tsinghua University Beijing Email: [email protected] and STEVEN WHITE INSEAD Singapore and Fontainebleau, France Email: [email protected] Acknowledgements The research on which this paper is based was financially supported by the National Science Foundation of China (NSF Research Projects 70173008 and 70373005). The authors would like to thank the interviewees and Mr. Zhiping Zhao’s help with interviews. 1 LATECOMER STRATEGIES: LEVERAGING AND LEARNING BY CHINA’S HANDSET MAKERS ABSTRACT This paper examines the deliberate learning strategies of new Chinese entrants in the mobile telephone handset industry. Within a particular industry and national context— characterized by a large domestic market, disintegrated technological regime, established foreign firms, and supportive government policies—they have been able to acquire key resources and capabilities and also exploit their own specific advantages in order to become serious competitors in the domestic market vis-à-vis global incumbents. These latecomers have tightly linked their product innovation efforts to the local market characteristics and created competitive advantages through their distribution channels. The findings relate to the broader literature on organizational learning emphasizing the sequential, evolutionary and path-dependent nature of such learning. 2 The objective of this paper is to identify the environmental and organization-level factors that created the opportunity for Chinese firms to newly enter the Chinese handset market that had been completely dominated by a few multinational incumbents. To do this, we draw on the extensive literature focused on other national contexts, primarily Korea and Taiwan, that has examined the process of technological learning and capability accumulation (e.g., Amsden, 1989, 2001; Kim and Lee, 2003; Lee and Choi, 1988; Bell and Pavitt, 1993; Hobday, 1994, 1995a, 1995b, 1995c, 1998; Kim, 1997. Kim, Lee and Lee, 1987; Kim and Dahlman, 1992; Kim and Nelson, 2000; Matthews and Cho, 2000; Kim and Lee, 2003; Figueiredo, 2002, 2003). These and related studies come under what Figueiredo (2001, 2002) classifies as the latecomer firm literature. Unlike studies of leading firms at the technological frontiers, the latecomer studies must address the process by which these firms acquire often basic technological capabilities first to enter and subsequently compete in new industries. These studies usually highlight two major disadvantages facing most latecomers intent on entering new industries and markets: distance from main sources of technology, and distance from major markets. On the other hand, latecomer firms motivated to catch up may also have a number of advantages. Those often cited include cheap and well- trained labor, subcontracting opportunities based on cost-advantages, training by foreign buyers, a large and easily accessible pool of public knowledge, low or no sunk costs in earlier technology, local market knowledge, and favorable governmental policies (export promotion incentives, local industry protection policies, financial subsidies, etc.). To overcome these disadvantages and exploit any advantages they have, however, latecomers must successfully learn. In this context, learning involves the absorption of external knowledge (from abroad or from adjacent multinationals), upgrading of 3 technological capabilities, and acquisition of other competitively important resources and capabilities. Studies have addressed how latecomers acquire needed technologies from advanced countries (Pack, 2000; Wu and Hsu, 2001; Hiraoka, 2001), and how they manage the learning process and move up the value chain (Kuman and Bhat, 2000) and narrow technology gaps with firms in developed countries (Jegathesan, Gunasekaran and Muthaly, 1997; Bowonder, 1998; Matthews, 2001). These and other studies at the firm level have basically confirmed the main characteristics of learning processes proposed by Lall (1992) and Bell and Pavitt (1995). Specifically, learning is usually costly and time-consuming, technological capability building is not an automatic process of production, firms are the central actors, learning is a cumulative process, the absorption and assimilation of new technologies by firms in a developing country involves a learning process which is often prolonged and risky, and latecomers often underinvest in the learning process. Moreover, any analysis of the process and outcomes of firm-level technological learning initiatives must incorporate the industrial, policy, national and international features of the context in which it occurs (e.g., Hobday, 1995a; Kim, 1997). While scholars interested in latecomer issues typically focus on the acquisition of technological knowledge and capabilities, a large body of research on innovation highlights the role of the market as both source of ideas and direction for development efforts (e.g., von Hippel, 1989) as well as a selection mechanism. Regarding the latter role, technological capabilities and innovative outputs are valuable only to the extent that they have a value in the marketplace or provide some kind of competitive advantage. Conversely, as the literature on the resource-based view of the firm and organizational capabilities argues, any resources and capabilities that enhance firm performance (i.e., not just technology-related ones) are valuable and should be acquired (e.g., Penrose, 1959; 4 Nelson and Winter, 1982; Barney, 1991; Wernerfelt, 1994; Teece, Pisano and Shuen, 1997; Itami, 1987). In this paper, we examine the emergence of China’s handset manufacturers from an organizational learning perspective to address the same basic questions of prior latecomer literature; namely, how did these firms acquire the resources and capabilities to enter the industry and eventually compete with incumbent multinationals, and what contextual factors (industry, policy, national and international) played a role in this process? Rather than a narrow focus on technological knowledge and capabilities, however, we consider a broader range of firm-level resources and capabilities that may explain the demonstrated success of these latecomers vis-à-vis incumbents. The data for this analysis is drawn from a series of 22 interviews with managers in Chinese and foreign manufacturers and industry experts, supplemented by publicly available data on the firms and handset market. RISE OF CHINESE HANDSET MANUFACTURERS As a group, China’s handset manufacturers have been extremely successful in terms of acquiring and enhancing the resources and capabilities necessary to compete in the domestic handset market. From a collective market share of only 5.3% in 1999, they overtook the dominant multinationals in the Chinese market by 2003 (Figure 1). Given the extremely high market growth rates during this period, their increase in absolute production volumes and sales is even more dramatic. In terms of global production, Chinese manufacturers’ share rose from 2.3% in 1999 to 35% in 2003. These impressive gains were accomplished by a rapid increase in the number of domestic manufacturers and rapid production scale-up by each manufacturer. 5 As prior literature suggests, the factors behind such a spectacular emergence of latecomer firms lie in both the environment from which they emerged and within the organizations themselves. The following sections describe those factors relevant to the rise of China’s handset manufacturers. ENVIRONMENT: OPPORTUNITIES OUTWEIGH BARRIERS Assuming that new entry is a result of strategic choice by firm managers, we must also assume that those managers not only perceived attractive opportunities for entry, but that those opportunities also outweighed barriers to entry. In the case of China’s handset industry in the mid-to-late 1990s, there were significant barriers to new entrants in the domestic market. First, the domestic market was highly concentrated and dominated by foreign firms. The leading global manufacturers had all established handset manufacturing and sales operations in China between 1993 and 1996 (Table 1), although most were in the form of Sino-foreign joint ventures. They were well financed and had successfully established production, marketing and sales operations in the domestic market. In the early years, from the late 1980s to early 1990s, Motorola controlled essentially 100% of the market. It had entered early with a major investment and long- term commitment to China. It also benefited from the Chinese government’s initial adoption of the TACS (Total Access Communications Service) standard, originating from AMPS (Advanced Mobile Phone System). Motorola supplied system equipment for this standard, and also supplied China Telecom with handsets. Nokia and Ericsson, using a different standard, entered China only in 1995 when China Unicom was created and began to build its GSM network. 6 Motorola’s reluctant transition from analog to digital standard handsets and its slow pace of new handset model introductions created the space for Nokia and Ericsson to join Motorola as dominant firms; the three of them held a combined market share of 80% in 1998. The remaining market was split among Siemens, Samsung, Philips, Alcatel and Sony. Besides the overwhelming dominance of foreign firms in the domestic