Adoption of Contour Hedgerows by Upland Farmers in the Philippines: An Economic Analysis ----•=-.,•� �=���•,,,,,.w�=,••mo,.�• Ma. Lucila A. Lapar, Sushil Pandey, and Herman Waibel

IRRI lNrERNATIONAL RICE RESEARCH lNSTITIJTE Contents

Introduction 1 The contour hedgerow technology 2 A microeconomic model of 4 The nature of the production system and soil conservation S Intensification, property rights, and soil conservation 6 Microeconomic evidence from the Philippine uplands 8 Econometric analysis 23 Cost-benefit analysis 29 Concluding remarks and implications 32 References 34 Appendix A. A microeconomic model of soil conservation. 38 Appendix B. Distribution of sample respondents by survey site and villages. 39 Appendix C. Estimating the productivity effects of soil conservation. 40

Adoption of Contour Hedgerows by Upland Farmers in the Philippines: An Economic Analysis

Ma. Lucila A. Lapar, Sushi I Pandey, and Herman Waibel*

Introduction Soil degradation through physical loss (or factors: (I) lack of or limited effective technical erosion) is an important problem, especially in or social solutions to alleviate poverty and the sloping uplands of the humid and subhumid environmental problems in these areas, (2) tropics. These areas have highly erodible soils unclear officialresponsibility for land use, (3) and high-intensity rainfall. Farmers in the humid unclear property rights to sloping public upland tropics of Asia grow a range of subsistence areas, and (4) greater degrees of poverty and crops in sloping and marginal uplands and often illiteracy in upland communities, making it use highly erosive practices (Garrity et al 1993). difficult to transferknowledge and provide In addition to decreasing in situ productivity, services for more sustainable agricultural these practices also reduce the sustainability of production (Sajise and Ganapin 1991, USAID lowland through siltation and 1995). damage to irrigation infrastructure (Francisco 1994). Several government projects with funding from internationaldonors were begun to intro­ Under what conditions will farmers adopt duce and spread hillside conservation farming practices that conserve soil? Experiences from practices aimed at managing sloping upland many projects indicate that the problem is often soils forsustainable crop production. Programs not the lack of technology per se but an ill fit of in agroforestry and watershed management-for the technology being promoted with the socio­ example, the Integrated Social Forestry Project economic conditions under which farming is of the Department of Environment and Natural carried out (Fujisaka 1989, Anderson and Resources (DENR) and the Central Visayas Thampapillai 1990, Baum et al 1993, Lutz et al Regional Project of the Department of Agricul­ 1994). Engineering solutions such as rock walls, ture (DA)-have always had a soil conservation check dams, and bench terraces have had little component. More often than not, these programs success in creating wider impact because of their provide direct incentives to farmer-participants high costs. Other less costly technologies such to adopt the suggested soil conservation technol­ as contour hedgerows (CH), contour plowing, ogy. Some nongovernmentorganizations and cover management have also been adopted, (NGOs) have likewise begun community but sporadically. Overall, various interventions development projects with soil conservation designed to promote the adoption of conserva­ components, such as those undertaken by the tion techniques seem to have had a limited World Neighbors and the Mag-uugmad Founda­ impact on soil conservation. tion, Inc. Although some of these initiatives successfully convinced farmers to adopt soil The soil degradation problem in the Philip­ conservation technology, others were not quite pine uplands could be the direct result of several as effective. Apparently, direct incentives alone

'Project scientist and agricultural economist, respectively, International Rice Research Institute; and professor, University of Hannover. We would like to acknowledge the research assistance of Pio Adan Genas and S.P. Regmi in the field survey and data processing. The research reported here was partiallyfunded by GTZ. Federal Republic of Germany.

1 do not guarantee adoption even if such incen­ The contour hedgerow technology tives appear to have increased adoption rates Contour hedgerow intercropping or alley under several government-sponsored projects. cropping on sloping lands is an agroforestry practice of planting leguminous plants on the This socioeconomic study of the adoption of contour to provide green leaf manure to fertilize CH technology by upland farmers in the Philip­ annual crops and serve as a barrier to soil loss pines is part of a project by the Upland Rice (Garrity 1994, Ehui 1993). The hedgerows are Research Consortium in South and Southeast cut back at the time of planting of the food crops Asia that aims to address the major constraints and are periodically pruned during cropping to to productivity and sustainability of upland rice­ prevent shading and to reduce competition with based farming systems. The major objectives of associated food crops. The major advantage of the study are to (I) analyze costs and returns the CH system is that it allows simultaneous associated with adoption, (2) estimate productiv­ fallow-i.e., the cropping and fallow phases can ity effectsof adoption of a soil conservation take place concurrently on the same land, technology, (3) determine the socioeconomic thereby making permanent cropping possible factors that affect farmers' adoption decisions, and overcoming the need for fallowing, which is (4) evaluate farmers' perceptions of the advan­ characteristic of shifting cultivation systems tages and disadvantages of adoption, and (5) (Garrity 1994, Ehui 1993). This technology derive policy implications fromempirical appears to be an appropriate form of soil erosion findings. Although the study looks at soil control for areas with sloping land, permanent conservation in general, it focuses on a particu­ plow agriculture, intense rainfall, and land lar soil conservation technology, the contour scarcity (Fujisaka 1993, Ehui 1993). hedgerow. This soil conservation practice has been widely promoted in the Philippine uplands The CH system has emerged as the latest since the early 1980s. Funding for the study example of paradigm shifts in soil conservation came from the Federal Ministry for Economic (Garrity 1994). Soil conservation earlier empha­ Cooperation (BMZ)/German Agency for Techni­ sized the engineering approach; it then yielded cal Cooperation (GTZ). to the biological approach that focused on the role of agroforestry in conserving soil. Subse­ This report is structured as follows. The first quently, the pruned leguminous tree hedgerow part discusses CH systems and gives some concept of contour fanning became popular as a background information regarding various way of creating simultaneous fallow. Results of efforts to promote this technology in upland global research on CH are not easy to general­ areas of the Philippines. The next section ize, but two major conclusions can be drawn presents a microeconomic model for analyzing from them. First, pruned tree hedgerows are not factors that influence adoption. The next part able to maintain an adequate nutrient supply to describes the characteristics of production sustain annual cropping indefinitely without systems and discusses incentives for soil conser­ external nutrientapplication. Hence, hedgerows vation. The next section analyzes the relation­ are not a viable alternativeto fallow rotation in ship between property rights and soil conserva­ the absence of external nutrients, but rather an tion, followed by descriptive results of empirical intermediate pathway between fallow rotation work conducted in the Philippines. Subsequent and continuous cropping with inorganic fertil­ sections present an econometric analysis of the izer. Second, farmer adoption of contour productivity effectsof CH and the factors hedgerows has been limited because of the determining adoption. A benefit-cost analysis of added labor needed for pruning and mainte­ CH systems for the Philippines follows. The nance. Many options with the same soil conser­ final section synthesizes the results and implica­ vation functions but less labor requirement and tions for policy and technology development and more economic benefits have been explored to dissemination. overcome the limitations of pruned tree

2 hedgerows. These options include the use of solutions to the perceived dominant constraints fodder grass strips and "cash perennials" such as to crop cultivation on steeply sloping lands fruit trees, coffee, and mulberry, among others. (Garrity et al 1993). The bunds provided a base for the establishment of double-CH of legumi­ The CH technology has been introduced into nous trees or forage grasses and a barrier to the Philippine uplands with various adaptations surface runoff,which leaves the field in contour (Garrity et al 1993). Leucaena hedgerows were ditches. The CH concept was also applied to introduced in the mid-l 970s. Applied research strongly acidic upland soils by the International in various locations in the Philippines showed Rice Research Institute (IRRI) and the DA that Leucaena hedgerow intercropping produced (Fujisaka and Garrity 1988). Field experiments crop yield increases ranging from 23% to 100% showed that, after 3 yr of hedgerow intercrop­ (Guevarra 1976, Vergara 1982, Alferez 1980). ping, a striking natural development of terraces Leucaena hedgerows also provided a barrier to occurred (Garrity et al 1993). Yield increases soil movement on sloping lands, resulting in a were also observed (Basri et al 1990, Mercado et large reduction in both runoffand soil loss al 1992). On the other hand, crop yields were (O'Sullivan 1985). By the early 1980s, the DA seriously reduced in rows adjoining the hedges, advocated Leucaena hedgerow intercropping as with or without the application of external a technology that was better able to sustain nutrients. This is also referred to as the scouring permanent cereal cropping with minimal or no effectthat degrades soil resources in alleyways. fertilizer inputs and as a soil Experience in Claveria, Misamis Oriental in measure for sloping lands (Garrity et al 1993). Mindanao, showed that farmer adaptations of The extension of this system among Filipino the CH technology evolved into a technology farmers was encouraged by the work of the featuring an A-framecontour layout, with NGO Mindanao Baptist Rural LifeCenter, plowing and shoveling as options, and farmer­ which developed a 10-step program for farmer selected combinations of native and planted implementation of Leucaena hedgerows. This grasses (such as species of Setaria and program was called the Sloping Agricultural Brachiaria brizantha), pasture legumes (such as Land Technology (SALT) and, by the mid- Stylosanthes guianensis), tree crops (such as l 980s, the DA adopted it as the basis for its mulberry), and perennial crops (such as pine­ extension effort in the uplands. The DENR apple) (Fujisaka 1993). An indigenous contour likewise used it as the technical basis for its hedgerow technology was also reported to be social forestry pilot projects. Some adoption of practiced in Matalom, Leyte (Ly Tung and Leucaena hedgerows occurred in the high­ Alcober 199 I). intensity extension projects, but there was little evidence of widespread farmer interest in the Adoption of contour hedgerows has been SALT system. This could be due to the lack of short-lived. Farmers were observed to have secure land tenure, large initial investment in "abandoned" the hedgerows or allowed them to labor, difficulty in obtaining planting materials, lie fallow because of several technical reasons and technical training and information required (Fujisaka and Cenas 1993). This led to the for sustained implementation (Garrity et al observation that the technology had "failed." 1993). Aside from Leucaena, hedgerows of Garrity (1994), however, contends that fallowing other species were also used-Gliricidia of hedgerows is not really an indication of sepium, Flemingia congesta, Acacia vellosa, failure but rather a rational response of farmers Leucaena diversifolia, and Cassia spectabilis. to the continued decline in soil productivity in the absence of externalnutrient inputs. Contour Contour bunding with hedgerows was hedgerows can be managed in a fallow rotation introduced by the World Neighbors, another system. They do not completely eliminate NGO, as part of an approach oriented toward fallowing; rather they enhance the process by developing a high degree of direct participation shortening the fallow period while lengthening by farmers in devising and implementing local the cropping period. They also reduce labor for

3 reopening of land and for subsequent weeding. operates and may be considered farm-specific, Furthermore, they can produce wood, fodder, farmer-specific, or technology-specific. Institu­ and other products of economic value. tional and policy factorsdetermine the incen­ tives for adopting conservation practices. These Recent work fundedby the Australian include security of tenure, economic returnsto Centre for International Agricultural Research agriculture vs other enterprises, and access to investigated farm-level factors associated with technical assistance and inputs. Farmer-specific the adoption of contour hedgerows in eight case­ factors are farmers' goals, their perceptions, and study areas in the Philippines (Garcia and their resource constraints. Farm-specific factors Gerrits 1995, Garcia et al 1995-97). Empirical are related to the biophysical characteristics of results indicate that readily measurable personal the production system such as soil characteris­ attributes of farmers such as age and education tics, field slope, and climate. Technology­ were not important in explaining adoption, but specific factors are features of the technology the less easily measured personality traits related available to farmers. Figure 1 presents these to innovativeness and managerial ability were factors and their interactions. clearly critical, particularly among early adopt­ ers (Cramb and Nelson 1997). In terms of farm­ The factors indicated in Figure 1 are the specific factors, adoption was more likely on same ones that have been studied widely in the fields that are larger and steeper, have more context of adoption of modem crop varieties and erodible soils, are located closer to the home­ associated crop management technologies stead, have relatively more uniformterrain, and (Feder et al 1985). But soil conservation tech­ are oriented down (rather than across) the terrain nologies differfrom varietal and crop manage­ (Cramb and Nelson 1997). Insecurity of land ment technologies in that the formerrepresent tenure as well as liquidity constraints arising an investment that generates a stream of benefits from low cash income are among the major into the future while the latter generate returns constraints to adoption identifiedin the study. within a shorter time horizon. For soil conserva­ Results of cost-benefit analyses show that tion to be economically viable, the present value hedgerow intercropping can potentially sustain of the stream of benefits must exceed the present maize production relative to the traditional value of its cost. Appendix A presents a formal method of open-field farming by controlling multiperiod model for analyzing the economics erosion and contributing nitrogen to the crop­ of soil conservation. Based on this model, two ping alleys (Nelson et al 1996a). important factors that critically determine the economics of soil conservation are the discount The experience with contour hedgerows rate and farmer perceptions about the size of over the past 20 years suggests that it is a future benefits. potentially beneficial technology that has certain limitations. In spite of the improved basic The discount rate measures the rate at which knowledge about this technology, there is still farmers are willing to trade off future consump­ room for technical and economic analysis to tion for current consumption. Future consump­ develop practices that are more easily adoptable tion is valued less when the discount rate is and adaptable by farmers in a wide range of higher. A poor farmer who is striving to survive socioeconomic and biophysical conditions. is likely to have a very high discount rate and may not be willing to sacrifice current consump­ A microeconomic model of soil tion for future benefits, even though those conservation benefits could potentially be high. On the other Several socioeconomic factorsaffect farmers' hand, farmers who have a lower discount rate decisions to adopt or not adopt a soil conserva­ are more likely to adopt soil conservation tion technology. These factors determine the practices, with other things remaining the same. general socioeconomic milieu in which the farm

4 Personal factors Institutional factors Educa tion

Pcrception of Soil erosion conservation problem effon

Physical factors Economic factors

Slope length Net farm income Discount rate/planning period Slope degree Debt level Risk aversion Soil erodibility Off-farm income Farm type

Fig. 1. Decision-making process for the use of soil conservation practices (Ervin and Ervin 1982).

As benefits accrue in the future, farmer the area and not necessarily to improve yield. As perceptions of the size of the future benefits also a result of the lack of investment, land quality play a critical role in adoption decisions. Infor­ suffers over time until the field is finallyaban­ mational problems about the effect of soil doned and the farmer moves to a new area. management practices on future benefits may During the long fallow period, natural regenera­ lead farmers to substantially underestimate the tion may restore soil productivity enough to size of such benefits. allow recultivation of the field. Incentives for soil conservation under this situation will be The nature of the production system minimal. and soil conservation The characteristics of the production system at When the land frontier is closed, further any time result from an interplay between increases in population provide incentives for farmers' attempts to change it in a particular intensifying agricultural production so that way to meet their goals and the environmental sedentary farmingsystems evolve (type II). factors that determine what is feasible. The three Farmers attempt to be self-sufficient by produc­ major determinants of the nature of the produc­ ing a range of agricultural outputs under a tion system are population density, market subsistence mode of production in the absence access, and agroclimatic conditions (Boserup of markets. As the scope for increasing area is 1965, 1981, Pandey 1996). Figure 2 shows a limited, the only option available is to improve simplified construct based on population density yield per unit area by using more labor and other and market access. When population density is inputs for current production. Labor-intensive low and no outside market demand exists, methods of soil conservation are likely to be returns to labor are maximized by adopting an more appropriate to type II systems. Although extensive land-use strategy, such as shifting investing in soil quality is also a way of improv­ cultivation based on long fallow periods (type I). ing productivity, whether fa1mers will actually The farmers' primary objective in this land do so will depend on several factors that deter­ surplus situation is to allocate labor to expand mine economic incentives. Where such incen­ tives are lacking, soil degradation will continue

5 Market access

Low High

Traditional Perennial or foodcrop Low Subsistence Sustainable?

Sustainable Type I Type III Population density Intensified Diversified

Subsistence Food and cash crops High Sustainable?? Sustainable??

Type II Type IV

Fig. 2. Effect of market access and population pressure on land use and sustainability (Pandey 1996). until migration reduces population pressure or preference for labor-saving methods. If such the area itself is abandoned. techniques are not available or if limited security of tenure restricts the planning horizon, farmers When population density is low but market may allow the land to degrade. access is well developed, plantation-type commercialized production systems will prob­ Intensification, property rights, and ably emerge (type III). Annual or perennial food/ soil conservation fiber or industrial crops predominate depending Extended land use as a means of enhancing on market conditions. On the other hand, sustainability is not an option in densely popu­ commercialized production systems based on lated areas of Asia. Land use needs to be intensi­ food and cash crops are likely to develop when fied to feed the increasing population. Under both population density and market access are what conditions is land-use intensification high (type IV). Such production systems may be compatible with conservation? diversified or specialized depending on a range of conditions. The opportunity to interact with The effectof intensification on soil conser­ the market in these systems can influence soil vation depends on the structure of property conservation decisions in two ways. First, to the rights, the level of development of land and extent that cash crops are more profitable per capital markets, access to technology and unit area than food crops, an increase in cash information, and developments in the nonfarm crop production would increase the marginal sector. Security of tenure is a critical variable value product of the soil and encourage adoption that determines incentives to conserve land of conservation practices. Income from cash quality. If property rights to land are well crops will also help relax liquidity constraints defined and enforceable, farmers will have that may restrict such investments. Second, incentives to conserve the soil because future market access will also increase the opportunity benefits from soil conservation will accrue to cost of labor used for conservation investment. farmers who make the investment. Security of This will make labor-intensive conservation tenure will lengthen the planning horizon or practices more expensive, thus encouraging a lower the effective discount rate. On the other

6 hand, if property rights are ill defined or unen­ or if government policies hinder such a natural forceable, a "mining" strategy based on rapid evolution. When intensification occurs in exhaustion of soil fertility will be adopted. This response to rapid migration to a newly opened kind of mining strategy can be observed mainly area, the natural process of evolution of property in the forest margins, as well as in rapidly rights tends to break down, leading to the commercializing areas with ill-defined property adoption of agricultural practices that are not rights (Fujisaka et al 1986, Cruz and Repetto sustainable. If such areas happen to be sloping 1992). For example, farmers who followed uplands with highly erosive soils, land degrada­ loggers in the uplands of the Philippines grew tion in such societies can be a severe problem. food crops in logged areas for a few years and The adoption of conservation practices can be then abandoned the fields. Because these fields encouraged under such conditions by reducing did not belong to the farmers, they had no the pressure to intensify and by developing an incentive to conserve the productive capacity of appropriate system of property rights. such fields. The existence of well-defined and enforce­ Possession of a legal title to land is not able property rights to land is a necessary but necessary, however, for ensuring the security of not a sufficient condition foradoption. The land tenure (Bromley 1992, Place and Hazell adoption of soil conservation practices depends 1993). Empirical evidence indicates that farmers on the existence of several additional conditions. who do not have legal titles have often invested A poorly developed land market may fail to in soil conservation while others with legal titles internalizeland quality improvements in land have not always done so. In many communities, values, thus discouraging the adoption of the local land recognition system provides the conservation practices. Similarly, a poorly security of tenure that a legal title does not developed capital market may constrain adop­ necessarily provide. The community land tion by limiting funds available for such invest­ recognition system can assign rights to own, use, ments. Soil conservation in the sloping uplands and transfer land in the same way that a legal may be more effective if implemented at the title does, but often at a much lower cost be­ watershed level. Without strong community­ cause of community enforcement. In fact, level enforcement, such effortscould be stymied government attempts to replace the community by the free-rider problem. land recognition system with legal titles that are costly to enforce have often increased the The adoption of conservation practices in insecurity of land tenure in many societies the uplands is also linked to the macro and (Bromley 1992). sectoral policies that determine incentives for different land-use patterns (Cruz and Repetto How do property rights to land evolve as 1992, Coxhead and Jayasuriya 1994). Some land use is intensified? The theory of induced types of land use are soil-eroding while others innovation indicates that when land-use intensity are soil-conserving. For example, soil erosion is low, property rights to land tend to be nonspe­ under perennial crops is minimal because such cific and use-based (Hayami and Ruttan 1985, crops provide a continuous year-round ground Binswanger and Pingali 1987). As land-use cover. On the other hand, the production of intensity increases because of population annual food crops tends to cause more erosion pressure and/or expanded export opportunities, unless remedial measures are undertaken. When property rights become more specific with rights faced with a rising population, limited off-farm to own, use, and transfer. The natural evolution employment opportunities, and limited access to of property rights to land from general to markets, upland farmers may have no alternative specific rights breaks down if intensification but to intensify the production of staple food occurs at a pace faster than the capacity of local using a subsistence mode of production even institutions to adapt to changes in property rights though long-run sustainability is threatened. The

7 history of upland development in the Philip­ Microeconomic evidence from the pines, Vietnam, and Thailand highlights the Philippine uplands effects of macro and sectoral policies on the adoption of conservation practices very well. Study area and sampling design The migration of lowland population to the Claveria and Cebu are the two major sites in the uplands in the Philippines in the 1970s and Philippines where the CH technology was 1980s has been attributed mainly to the stagnant actively promoted in the early 1980s. World productivity of rice in the lowlands, a high rate Neighbors, in collaboration with the DENR, of population growth, and the low absorptive promoted a range of soil conservation practices capacity of the nonfarm sector. This migration, including contour hedgerows. The soil conserva­ coupled with poorly defined property rights in tion technology was a component of the overall the uplands, is considered to be the main factor technology to encourage a shift in production causing soil erosion in the uplands. In addition, systems from food crops to cash crops. Overall, the overvalued exchange rate encouraged the the CH technology spread around the initial production of food crops at the cost of perennial target area and the Cebu case is often cited as a export crops. Similarly, in Vietnam, the govern­ successful example of soil conservation technol­ ment policy of regional food self-sufficiency ogy adoption (Garcia and Gerrits 1995). until the late 1980s was a major factor forthe expansion of area under shifting cultivation and In 1985, IRRI began a farming systems the consequent soil erosion. On the other hand, research project in the acid uplands of Claveria, improved market access through increased Misamis Oriental, in collaboration with the DA. investment in infrastructure in the uplands A contour hedgerow-based farming system was helped diversify upland production systems in promoted using the farmer-to-farmer extension Thailand (Shinawatra 1985). Diversificationand approach based on the strategy used by World market integration not only relaxed the liquidity Neighbors in Cebu (Fujisaka and Garrity 1988). constraints to investment in conservation Sixty-four out of 182 farmers trained had practices faced by upland farmers but also established contour hedgerows by the end of improved their food security with the emergence 1990 (Fujisaka I 993). A subsequent study by of land-use patternsbased on comparative Cenas and Pandey (1996) documented the status advantage. Additionally, rapid growth in the of the CH systems of these farmers in 1995. nonfarm sector helped to siphon offthe excess Although contour hedgerows were considered population from these fragile upland areas and not usefuland subsequently abandoned by about subsequently reduced pressure for intensifica­ 25% of the initial adopters, others modified and/ tion. or maintained their hedgerow structures.

With the right mix of policy and institutional This study focuses on CH technology as a interventions, there is no reason why intensifica­ soil conservation practice. A group of 130 tion cannot be achieved sustainably. The farmers (74 adopters and 56 nonadopters) was Machakos experience is a case in point. Despite selected from Cebu and Claveria, Misamis a fivefold increase in population, Machakos Oriental. Cebu City provides a good market residents were able to increase per capita outlet for commercial produce from the peri­ agricultural output through a correct mix of urban sloping areas. On the other hand, the institutional and technological innovations and market for Claveria products is limited to the improved linkage with the nonfarm economy smaller city of Cagayan de Oro. The population (English et al 1994). Although the Machakos densities in Cebu and Misamis Oriental prov­ experience may not be replicable in many of the inces are 574 and 285 persons km-2, respectively Asian uplands, it highlights the importance of in (NCSO I 997). The study area in Cebu comes various policy and institutional options under Cebu City, which has a population density 2 encouraging the adoption of sustainable prac­ of 2358 persons km· • Thus, in terms of Figure 2, tices.

8 Cebu represents an area with good market hedgerows, adoption of soil conservation access and high population density, whereas practices other than CH, and farmers' percep­ Claveria represents one with low population tions regarding advantages/disadvantages of CH density and somewhat limited market access. was collected. Interviews with key informants including governmentofficials, nongovernment The sampling design used to select farmers organizations, and other governmentagencies was stratified and purposive. Because the study engaged in soil conservation were also con­ aimed to carry out an in-depth analysis of ducted. The farm-level data on production adoption behavior, farmers were divided into systems collected during the survey pertain to two strata-adopters and nonadopters. Adopters the 1995 cropping season. were farmers who have established contour hedgerows in at least one parcel of their farms, Demographic characteristics of who were cultivating and maintaining their respondents contoured parcels, and who had engaged in crop The heads of households who have adopted production during the year before the survey. contour hedgerows are, on average, about 2 yr The sample consisted of 39 adopters and 21 younger than the heads of nonadopting house­ nonadopters from nine barangays (villages) in holds (Table 1). This age patternis similar to Claveria and 35 adopters and 35 nonadopters that observed in Cebu, where the average age of 1 from six barangays in Cebu • To reduce the the heads of adopting households is about 5 yr effect of environmental variations, nonadopters lower than the average age of nonadopters (the were selected from the same barangays and, difference is statistically significant at the 10% where possible, farmers with fields adjacent to level based on the t test). On the other hand, a the CH fields of the adopters were chosen. different age pattern is shown in Claveria, where Given the purposive nature of the sampling the heads of adopting households are about 3 yr design, caution should be exercised in extrapo­ older than the heads of nonadopting households lating the farm and farmer characteristics of the (but the difference is not statistically signifi­ sample farmers to the overall population. cant).

A structured questionnaire was used for the The heads of adopting households also have field interviews. Detailed information on more schooling than those of nonadopting production systems, input use, costs and returns, households. On average, the heads of adopting the nature and extent of adoption of contour households have spent about 2 more years in

Table 1. Selected demographic characteristics of respondents, by adoption status.

Claveria Cebu All Characteristic Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters

Mean age• 45.8 42.9 44_1• 49.7 45.0 47.2 (11.8) (1.0) (12.2) (13.3) (11.9) (12.8)

Mean years in school• 6.8 6.2 5.3 ... 3.0 6.1 *** 4.2 (3.3) (3.6) (2.7) (2.3) (3.1) (3.2)

Mean household size• 6.8 6.5 5.7 6.0 6.3 6.2 (2.9) (2.6) (2.4) (2.4) (2.7) (2.5)

Mean distance of home 0.78 1.07 0.12 0.24 0.47 0.55 from nearest road (km)• (0.93) (1.00) (0.20) (0.49) (0.76) (0.82)

•Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations .... t test for difference in means is statistically significant at the 1 % level.• t test for difference in means is statistically significant at the 10% level. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, i 996.

'Appendix B shows the distribution of sample respondents by barangay in the two surveysites.

9 school than the heads of nonadopting house­ with that of nonadopters (Table 1 ). But these holds (the difference is statistically significant at differencesare not statistically significant. the 1 % level) (Table 1). Across sites, the heads of adopting households in Cebu attend school Membership in the alayon, a local farmers' longer than do the heads of nonadopting house­ group with labor exchange mechanisms, is holds (statistically significant at 1 %). Heads of relatively higher among adopters than adopting households in Claveria also have nonadopters (Table2). Discussions with respon­ slightly more schooling than the heads of dents indicate that membership in the alayon has nonadopting households, but the differenceis helped relax the labor constraint in the construc­ not statistically significant. tion of contour hedgerows. Adopters have also been members of such groups longer than On average, the household size of both nonadopters, on average. adopters and nonadopters is about the same- 6.3 and 6.2, respectively (Table 1). By survey The proportion of households with members site, the nonadopters in Cebu have a slightly who have previous training in soil conservation larger household size than the adopters, on is larger among adopters than among average, while those in Claveria have almost the nonadopters (Table 3). Adopters have also same household size as the adopters, on average. undergone the training much longer than These differences are not statistically signifi­ nonadopters. With more family members trained cant, however. or with knowledge about conservation practices and their benefits to farming, the household will The distance of the house from the nearest more likely adopt a soil conservation practice. road is one indicator of access to market. Adopters have relatively better market access Characteristics of landholding than nonadopters in both Cebu and Claveria, as Adopters operate a slightly greater number of indicated by the shorter average distance of parcels than nonadopters, on average, and this is adopters' houses to the nearest road compared statistically significant at the 10% level based on

Table 2. Membership profile in alayon.

Claveria Cebu All

Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters

Percent share of alayon members 5 0 20 3 12 2

Total number of respondents 39 21 35 35 74 56

Av no. of yr as member of alayon• 1.9 1.3 0.1 1.4 0.1 (1.3) (1.9) (1.7)

•Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996.

Table 3. Respondents and/or their household members with training in soil conservation and duration of training.

Claveria Cebu All

Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters

With training in soil 21 1 21 6 42 7 conservation• (54) (5) (60) (17) (57) (12)

Av no. of wk of training 2.6 0.4 0.6 0.6 1.4 0.6 b undertaken (4.9) (0.8) (0.3) (3.3) (0.3)

•Numbers in parentheses are percent shares of total. •Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996.

10 the t test (Table 4). In terms of total area culti­ 25% for nonadopters. The differenceis statisti­ vated, adopters have a larger farm size than cally significant at the 10% level (Table 4). nonadopters, on average, although this is not Comparison by sites shows that farmsin Cebu statistically significant. Only in Cebu is the have steeper slopes than farms in Claveria, on difference in farmsize statistically significant. average. Adopters at both sites likewise have In Claveria, both the number of parcels operated farms with steeper slopes than those of and total area cultivated are slightly larger for nonadopters, on average, although only in nonadopters than for adopters, on average, Claveria is the differencein slope statistically although the difference is not statistically significant. significant. For parcel size, there is no statisti­ cally significant difference between adopters The incidence of adoption of contour and nonadopters. Across sites, the average hedgerows on parcels owned and not owned is parcel size of farms is relatively larger in an indicator of the relationship between adop­ Claveria than in Cebu. tion and tenure status. Among adopters, about 42% of the parcels with CH are owned, whereas The average slope of land cultivated by about 58% are not owned (Table 5). Across adopters is about 28% compared with about sites, the proportion of owned parcels with CH

Table 4. Selected characteristics of land operated, by adoption status.

Claveria Cebu All Characteristic Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters

Av no. of parcels operated 2.40 2.52 2.86*** 2.02 2.59* 2.21 household·' (1.50) (1.36) (1.33) (0.86) (1.44) (1.09)

Av area operated 2.78 3.50 2.16** 1.28 2.49 2.11 household·' (ha) (3.20) (3.20) (2.19) (1.11) (2.77) (2.38)

Av parcel size(ha) 1.15 1.39 0.76 0.63 0.95 0.95 (1.64) (1.14) (0.86) (0.63) (1.31) (0.96)

°* Slope(%) 24 18 32 31 28* 25 (14) (11) (12) (10) (14) (12)

•Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. ••• t test for the difference between means for adopters and nonadopters is statistically significant at the 1 % level. •• t test for the difference between means for adopters and nonadopters is statistically significant at the 5% level. •t test for the difference between means for adopters and nonadopters is statistically significant at the 10% level. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996.

Table 5. Frequency distribution of parcels according to ownership status and contour hedgerow adoption.•

Claveria Cebu All

Parcel Adopters Non- Adopters Non- Adopters Non- adopters adopters adopters With CH Without CH With CH Without CH With CH Without CH

Owned 37 18 21 23 10 19 60 28 40 (62.7) (51.4) (39.6) (27.7) (58.8) (26.8) (42.3) (53.8) (32.3)

Not owned 22 17 32 60 7 52 82 24 84 (37.3) (48.6) (60.4) (72.3) (41.2) (73.2) (57.7) (46.2) (67.7)

Total 59 35 53 83 17 71 142 52 124 (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0)

Chi-squareb 4.809"" 0.759 5.383""

•Numbers in parentheses are percent shares of total. •The chi-square test was performed for the categories of adopters (combined with and without CH parcels) and nor.adopters.•· Significant at the 5% level. Source of daia: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996.

11 among adopters is larger in Claveria than in nonadopters is smaller than the relative share in Cebu. But the incidence of ownership among the sample. Pure renters have a smaller share nonadopters is relatively lower. Owned parcels among adopters but a larger share among account for only about 32% of the total number nonadopters relative to the sample average. of parcels cultivated by nonadopters. Statistical Thus, while there are relatively more renters tests using the Cochran-Mantel-Haenszel chi­ than owners in the sample, there appear to be square also show a moderately strong positive relatively more owners among adopters than association between ownership of land and among nonadopters. adoption, as indicated by the statistically signifi­ cant chi-square statistic. This positive associa­ Crop production tion holds true in Claveria but not in Cebu. There are two main cropping seasons, the wet season or panuig and the dry season or buklas. Table 6 shows a disaggregation of tenancy The wet season usually starts in May-June and status into three types as observed in the study­ lasts until September-October. The dry season pure owner, pure renter, and both owner and usually begins during October-November and renter. The last type is a respondent who, in lasts until March-April. addition to his or her own land, currenly rents land from other farmers. The proportion of pure Maize is the main crop produced by both owners among adopters is relatively larger than adopters and nonadopters during the wet season the proportion in the sample. On the other hand, (Table 7). Farms planted to rice account for only the relative share of pure owners among about 6% of the total area planted by adopters and less than l % of the total area planted by nonadopters. Comparison by sites shows that Table 6. Distribution of respondents by tenancy status on all parcels operated in 1995, by adoption status. this patternis similar to patternsfound in Claveria and Cebu. These results suggest that Tenancy % share in % share among % share among o status the sample adopters nonadopters wet-season production concentrates on f od crops (maize, rice, and root crops), which are Pure owner 29 34 23 usually intended for consumption. Pure renter 53 46 63 Both owner 18 20 14 and renter Dry-season production shows a different Total 100 100 100 pattern, however. About one-fourthof the total Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996. area cultivated by both adopters and

Table 7. Cropping area by season, crop, and adoption status.

Claveria Cebu All Season/crop Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters

Wet season Maize (% area) 83 92 85 92 84 92 Rice (% area) 7 1 3 1 5 0.8 Root crops (% area) 1 2 2 0 1.5 1.5 Vegetables (% area) 9 5 8 6 9 5.5 Flowers (% area) 0 0 2 1 0.5 0.2 Total area (ha) 52.1 43.2 30.3 20.7 82.4 63.9

Dry season Maize (% area) 75 90 13.2 29.6 52 70 Rice (% area) 6 1.1 4.1 0 6 1 Root crops (% area) 5 0.1 3.1 2.8 4 1 Vegetables (% area) 4 0.2 24 10 11.5 3 Flowers (% area) 0 0 1.6 1.5 0.6 1 Fallow (% area) 10 8.6 54 56 25.9 24 Total area (ha) 52.1 43.2 30.3 20.7 82.4 63.9

Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996.

12 nonadopters is fallowed. Of the remaining area In terms of value of output2 (in US$ ha·'), cultivated, about three-fifths and two-thirds are adopters have a relatively larger output value planted with food crops by adopters and than nonadopters, on average (Table 8). The nonadopters, respectively. There is a relative value of output from CH parcels of adopters is increase in the proportion of area planted to cash also about three times that from their non-CH crops (vegetables and flowers) among adopters parcels, on average. Across sites, adopters in compared with nonadopters. This relative Claveria and Cebu have a relatively larger increase in area planted to cash crops by adopt­ output value than nonadopters, on average. The ers during the dry season is very much apparent differencein the ratio of value of output from in Cebu but not in Claveria. Less than 5% of the parcels with CH compared with those without total area planted by both adopters and CH is lower in Claveria than in Cebu. This nonadopters in Claveria has cash crops. In Cebu, could be explained by the relatively higher on the other hand, the relative share of area incidence of cash cropping in Cebu. planted to cash crops is larger than the relative share of area planted to food crops among Labor inputs per hectare incurred for crop adopters, whereas the relative share of area production in 1995 are higher foradopters than planted to food crops is about twice that of cash for nonadopters, on average, although the crops among nonadopters. difference is not statistically significantbased on the t test (Table 9). Fertilizer application and These differences in cropping patterns harvesting account for the largest share of total across sites could indicate differences in market labor input used by adopters in crop production, opportunities resulting from differences in while nonadopters spend the largest share of access to markets. As previously discussed, labor in weeding operations. The differencein respondents in Cebu appear to have a much the observed labor use could be attributed to better access to markets because of their relative crop choice and cropping intensity-that is, proximity to roads compared with respondents more adopters produce vegetables and flowers, in Claveria. Thus, it appears that the cropping which are not only intrinsically input-intensive pattern of adopters in Cebu is in response to the (require more fertilizer) but also labor-intensive, prevailing market opportunities in the area. particularly during harvesting. Vegetables and Second, by adopting a soil conservation technol­ flowers require more than one harvest compared ogy such as contour hedgerows, adopters appear with, say, maize. Statistical tests indicate that, to have been able to take advantage of these among specific crop production activities, only market opportunities. in fertilizer application is the difference in labor

Table 8. Gross value of output($ ha·' yr·') produced by respondents in 1995.•

Claveria Cebu All

Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters

All parcels 1,226 1,049 4,814 1,884 3,031 1,487 (3,560) (1,487) (21,497) (4,674) (15,510) (3,546)

Parcels with CH 1,676 5,226b 3,775 (4,557) (23,308) (18,186)

Parcels without CH 861 2,038 1,389 (1,280) (5,026) (3,534)

•Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. US$1 = 25. bHigh value of output is due to some respondents engaging in cut-flower and high­ value crop production. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996.

'The heterogeneity of crops produced by respondents necessitated the conversion of yield into monetary terms for consistency. Output was valued at the market price prevailing at the time of harvest.

13 Table 9. Labor inputs for crop production (all crops) by To summarize, adopters show a different respondents in 1995, by adoption status.• cropping patternthan nonadopters. That is, Adopters Nonadopters adopters are more likely to produce food crops Activityb Person-d %of Person-d %of during the wet season and cash crops during the ha·• total ha·• total dry season. In contrast, nonadopters are more Land preparation 62 17 77 22 likely to produce food crops during both the wet (58) (106) and dry seasons. This contrast in cropping

Seeding/planting 32 8 29 8 patternscould be due to the market opportunities (36) (34) open to respondents. The results suggest that, with better market access, adopters are more Weeding 62 17 88 25 (84) (103) likely to take advantage of market opportunities for both cash crops and food crops. Hence, there Fertilizer application 79•• 21 39 11 (125) (57) appear to be more incentives for adopters to adopt a soil conservation measure in order to Pest control 42 11 38 11 (82) (102) maintain soil productivity and enable them to produce more output for sale in the market. The Harvesting 78 21 65 18 (103) (103) differences in crop choice between adopters and nonadopters are also reflected in the difference Postharvest 18 5 20 5 in value of output. Adopters have a larger output (54) (52) value than nonadopters. In terms of labor and Total labor ha·' 373 100 356 100 input costs, adopters used more labor and inputs, (373) (332) particularly fertilizer, in their crop production •Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. "t tests for activities in 1995. Again, these differences may differences in means between adopters and nonadopters were conducted by activity. Level of significance is indicated by asterisks, as reflect differencesin cropping patternswhere shown. •· Significant at the 5% level. adopters are producing more labor-intensive Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996. cash crops than nonadopters. input incurred by adopters vis-a-vis nonadopters statistically significant. In terms of input costs, Income sources and shares adopters have spent about $430 ha· 1 compared Adopters have a relatively larger household with about $130 for nonadopters, or about three income than nonadopters, on average (Table 10). times more for crop production inputs such as Household income is defined as the sum of cash fertilizer, pesticides, and herbicides, on average. income fromlivestock, timber and fruit sales, This difference in input costs is statistically and nonfarm activities and the value of crop significant at the 1 % level. production. Across sites, adopters in Cebu have

Table 10. Household income and percent share of income sources of respondents in 1995, by adoption status.•

Claveria Cebu All

Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters

Household incomeb(US$) 1315 2869 2902 762 2065 1552 (1148) (5683) (6689) (1028) (4708) (3668) % share of crop production 51.0 56.4 31.0 37.2 41.5 44.4 % share of livestock sales 20.4 17.4 22.3 22.9 21.3 20.9 % share of noncrop sales 5.6 4.7 8.8 10.2 7.1 8.1 % share of nonfarm income 23.0 21.4 37.9 29.8 30.0 26.6 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 %share of nonwage income 42 53 62 80 53 71 from nonfarm activitiesb to total nonfarm income

•Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. "Household income is defined as the sum total of gross cash income from nonfarm activities, livestock sales, and sales of noncrop production such as timber and the value of crop production. US$1 = 25. •Nonwage income from nonfarm activities includes remittances, land rent, business income, and other nonfarm income. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996.

14 a relatively larger household income than dents of the presence ( or absence) of soil erosion nonadopters, while the reverse is true in on each of the parcels being cultivated. Claveria, where adopters have a relatively lower household income than nonadopters, on average. The incidence of soil erosion on all parcels cultivated is higher among nonadopters than In terms of sources of income, both adopters among adopters of contour hedgerows. About and nonadopters obtain the largest proportion of four-fifths of all parcels cultivated by income from crop production, accounting for nonadopters are reported to have soil erosion, about one-third of total income, on average. whereas only about two-thirds of all parcels with Nonfarm income comes next, accounting for a CH and one-half of all parcels without CH little more than one-fourth of total income. cultivated by adopters are reported to have soil Nonfarm income consists of off-farmwages, erosion (Table 11). Across sites, the proportion land rent, remittances, and business activities, of parcels reported as eroded is higher among usually trading. Income from the sale of live­ parcels cultivated by nonadopters than among stock is ranked third among income sources. A those cultivated by adopters in Claveria and comparison between sites shows that income Cebu. Statistical tests using the Cochran­ from crop production is the largest source of Mantel-Haenszel chi-square indicate a strong income for both adopters and nonadopters in negative linear association between respondents' Claveria, whereas nonfarm income and income perceptions of soil erosion and adoption of CH from crop production are the major sources of in Cebu and in the combined sample. This income among adopters and nonadopters in implies that the incidence of soil erosion after Cebu, on average. Income from livestock adoption is highly likely among nonadopters in production accounts for about one-fifth of Cebu and in the combined sample. Regression of household income, on average. Among the adoption status on the farmers' perceptions of livestock raised by respondents, cattle account soil erosion on plots cultivated shows a statisti­ for the largest share of sales, with adopters cally significant negative coefficient at the 1 % having a larger value of sales than nonadopters, level, implying that the incidence of soil erosion on average. The main reason for the larger is negatively correlated with adoption of the CH average cattle sales of adopters is that cattle technology. dispersal is part of the adoption incentive package provided by projects that promoted the Among contoured parcels in Claveria, the adoption of contour hedgerows in Cebu and proportion of parcels reported as eroded is Claveria. Noncrop production, consisting of higher than those reported as not eroded and this timber and fruit production, accounts for the could be due to the relative age of the contour lowest share of household income among structures (Table 11 ). The contour structures on adopters and nonadopters, on average. Respon­ parcels reported as not eroded have been con­ dents reveal that the timber and fruits produced structed 3 yr longer, on average, than those on are mostly consumed at home or given as gifts to parcels reported as eroded. This differenceis neighbors and friends, and that only a small statistically significant at the 10% level using proportion of total production is sold. the t test. In Cebu, the proportion of CH parcels reported as eroded is almost the same as the Soil conservation practices proportion of those reported as not eroded. A Incidence of soil erosion and use of soil erosion comparison of erosion incidence among CH control. To get an indication of the incidence of parcels in Cebu and Claveria indicates that the soil erosion on the parcels cultivated, respon­ higher incidence of reported erosion in Claveria dents were asked whether they currently observe could be explained by the length of time that the soil erosion on each of the parcels they cultivate. hedgerows have been in place. The average age Hence, the incidence of soil erosion in this of CH structures among parcels observed with discussion refers to the observation by respon- erosion in Claveria is about half the age of those

15 Table 11. Distribution of parcels cultivated where soil erosion is observed (after adoption of contour hedgerows) by respondents, by adoption status.

Claveria Cebu All

Adopters Non- Adopters Non- Adopters Non- adopters adopters adopters

With CH Without With CH Without With CH Without CH CH CH

Reported by farmers as eroded

No. of parcels• 47 19 42 42 7 60 89 26 102 (79.7) (54.3) (79.2) (50.6) (41.2) (8 4.5) (62.7) (50.0) (82.3)

Av slope0 29 23*** 21··· 32 37-- 15 30 27 17 (13) (11) (9) (12) (7) (133) (12) (12) (102)

Av age of CH0 5• 10 8 (4) (9) (7)

Reported by farmers as not eroded

No. of parcels• 12 16 11 41 10 11 53 26 22 (20.3) (45.7) (20.8) (49.4) (58.8) (15.5) (37.3) (50.0) (17.7)

Av slope0 26 9 7 33 24 26 31 15 16 (11) (14) (9) (12) (15) (10) (12) (16) (14)

Av age of CH0 8 9 9 (4) (6) (6)

Total no. of parcels 59 35 53 83 17 71 142 52 124 (100) (100) (100) (100) (100) (100) (100) (100) (100)

Chi-squarec 1.409 22.517*** 18.373***

•Numbers in parentheses are percent shares of total. •Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. t tests conducted to test for difference in means of slope and difference in mean age of CH of parcels reported as eroded vis-a-vis those reported as not eroded. Levels of significance are indicated with asterisks as shown below. 'Chi-square test conducted for categories of adopters (combined with and without CH parcels) and nonadopters. Levels of significance are indicated with asterisks as shown. •·· Significant at the 1% level.·· Significant at the 5% level. • Significant at the 10% level. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996. in Cebu, such that the soil-conserving effects as the dependent variable. The independent may not yet be clearly visible in the former variables are slope and age of the CH structures. compared with the latter. Interviews with The results indicate that incidence of soil adopters reveal that the terracing effect of CH erosion is negatively associated with age of CH becomes more pronounced after about 5 yr and structures and positively associated with slope, only after that period is a reduction in soil although the estimated coefficients are not erosion on the farm clearly visible. statistically significant.3

Probit analysis determined the effect of Among noncontoured parcels cultivated by slope and age of the CH structures. The probit adopters, slope appears to make a differencein model was estimated with erosion, a dummy the incidence of erosion. Parcels reported as variable having a value of 1 if the respondent eroded have steeper slopes than those reported perceives the parcel as eroded and O otherwise as not eroded, on average, and this slope differ-

'The estimated probit model is: Prob(erosion) = -0.68 + 0.006 • slope - 0.005 • age of CH (0.26) (0.008) (0.008) where the numbers in parentheses are standard errors.

16 ence is statistically significant at the 1% and 5% CH in Cebu than in Claveria (as reflected in the level in Claveria and Cebu, respectively. average age of the CH structures).

Adoption of contour hedgerow technology. On average, a total of about 547 m of The average parcel size with contour hedgerows contour hedgerows have been established by is 0.8 ha for all adopters (Table 12). Adopters in each adopter on his/her parcel (Table 12). This Claveria have a larger average parcel size than is equivalent to an average of about 1,282 m of 1 adopters in Cebu (1.26 ha vs 0.49 ha). This CH ha- • Across sites, the average length of CH result indicates the relative scarcity of cultivable ha- 1 is slightly longer in Cebu than in Claveria. land in Cebu compared with Claveria; it is a function of the differences in population density Contour hedgerows are constructed on about between the two sites. three-fourths of the total area operated by all respondents, on average. Across sites, the extent The average slope of parcels with CH is of adoption is higher in Cebu than in Claveria about 30% (Table 12). Parcels in Cebu have (Table 13). The proportion of full adopters, or relatively steeper slopes than those in Claveria, adopters who have constructed CH on 100% of on average. Despite this physical condition that their farm, is also higher in Cebu than in is highly conducive to soil erosion, there is, as Claveria. A larger proportion of adopters in discussed earlier, a lower incidence of soil Claveria than in Cebu, on the other hand, have erosion among adopters in Cebu. This could be constructed CH on less than half of their farm. explained by the longer history of adoption of The much smaller average farm size in Cebu than in Claveria may explain why adopters in

Table 12. Selected characteristics of contour hedgerow the former are able to construct CH on a larger establishments, by site.• proportion of their farm relative to the latter.

Characteristic Claveria Cebu All (n=39) (n=35) (n=74) Construction and maintenance of contour hedgerows: NVS vs. non-NVS. Natural grasses Av parcel size (ha) 1.26 0.49 0.80 (5.44) (0.66) (3.50) are the predominant hedgerow species in the survey area (Table 14). This is followed by Av no. of parcels 1.4 2.3 1.8 adopter' (0.6) (1.1) (1.0) napier grass, with a larger share in Cebu than in Claveria. The relative popularity of napier grass Av total area 1.60 1.62 1.61 in Cebu may be attributed to its limited grazing adopter' (ha) (0.62) (1.58) (1.37) area such that napier grass hedgerows have Av slope(%) 25.6 32.5 29.7 (6.5) (12.0) (10.6) Table 13. The extent of adoption of contour hedgerows. Av width of alley (m) 7.5 7.0 7.2 (4.4) (5.1) (4.8) Extent of adoption Claveria Cebu All Av height of hedgerow 0.7 0.9 0.8 Percent share of contour riser (m) (0.6) (0.3) (0.5) hedgerow area to total area 69.4 86.8 77.6 operated by adopters• (33.0) (23.2) (30.0) Av width of 1.3 1.2 1.3 hedgerow (m) (0.9) (0.4) (0.6) Percent share of full adopters0 46.2 62.8 54.0 Av total length of 671.8 461.3 546.5 Percent share of partial adopters hedgerows parcel·' (m (1135.9) (454.0) (805.6) ) At least 50% but <100%' 25.6 28.6 27.0 Less than 50%" 28.2 8.6 19.0 Av length of CH 1273.6 1288.2 1282.3 ha- 1 contoured (m) (805.9) (914.3) (868.9) •Av share for all adopters. Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. •Adopters who have established contour hedgerows on Av years of practice 5.4 9.8 8.1 100% of their farm. 'Adopters who have established contour of the technology (3.2) (8.1) (6.9) hedgerows on at least half but less than all of their farm. "Adopters who have established contour hedgerows on less than half of their •Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. farm. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996.

17 Table 14. Percent shares of parcels, by type of hedgerow shift in hedgerow systems are the natural species. domination of grasses and the high mortality of Species Claveria Cebu All the planted species. Natural grass 47.1 44.8 45.8 Napier grass 18.9 37.2 29.9 The activities involved in establishing Gliricidia sepium 9.4 6.4 7.6 Setaria sp. 9.4 2.6 5.3 contour hedgerows include constructing the A Leucaena leucocephala 5.1 3.0 frame, layouting, plowing of the portion already Others• 15.2 3.9 8.4 laid out, shoveling of soil to create bunds, •Includes gmelina, guinea grass, banana, mulberry, pineapple, and hauling of planting materials (if necessary), and ferns. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996. planting or seeding of hedgerow species. On average, it requires about 12 person-ct ha·1 to become more valuable as fodder. Other major construct hedgerows with NVS, while it requires hedgerow species are G. sepium, Setaria sp., and about 55 person-ctha· 1 to construct hedgerows L. leucocephala. There has also been an ob­ with planted species (Table 16). The large served shift of hedgerow systems from non­ difference in labor requirement is due to the natural vegetative strips (non-NVS) to NVS relatively larger share of labor for shoveling the (Table 15). While many of those who started soil to form contour bunds in the non-NVS with non-NVS systems have continued to use hedgerow system. The non-NVS system also them, about one-third have shifted to the NVS requires more labor to do a field layout. Addi­ system. A larger proportion of those who tional labor is also used to haul planting materi­ changed from non-NVS to NVS systems are als as well as to plant the hedgerow species. from Cebu. Among the reasons cited for the Maintenance activities include application Table 15. Temporal patterns of adoption of contour of fertilizer on hedgerow species (if necessary); hedgerow species (% of parcels). weeding, pruning, and replanting of hedgerows; Category Claveria Cebu All and repair of destroyed gullies. While there is a large differencein labor use for construction Remain with NVS• 7.7 8.6 8.1 Change from non-NVS to NVS 23.1 48.6 35.1 between NVS and non-NVS hedgerows, the Remain with non-NVS 69.2 42.8 56.8 maintenance activities require approximately the same amount of labor, on average, for the two •NVS = natural vegetative strips. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996. systems. The largest share in total labor needed

Table 16. Average labor use per hectare for construction and maintenance of contour hedgerows, by type of hedgerow.•

Natural vegetative strips Planted species0 All Activity (person-d ha·') (person-d ha-') (person-d ha·')

Construction 12.4 55.1 48.9 (13.9) (63.7) (58.9)

A-frame construction 0.0 0.5 Layouting 1.6 9.5 Plowing 10.1 8.1 Shoveling 0.7 22.5 Hauling of planting materials 5.3 Seeding/planting 9.2

Maintenance 13.2 13.5 13.5 (13.9) (13.8) (13.7)

Fertilizer application 0.1 Pruning and weeding 13.1 10.7 Replanting 0.9 Gully repair 0.1 1.8

•Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. •includes leguminous species, forage grasses, and perennial species. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996.

18 to maintain contour hedgerows in both systems A ranking of soil conservation practices is accounted for by the weeding and pruning according to the proportion of respondents using activities that are needed to prevent shading of them indicates that among adopters, the three the crops by the overgrown hedgerow species. most widely used practices in addition to CH are contour plowing, returningof crop residues to The large amount of labor needed to con­ the farm, and the use of animal manure as struct and maintain contour hedgerows is cited fertilizer (Table 17). Among nonadopters, the as one of the major constraints to adoption of top three practices are returning of crop resi­ the technology by respondents in the survey. The dues, contour plowing, and crop-fallow rotation. results indeed suggest a large investment in labor to construct and maintain the structures. In summary, soil erosion is more likely to be observed among non-CH parcels than among Other soil conservation practices. Both CH parcels. Likewise, the incidence of soil adopters and nonadopters of the CH technology erosion is higher among parcels cultivated by have also adopted other soil conservation nonadopters than among those cultivated by practices in addition to CH such as contour adopters. This suggests that after the adoption of plowing, mulching, strip cropping, returningof the CH technology, soil erosion is perceived to crop residues to the cultivated farm, use of have been reduced. This perception is particu­ organic matter/animal manure as fertilizers, larly apparent among respondents who have crop-fallow rotation, and construction of diver­ practiced the technology much longer. Natural sion canals. grasses are the predominant hedgerow species observed in the survey area, perhaps because of

Table 17. Distribution of respondents by other soil conservation practices• observed on all parcels, by adoption status.b

Claveria Cebu All (n=54)c (n=70) (n=124) Practice Adopters Non-adopters Adopters Non-adopters Adopters Non-adopters of CH of CH of CH of CH of CH of CH

Contour plowing 33 16 39 24 72 40 (100) (76) (98) (80) (99) (78)

Mulching 18 8 24 6 42 14 (55) (38) (60) (20) (58) (27)

Strip cropping 12 5 26 12 38 17 (36) (24) (65) (40) (52) (33)

Returning crop residues 30 19 39 25 69 44 (91) (90) (98) (83) (95) (86)

Use of organic matter 27 10 22 6 49 16 (82) (48) (55) (20) (67) (31)

Use of animal manure 27 13 23 3 50 16 (82) (62) (58) (10) (68) (31)

Crop-fallow rotation 17 11 29 24 46 35 (52) (52) (72) (80) (63) (69)

Construction of diversion canals 14 9 23 10 33 19 (42) (43) (58) (33) (51) (37)

•These are practices other than contour hedgerows practiced by adopters and nonadopters of contour hedgerows on all of their parcels. Hence, adopters and nonadopters as used in this table refer to those with and without contour hedgerows as was consistently defined throughout this paper. "Numbersin parentheses are percent share of total. 'No.of observationsis less than the sample size because of missing values. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996.

19 their cost advantage. It requires less labor to Table 19. Adopters' perceptions of problems with contour hedgerows. construct natural grass-based hedgerows than Percent share those with planted species. The extent of Problem of responses adoption of contour hedgerows is much higher in Cebu than in Claveria. Other types of soil None 50 Labor intensive (establishment 35 conservation practices are also used by both and maintenance) adopters and nonadopters of CH. Increased labor time for plowing 3 Stray animal destroying hedgerows 4 Shading of crops 2 Farmers' perceptions about contour Persistence of soil erosion 2 hedgerow technology Others 3 No response 1 The most commonly cited benefit fromthe adoption of contour hedgerows is the minimal Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996. Data for Cebu and Claveria combined. soil erosion on the fields (Table 18), whereas improvement in soil fertility ranks second. It is surprising that only a few adopters consider the most distinguishing characteristic (Table 20). yield increase as a major benefit from adoption. This suggests that membership in the organiza­ This suggests that yield gain is probably not tion may have helped relax the labor constraint very high and is confounded by other factors. If for this group. Further research is needed to farmers do not perceive yield gain to be a major identify precisely the factors that may have led advantage, the idea of soil conservation may be to the differentperceptions. promoted more effectivelyby emphasizing only the benefits that farmers perceive easily. The labor-intensive nature of the technology also appears to be a major constraint to adop­ While half of the respondents say that they tion. About one-third of the nonadopters cite the have no major problems with contour high labor requirement as the major reason for hedgerows, about one-third consider the high labor requirement4 for construction and mainte­ Table 20. Characteristics of adopters who perceived/ nance of structures a major concern(Table 19). did not perceive problems with contour hedgerows. Other problems cited include the increase in Characteristic Without With labor time for land preparation, the destruction problem problem of hedgerows by stray animals, the shading of Farmer crops by hedgerows, and the persistence of soil Av age(yr) 45.4 44.6 Av schooling(yr) 5.8 6.5 erosion despite the presence of hedgerows. For Av gross income those who indicated no problem with the tech­ ($ household·')• 1619 1820 Land-labor ratio 2.3 2.8 nology, membership in the alayon appears to be No. of yr of adoption 8.7 7.1 With membership in alayon(%) 20.5 5.7

Table 18. Adopters' perceptions of the benefits from Farm contour hedgerows. Av slope(%) 29.8 29.6 Av no. of parcels 2.7 2.5 Percent share Benefit of responses Type of contour hedgerow(%)b Natural grass 39.5 50.6 Minimize soil erosion 53 Napier grass 26.3 29.2 Improve soil fertility 16 Gliricidia sepium 15.8 4.5 Increase yield 11 Setaria sp. 5.3 5.6 Source of fodder 8 Gmelina 5.3 Easier land preparation because alley is flat 5 Othersc 7.8 10.1 Minimize damage to crops 4 Others 2 •Exchange rate: US$1 = P25. •Percentage of parcels with contour No response 1 hedgerows. "Includes Leucaena leucocephala, guinea grass, banana, pineapple, mulberry, and ferns. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996. Data for Cebu and Claveria combined. Data for Cebu and Claveria combined.

'On average, it requires 49 person-d ha·' to construct and 14 person-d ha·' to maintain contour hedgerows (see Table 16).

20 nonadoption (Table 21 ). Lack of technical were available. These results indicate that more knowledge about the technology and loss of farmersmay be encouraged to adopt the technol­ cultivable area are cited as the major reasons for ogy by making technical knowledge and assis­ nonadoption by about one-fourthof the respon­ tance easily available to more farmers. This can dents. Others mentioned difficultyin land be achieved by strengthening the labor-sharing preparation in the presence of hedgerows, groups and by promoting activities that could nonownership of the land, and lack of capital to generate added income to farmers. finance the growing of hedgerows. Only a small proportion of the respondents said that they did The most widely cited erosion-related not adopt the technology because soil erosion is problem that many nonadopters experience on not a problem in their fields. their farmsis the destruction of crops and loss of seedlings and inputs (Table 23). The formation The provision of technical assistance and of gullies due to erosion is also causing prob­ training about contour hedgerows would encour­ lems on the farms of 16% of the nonadopters. age about one-third of the nonadopters to adopt No farmer mentioned reduction in yield as a the technology (Table 22). On the other hand, major problem caused by soil erosion. It thus one-fifth of the nonadopters would be encour­ appears that the physical manifestationsof aged to adopt the technology if labor and capital erosion are the most perceptible erosion-related problems from the farmers' point of view. It is

Table 21. Reasons given by nonadopters for not also interesting to note that about one-fifth of adopting contour hedgerows. the nonadopters indicate no erosion-related problems on their farms. Reason Percent share of responses Nonadopters attempt to address the erosion­ Needs too much labor 38 Lack of technical knowledge 16 related problems on their farms through the Loss of cultivable area 11 construction of diversion canals (23%), contour Land preparation difficult in the presence of 5 plowing (23%), and application of more fertiliz­ contour hedgerows Soil erosion not a problem in the field 5 ers (16%) (Table 24). Others place barriers Nonownership of land 5 along the slope to minimize further erosion of Lack of capital 2 Others• 14 the soil (6%), while others simply leave the land No response 4 fallow (6%). The responses also indicate that

•Includes seven different reasons with equal number of responses for farmers use practices other than contour each. hedgerows that may be cheaper or more suitable Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996. Data for Cebu and Claveria combined. to the specific conditions of their fields. Hence, CH need not be viewed as the universal solution Table 22. Factors that would encourage adoption by to the land degradation problems of upland nonadopters. farmers, but rather as one of the available Factor Percent share of responses Table 23. Erosion-related problems encountered by nonadopters on their farms. Technical assistance/training 34 Labor and capital availability 20 A range of hedgerow species Problem Percent share of to choose from 11 responses Evidence of loss and loss of fertility 5 Destruction of crops/erosion of Ownership of land 5 seedlings and inputs 53 No need to adopt contour hedgerow Formation of gullies 16 as soil erosion is not a problem 14 Costly land preparation because Others• 7 of exposure of hard soil 4 No response 4 Others 2 No problems 21 "Includes four different reasons with equal number of responses for No response 4 each. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996. Data for Cebu and Claveria combined. Data for Cebu and Claveria combined.

. 21 Table 24. Actions taken by nonadopters to address well as relaxing capital and labor constraints to erosion-related problems on their farms. adoption would encourage nonadopters to try the Action taken Percent share of technology. responses

Diversion/drainage canal 23 Access to services and institutions to divertwater flow Both adopters and nonadopters have access to Contour plowing 23 Application of more fertilizer 16 various services and institutions, with adopters Fallowing the land 6 accounting for a larger proportion of respon­ Placing barriers such as stone/ 6 wood along the slope dents with access to these services than Others• 13 nonadopters overall (Table 25). In terms of No response 13 access to public transport, a larger proportion of •Includes four different actions with equal frequency. adopters than nonadopters have access and this Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996. Data for Cebu and Claveria combined. pattern holdstrue across sites. This relative differencein access to public transport and subsequently to markets may be associated with options. A wider range of technologies needs to the likelihood of adoption of a soil conservation be developed and promoted to give farmers technology. The results indicate that more more flexibility in choosing the most suitable adopters than nonadopters have access to practice, given their specificbiophysical and institutions, suggesting that the adopters' access socioeconomic conditions. may have been a factor in their adoption of the soil conservation technology. On the other hand, To summarize, the major benefitfrom the lack of access of nonadopters to these contour hedgerows as perceived by the respon­ services also puts them at a disadvantage in dents is the reduction in soil erosion. Although gaining access to information about new tech­ this may ultimately contribute to yield increase, nologies and more efficient farming methods. only a few farmers mentioned this as a benefit. The relatively distant locations of nonadopters' The high labor requirement for the construction homesteads from roads relative to those of and maintenance of the hedgerow structure is adopters (as previously discussed), however, perceived to be the major constraint to adoption. may also explain the lack of access to these Providing technical assistance and training as institutions.

Table 25. Distribution of respondents by access to services and institutions, by adoption status.•

Claveria Cebu All Type of access Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters Adopters Nonadopters

To public transportation 39 19 32 25 71 44 (100) (90) (91) (71) (96) (79)

To government agencies/workers 27 9 30 17 57 26 (69) (43) (86) (49) (77) (46)

To extension centers/workers 27 11 30 29 57 40 (69) (52) (86) (83) (77) (71)

To institutions engaged in soil conservation 24 10 22 15 46 25 (62) (48) (63) (43) (62) (45)

To credit 33 15 28 29 61 44 (85) (71) (80) (83) (82) (79)

Total no. of respondents 39 21 35 35 74 56

•Numbers in parentheses are percent share of total. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996.

22 The incidence of access to institutions Econometric analysis engaged in soil conservation among all respon­ Econometric analysis was done to determine the dents is relatively lower than access to govern­ factors that affectthe adoption decision of ment agencies and extension centers. As in the upland farming as well as to estimate the previous two institutions, however a larger productivity effectsof adoption on farmproduc­ proportion of adopters than nonadopters have tion. access to institutions engaged in soil conserva­ tion. In Claveria, the institution currently Factors affecting the adoption decision engaged in promoting soil conservation tech­ Adoption of soil conservation: a conceptual nologies, particularly CH technology, is the model. The adoption of soil conservation International Center for Research on practices is conceptualized as a decision-making Agroforestry (ICRAF). In Cebu, the DA has a process (Fig. I; Ervin and Ervin 1982), which Resource Management Training Center located starts with the recognition of an erosion prob­ in Barangay Taptap, one of the mountain lem. That perception is viewed as a product of barangays in the city. This training center is farmers' personal characteristics that might engaged in providing technical assistance and cause a more acute awareness of the seriousness training on sustainable farrning systems and one of erosion (e.g., forrnaleducation), coupled with of the technologies promoted is the use of the actual physical characteristics of the land contour hedgerows as a soil conservation that they cultivate. measure. The NGO World Neighbors also has a training center that provides technical assistance Once the erosion problem is perceived, and training on soil conservation technologies, farmers decide whether or not to adopt a conser­ including CH establishment, to its members. vation practice and, if so, what type. The different factor categories are modeled to play A larger proportion of adopters than separate roles in that decision. Personal factors, nonadopters have access to credit. Comparing such as more education, can be viewed as access among respondents across sites shows influencing farmers' disposition to use practices that a slightly larger proportion of nonadopters because of increased information on benefits than adopters in Cebu have access, while a and costs of erosion control. Those personal slightly larger proportion of adopters than characteristics that involve acquisition costs can nonadopters have access in Claveria. Credit be interpreted as human capital. The degree of sources to which respondents have access soil erosion potential of the land is an important include forrnal sources such as rural banks, biophysical factor that influences adoption. development banks, and private financing Economic factors may either enhance or con­ companies and inforrnalsources such as farrn­ strain farmers' disposition toward soil conserva­ ers' cooperatives, traders, private business tion, whereas educational programs and techni­ corporations, moneylenders, family members, cal assistance are institutional instruments to and friends. The results suggest that credit does encourage farmers to use the practice. appear to be accessible to respondents in Claveria and Cebu, although adopters may have The final step is the determination of soil relatively better access than nonadopters. conservation effort,which is a function of the Interviews with respondents also revealed that, effectivenessand coverage of individual prac­ although credit may be accessible, risk aversion tices over the land. Personal factors such as prevented several from actually obtaining credit management ability affect the proper application for use in their farrnoperations. Respondents and maintenance of practices, especially on revealed that the uncertainty inherent in crop widely varying topography and soils. Physical production causes them to be more risk-averse factors that define soil erosion potential deter­ about borrowing as the possibility of a crop mine potential productivity benefits over the failure may result in their inability to pay back entire farm unit. The conservation effort is also the loan.

23 hypothesized to depend heavily on economic entails a training component that benefits factors because of the relationship between the farmer-members. Indeed, Sajise and Ganapin cost of practicing a particular type of soil ( 1991) contend that the presence of mechanisms conservation and the degree to which it reduces for group labor is a factor that contributes to the soil erosion. increase in adoption of conservation measures. In the case of CH adoption, the availability of From the conceptual model above, several exchange labor in alayon groups could relax variables are hypothesized to affect farmers' labor constraints in the construction of CH decisions to adopt a soil conservation technol­ structures. In a study of CH adoption in Leyte, ogy. These variables are classified into four Philippines, Gabunada and Barker (1995) indeed categories-personal, economic, institutional, found that membership in the alayon group had and biophysical (or the degree of soil erosion a significant positive effecton the probability of potential). The following paragraphs discuss adoption. specific variables and their hypothesized effects on the adoption decision of farmers. Land-labor ratio, measured as the ratio of the area operated to the number of family The effectof farmer age on the adoption members engaged in farming on a full-time decision can be taken as a composite of the basis, is used as an indicator of population effects of farming experience and planning pressure. Households with a lower land-labor horizons. While more farming experience as ratio may have incentives to invest in soil equated with older farmers is expected to have a conservation forcrop intensification. On the positive effecton adoption, younger farmers, on other hand, the potential loss of land to CH may the other hand, may have longer planning discourage them from adoption. Contour horizons (i.e., a lower discount rate) and may be hedgerows occupy nearly 20% of the land more likely to invest in a conservation technol­ (Cenas and Pandey I 996), resulting in reduced ogy. Hence, the effect of age on adoption cannot cropping area. For households with more land be determined a priori. Hoover and Wiitala per unit of labor, this potential loss of land and ( 1980) found in their study of Nebraska farmers subsequent reduction in cropping area may be that age had a significant negative influence on less of a constraint relative to those with little farmers' adoption decisions. land. Hence, households with a higher land­ labor ratio may also adopt CH. The effectof Higher education levels should be associ­ land-labor ratio on adoption is therefore indeter­ ated with greater information on conservation minate a priori. measures and the productivity consequences of erosion, and higher management expertise The effect of insecure tenure status often (Ervin and Ervin 1982, Hoover and Wiitala discourages farmersfrom engaging in conserva­ 1980). As a human capital variable, education tion practices that have longer time periods also positively affectedthe efficiencyof farm­ because they may not be able to reap the long­ ers' adoption decisions (Rahm and Huffman run benefits (Ervin 1986). Equating land titles 1984). Hence, adoption is hypothesized to be with secure tenure and thus with increased positively correlated with farmers' education investment, however, is too simplistic (Lutz et al level. 1994). In fact, ownership may not be as signifi­ cant a factorin soil conservation decisions as is Membership in a local farmers' organization sometimes thought, as suggested by the findings is posited to have a positive effecton the adop­ of studies on conservation practices by farmers tion of a soil conservation technology. Commu­ in Central America (Lutz et al 1994) and in the nity or farmer organizations are effectivein Philippines (USAID 1995). Place and Hazell providing follow-up support (USAID 1995) to (1993) also found that legal land rights were not farmer-members. Membership in such organiza­ significant determinants in African farmers' tions not only provides additional labor but also decisions to undertake land-improving invest-

24 ments. These results suggest that, while land level of nonfarm income would be largely ownership is an enabling factor for conservation, exogenous to the adoption decision. it is not a sufficient condition. The slope of the field is the only indicator The distance of the homestead to the nearest used as a proxy for erosion potential. Although road, as a proxy for market access, may capture erosion potential depends on rainfall pattern, the effect of several variables. Access to markets soil physical characteristics, and slope in a provides farmers with opportunities for income­ complex way, the nature of the data collected earning activities. Thus, there is more incentive does not permit the inclusion of factors other for farmers to ensure that farm productivity is than slope. In addition, rainfall patternsand soil improved or at least maintained in order to take physical characteristics may not vary much from advantage of market opportunities. Farmers who field to field within a location. can potentially generate good returnsfrom the production and sale of crops that are highly Empirical results. A microeconometric demanded in the market may therefore find soil framework based on the concept of utility conservation economically attractive (Clarke maximization is used to empirically explain 1992). Several farmers mentioned during the farmers' decisions to adopt a soil conservation interviews that soil conservation is important for technology. The underlying theoretical basis for realizing high levels of profits from cash crop­ the approach is that a net positive benefit results ping. In addition to this effect, farmers who live in a higher utility level forfarmers. Hence, the near the road are more likely to be visited by probability that a farmer will adopt a soil extension agents than ones who live far from the conservation practice is the probability that the road. The cost of gaining access to technical utility of the old technology is less than the knowledge and information will be lower for utility of the new soil-conserving technology farmers living close to the road. The anticipated (see, for example, Rahm and Huffman 1984). effect of this variable is therefore positive. This can be estimated using the probit model (Maddala 1983, Greene 1997)5. For the empiri­ To the extent that liquidity is a constraint to cal model, the probability that a farmer will adoption, nonfarmincome will have a positive adopt the CH technology is estimated as a effect on adoption by relaxing this constraint. function of farm, farmer, and market characteris­ The level of nonfarm income may, however, not tics. be exogenous but may be affected by the profit­ ability of farming operations, which, in tum, Two separate probit equations were esti­ depends on the conservation decision. Thus, mated using parcel-level data6 for each site after adoption of conservation practices and the level an F test conducted on the data set turned out to of non farm income may be determined simulta­ be significant for the null hypothesis of no neously. The simultaneity arises from labor structural differencebetween the data fromthe allocation decisions of the households forfarm two sites. A test for multicollinearity among the and nonfarm activities. The nonfarmincome of independent variables did not show statistically the households surveyed, however, is mostly significant collinear relationships among the derived from remittances of family members variables. Table 26 shows descriptive statistics working overseas, nonfarm business activities, of the independent variables. Table 27 shows the and employment in the nonfarm sector. As skill results of the probit model estimation. requirements for these jobs are likely to be different from those for farming, farm and Adoption in Claveria is significantly influ­ nonfarrn employment may be considered as enced by tenure status, slope, and age of the noncompetitive activities. In this situation, the household head. The results suggest that adop-

'The underlying assumption is that the error term e is independently, normally distributed with zero mean and constant variance cf. •oata from 318 parcels from the 130 sample respondents were used in estimating the probit model.

25 Table 26. Descriptive statistics of the independent Table 27. Estimated coefficients of the probit model.• variables used in the probit model.• Claveria Cebu Variable Claveria Cebu Variable Coefficient Chi- Coefficient Chi- Age of household head (yr) 46.5 48.2 square square (11.0) (13.5) Constant 0.52 0.40 -1.78 7_44··· Education (yr) 7.1 4.4 Age of household head -0.03 5.85.. 0.007 0.60 (3.4) (2.7) Education -0.03 0.70 0.17 14.02··· Tenure (dummy)• 1.02 12.22··· -0.31 1.56 < Land-labor ratio 0.2 0.1 Member (dummy) 0.34 0.18 0.84 4.82·· 2.25 0.10 0.02 (0.2) (0.1) Land-labor ratio -0.94 Slope 0.05 19_34··· 0.02 4.95.. Slope(%) 21.9 31.3 Nonfarm income -0.005 2.32 0.005 2.61 (13.3) (11.5) Distance from road -0.10 0.47 -0.94 5_14·· °00 Distance from road (km) 0.8 0.2 -2 Log likelihood ratio 165.51"'" 192.54 (1.0) (0.4) Probability of adoption 0.46 0.51

Nonfarm income• 35.3 48.8 •*.. Significant at the 1 % level. **Significant at the 5% level. (35.2) "Significant at the 10% level. b1 for owner, O otherwise. '1 for alayon (33.4) member, 0 otherwise. Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland fam1ers, 1996. Tenure< 52 30

d Member 3 12 significant in Claveria. The importance of labor exchange groups in relaxing labor constraints in •Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. "Percentshare of nonfam, income to total household income. 'Percent share of parcels the construction of contour hedgerows was cultivated by owners. "Percent share of parcels cultivated by alayon members. highlighted by the respondents' answers to Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland fam1ers, 1996. questions about constraints to adoption. High labor requirements for the establishment and tion of contour hedgerows is more likely among maintenance of CH was the most often cited households headed by younger farmers, on constraint to adoption among the respondents parcels with a steeper slope, and on parcels surveyed. The weak statistical performance of owned by the farmer.The likelihood of adoption the membership variable in Claveria could be in Claveria is estimated at 46% on average, and because, after adoption, very few farmer­ this is statistically significant at the 1 % level. adopters remained as members of the group. Discussions with farmer-respondents indicate For Cebu, adoption is significantly influ­ that the alayon movement has remained stronger enced by education, membership in the alayon, in Cebu than in Claveria, and this could be slope, and distance of the farmer's house from because the institutional organization among the the road. The results indicate that education is alayon groups is better in Cebu than in Claveria. also a positive influence on adoption, and this is consistent with the results of Ervin and Ervin The results also highlight the differencesin (1982) and Rahm and Huffman (1984). Like­ factors that affectadoption across sites. For wise, adoption is more likely among farmers example, tenure status was significant only in who are members of the alayon group and who Claveria, perhaps because of the larger propor­ live close to the road. Contour hedgerows are tion of owned parcels with contour hedgerows also more likely to be adopted on parcels with than parcels without contour hedgerows. In steeper slopes. The likelihood of adoption in Cebu, on the other hand, a larger proportion of Cebu is estimated at 51 % on average and is parcels with contour hedgerows were being statistically significant at the 1 % level. cultivated by nonowners than parcels owned by their cultivators. These results suggest that, The dummy variable for membership in the although security of tenure in the form of a legal alayon has a positive sign at both sites, implying title is an important decision variable in the that members are more likely to adopt than adoption of CH, the effect could be site-specific. nonmembers, although it was not statistically In Cebu, adoption was observed to be high

26 among parcels operated by nonowners but who Table 28. Estimated elasticities of the probability of adoption (continuous variables only).• have assured long-term access to the land from their absentee landlords. Nevertheless, there is Variable Claveria Cebu merit to promoting policies aimed at making Age of household head -0.82 0.34 property rights more favorable to adoption. Education -0.12 0.38 Land-labor ratio -0.12 0.01 Slope 0.64 0.32 Institutional variables such as access to Nonfarm income -0.10 0.12 extension and credit were not included in the Distance from road -0.05 -0.08 final model estimates because of collinearity and •Elasticities area computed as Px<1>(xl})/(xl}) where is the probability density function and is the cumulative density function (Marquis and simultaneity problems. The variable that mea­ Phelps 1987). sures access to extension is correlated with the proxy variable for market access, i.e., the younger farmers. Adoption could also be distance of the farmer's house from the road; intensified with improved access to markets hence, the latter is likely to capture the effect of through better roads and transport facilities. the former on adoption. Discussions with farmer-respondents revealed that, although they Although the probit estimates determine the indicated that they have access to extension factors that affect the likelihood of adoption, services, only a fewof them actually get regular they do not indicate the factors that determine extension visits fromextension agents assigned the extent of adoption (McDonald and Moffitt to their respective areas. Moreover, among those 1980). Hence, tobit estimates for each site are who have relatively better access and more derived to address this issue, taking as the frequent contacts with extension agents, many dependent variable the proportion of contoured are adopters, and this could be because adopters area to total farm size. Table 29 shows the tobit live closer to the main road than nonadopters. estimates. The credit variable, on the other hand, is endog­ enous because the ability to obtain credit is also The extent of adoption in Claveria is signifi­ determined by factors that are determinants of cantly determined by slope. The results indicate adoption--e.g., education, income, and access to that farms with slopes less than 15 % are less markets, among others. Although credit was likely to increase their extent of adoption than reported to be accessible to the farmer-respon­ farms with slopes greater than 30%. Hence, dents, many of them appeared to be risk-averse farms with steeper slopes are more likely to have and hence did not obtain credit for production purposes. Table 29. Estimated coefficients of the tobit model.

Claveria Cebu Table 28 shows the estimated elasticities of Variable Coefficient Chi- Coefficient Chi- the probability of adoption. The elasticity square square estimates suggest that the probability of adop­ tion is more responsive to slope, education, and Constant 0.63 0.31 -0.06 0.003 Age of household -0.02 1.19 age variables than to the other significant head variables. This suggests that policy interventions Education -0.10 0.55 0.15 3.77** Household size -0.03 0.04 -0.05 0.59 aimed at improving the educational status of Member (dummy)• - 0.97 4.79** upland farmers may also encourage soil conser­ Tenureb 0.55 0.92 -0.13 0.07 Slope 1c -3.33 3.10* 1.08 1.36 vation in the uplands, particularly in Cebu, Slope 2d -0.05 0.01 -0.38 0.94 where the education variable was statistically Nonfarm income 1.10E-4 1.39 2.75E-5 6.01** significant. Indeed, farmer responses indicated Distance from road 0.25 0.69 -0.20 0.30 that providing technical assistance and training -2 Log likelihood 42.82 75.00 to nonadopters would encourage them to adopt •1 for alayon member, O otherwise . 'Definedas the proportion of contour hedgerows. Moreover, conservation owned land to total farm size. 'Defined as the proportion of land with slope <15%. dDefined as the proportion of land with slope between programs would be more effective if targeted to 15%and 30%. areas with relatively steeper slopes and to Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic surveyof upland farmers, 1996.

27 an expanded adoption of contour hedgerows varied results (Table 30). The effect of soil than farms with flatter slopes. In Cebu, the conservation on yield has been estimated mainly extent of adoption is significantly determined by in three ways: (I) by direct extrapolation of the education and membership in the alayon of experimental measurements (Comia et al l 994, the household head and by the household's level Paningbatan et al 1995), (2) by using simulation of nonfarm income. The results suggest that models (Young 1989, Ehui et al 1990, Nelson et households headed by more educated persons al 1996b), and (3) by comparing the yield of who are members of the ala yon and have more treated and untreated fields (i.e., with and nonfarm income are more likely to increase the without soil conservation adoption) obtained extent of adoption of CH. Membership in the from farm surveys (Lutz et al 1994, English et al labor-sharing group alayon may enable the 1994, Shively 1996). Simulation and experimen­ household to relax the labor constraint, thereby tal studies may be useful in identifying yield allowing it to expand its adoption of CH. differencesunder the conditions specified; Likewise, the availability of nonfarm income to however, they do not sufficiently allow for relax the liquidity constraints faced by the intrafarm and interfarmer differences in produc­ household may also enable it to finance the tion conditions. In the case of the third method, investment in CH. a production function approach is generally used to account for differences in farm and farmer Productivity effects of the adoption of characteristics, with adoption specified as a contour hedgerows dummy variable (see, for example, Shively Empirical studies to evaluate the effectof soil 1996). The evaluation of the effect of soil conservation on productivity often face the conservation on yield in such studies can be problem of identification (Capalbo and Antle problematic, however, because the estimated 1988)-that is, the pure effect of adoption may productivity effect may not be due to adoption be spuriously correlated with factors that affect alone but to some other factors that are corre­ the adoption decision. Hence, the observed lated with adoption. For example, farmers who positive differential in output between adopters choose to adopt conservation practices may also and nonadopters of a soil conservation technol­ be those farmers who have higher income and ogy, which suggests a positive relationship hence can finance the initial investment require­ between adoption and productivity, may not ments of constructing the structures, as well as correctly estimate the productivity effect attrib­ the optimal input requirements which could uted to adoption alone. This is usually true in result in higher yield compared with cases of sample self-selection where observed data are an endogenous outcome of a decision Table 30. Some empirical results on the effects of soil process in which an individual's decisions are conservation on yield. related to the differential between anticipated Country Crop Soil conservation Yield earnings in their best alternatives (Maddala practice increase 1977, 1986, Duncan and Leigh 1985). In the China• Grains Bench terraces 37% case of adoption, the choice to adopt or not to Haitib Maize Diversion ditches, other 22-51% adopt is not a random process but rather an conservation structures Sorghum Diversion ditches, other 28-32% individual decision based on some utility­ conservation structures maximizing criteria (Pitt 1983, Fuglie and Bosch b 1995). Failure to account for the self-selection Honduras Maize Diversion ditches 145 kg ha·" bias would result in biased estimates of the Nigeriac Maize Contour hedgerows 26-45% productivity effect of the adoption of soil Philippinesd Maize Contour hedgerows 100% conservation. This has subsequent implications for policies to promote conservation programs. Rwanda• Not Soil conservation 21% specified investments

•Hanxiong 1993. "Lutz et al 1994. 'Kangand Ghuman 1991. Empirical studies on the evaluation of the "T"acio 1993. "Byiringiroand Reardon 1996. 'Percentageincrease in effect of conservation practices on yield show yield cannot be estimated because no actual yield was reported.

28 nonadopters. Adopters may also just be better Table 31. Estimated coefficients of the production function for Cebu.• farmers than nonadopters and, hence, more likely to be more productive even without them Variable OLSb ESM adopting a soil conservation technology under Constant 3.78 (0.78)*** 3.57 (0.81 )*** similar biophysical conditions. This is an Labor (person-d) 0.43 (0.13)*** 0.45 (0.13)*** Fertilizer (kg) 0.06 (0.11) 0.07 (0.11) important empirical issue that has significant Season dummyc 0.33 (0.25) 0.35 (0.25) analytical and policy implications. If indeed Maize variety dummyd 0.37 (0.22) 0.34 (0.23) Contour hedgerow dummy• 0.40 (0.18)** there is a differentiationin productivity at­ Productivity effect' 0.46 (0.23)* tributes between adopters and nonadopters of a Productivity differential9 0.50 (0.65) particular soil conservation technology, the Adj. R2 0.23 0.20 productivity differences based on a production •Numbers in parentheses are standard errors .... Significant at the 1 % level. .. Significant at the 5% level.*Significant at the 10% level. "OLS= function analysis using ordinary least squares ordinary least squares, ESM = endogenous switching model. '1 for (OLS) will be biased. In addition, the existence wet season, O otherwise. "1 for modern variety, O otherwise. •1 for parcels with contour hedgerows, O otherwise. 'Measuresthe effect of of self-selection indicates that the promotion of contour hedgerows on productivity after correcting for the possible specific conservation practices may be more sample selection bias. •Measures the effect of sample selection bias on productivity. effective when targeted to potential users who Source of data: IRRI socioeconomic survey of upland farmers, 1996. have a comparative advantage in using that particular technology. tion of CH could potentially increase farm productivity by about 46% for an average An econometric framework that adjusts for farmer. self-selection in estimating the productivity effects of soil conservation is used in this study. Table 31 also presents the OLS estimates of This endogenous switching regression frame­ the production function. From these estimates, work is an improvement over the usual use of the differencebetween yields in contoured and OLS in evaluating the effects of conservation on noncontoured fields is approximately 47%. This farm productivity (Maddala 1983). The full is very close to the average productivity estimate endogenous switching regression model used obtained fromthe endogenous switching regres­ has been described in Lapar and Pandey (l 997) sion model. and is included in Appendix C. Cost-Benefit Analysis Table 31 presents the estimated coefficients Data problems beset a truly dynamic cost­ of the endogenous switching model for Cebu. benefit analysis of investment in contour Because the estimates for Claveria did not show hedgerows. Two major relationships are re­ statistically significant productivity effects, the quired. The first is the relationship between following discussions are based on the estimates erosion (or soil depth) and productivity. The for Cebu only. second is the relationship between conservation measure and soil erosion. The time path of land The estimates indicate that the hypothesis of productivity with erosion control measure can be no differentiation in productivity attributes predicted by combining these two relationships. between farmers cultivating contoured and Considerable investment in research efforts has noncontoured parcels cannot be rejected because been made to understand the nature of these of the statistical nonsignificance of the produc­ relationships as well as to develop simulation tivity differential coefficient. The latent produc­ models to enable the prediction of the effect of tivity attributes are hence homogeneous across soil conservation practices on productivity. farmers in the sample. The estimates also show a Although a range of models of different degrees significant positive average productivity effect of sophistication are now available, practitioners of 0.46. The econometric results thus indicate are constrained because calibration and valida­ that, after segregating the effect of latent produc­ tion of these models often require considerable tivity attributes between farmers cultivating data, and sometimes a reworking of some of the contoured and noncontoured parcels, the adop- relationships.

29 Rather than conducting a full-fledged cost­ The results (Fig. 3) indicate that the break­ benefit analysis, given the difficulties mentioned even increase in percentage yield declines above, we have taken a somewhat simpler rapidly with the increase in base yield without approach of relying on sensitivity analysis to conservation. In very poor environments where 1 highlight the major factors that determine the maize yield is only 200 kg ha· , the break-even profitability of investment in soil erosion increase in yield required is as high as 160% control. We have ignored the temporal patterns under the assumed internalrate of return of 0.4 of changes in yield both with and without and a cropping intensity of unity. Under the contour hedgerows and assumed that yield most favorable scenario of a maize yield of 1.6 t 1 remained constant. The average cost of estab­ ha· , an internalrate of returnof 20%, and a lishing CH (49 person-d), the average annual cropping intensity of 2, the required yield cost of maintenance (14 person-d), and the increase is 26%. The results highlight a paradox. proportionate area lost to hedgerows (20%) were A much higher increase in productivity is obtained from the survey data. The percentage needed to persuade farmers to adopt conserva­ increase in yield of maize required to recoup tion practices in relatively low-yielding (or more these costs at different internal rates of return degraded) environments where investment in was calculated assuming the life of CH to be 10 soil conservation may be most needed to prevent yr. Because the adoption of CH may encourage further erosion. On the contrary, yield gains more intensification of production, two levels of required are much lower in relatively high­ cropping intensity were also considered-single yielding (or less degraded) environments where and double cropping. Hence, cropping intensity the need to conserve soils may not be so appar­ takes a value of l for single cropping and a ent. The results suggest that agricultural re­ value of 2 for double cropping. searchers face a much tougher challenge in

% increase in break-even yield of maize

Cropping intensity= 1 • Discount rate 0.4 • Discount rate 0.2 Cropping intensity= 2 ■ Discount rate 0.4 ' Discount rate 0.2

80 60 40 ------

20 0-'------''------'----...___ __,_ ___ _._ __ __,'------'------' 0 200 400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 1600

Maize (kg ha·1) without contour hedgerows

Fig. 3. Percentage increase in yield of maize needed for investment in contour hedgerows to break even at different discount rates and cropping intensities.

30 making investments in soil conservation eco­ hedgerows too costly? Which of the three cost nomically attractive to farmers in areas with low components matters the most? To answer these initial productivity. Of course, the scenario questions, the analysis presented above was presented above captures only the on-site costs repeated fordifferent scenarios of cost reduc­ and benefits, which are the normal concernsof tion. The base values assumed were a maize 1 farmers. From society's point of view, consider­ yield of 400 kg ha- , an internal rate of returnof ation of off-siteeffects and other externalities 20%, and a cropping intensity of unity. The may shift the balance in favor of low-productiv­ analysis was done by changing one of the cost ity areas. components at a time while keeping the other two fixed at their base values. The results (Fig. The break-even increase in yield is reduced 4) indicate that the break-even increase in yield if the adoption of contour hedgerows encourages declines with a reduction in all costs. But the intensification of cropping ( or generates more break-even increase in yield remains above 50% income through switching to high-value crops). even if the initial cost of establishing hedgerows In areas with more favorableclimatic condi­ is reduced by 80%. What seems to matter most tions, an improvement in market access may is the reduction in annual cost of maintaining the thus encourage adoption by facilitating crop hedgerows. The reduction in establishment cost intensification. Yield-increasing technologies ranks second and the reduction in area loss is will also similarly encourage adoption. last. Of the three cost components, the break­ even increase in yield declines most rapidly with Why do farmers need such a large increase a given percentage reduction in the cost of in yield, especially in areas with lower initial maintenance. The difference betweenthe break­ productivity? Is investment in contour even yield required for a given percentage

% increase in break-even yield of maize

75

• Loss ol area to hedgerows ♦ Establishment cost ■ Mantenance cost

411-'-----'---_,____ ...L.- __..__ __.L....- _ ___,_ __ __.______,__ __...... _ ___, 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

% reduction in cost of hedgerows

Fig. 4. Percentage increase in yield of maize needed for investment in contour hedgerows to break even under different % reduction in cost.

31 reduction in establishment cost and the same encourage a switch from low-value subsistence percentage reduction in the maintenance cost is crops to high-value cash crops would improve small, however. These results are consistent with the returnsto investment in soil conservation. farmer perceptions that the maintenance of Without access to improved technologies and hedgerows is the most problematic. Hence, better marketing infrastructure, farmers are research aimed at reducing the annual mainte­ unlikely to view investment in soil conservation nance cost of hedgerows needs to be given as being economically worthwhile. Investment priority. Carefulselection of hedgerow species in rural infrastructure and policies to facilitate that require minimal maintenance would im­ the development of an efficient marketing prove the benefits from adoption. When compar­ system will therefore encourage adoption. ing Figures 3 and 4, it is also clear that develop­ Promoters of soil conservation technology have ing ways to make it possible for farmers to to consider it not in isolation but as an integral undertake crop intensification, especially in component of interventions designed to increase areas with low yield, may be more effective than the profitability of the overall production reducing the cost of adoption. system. A paradigm shift from that of finding a technical fixto the problem of soil erosion Natural vegetative strips are believed to be toward that of improving farmers' income by the least costly in terms of establishment and facilitating a transition to more remunerative maintenance. Although our estimate of the land-use systems is needed. Otherwise, these maintenance cost of NVS is similar to that of efforts are unlikely to make a significant dent in planted hedgerows, the establishment cost of the the problem of continuing erosion in the sloping former is much lower (Table 21). These systems uplands of Asia. are thus becoming more popular among farmers. The major components of the total cost incurred The results also highlight the need to reduce in the establishment of planted species are the the cost of adopting contour hedgerows, to costs of planting material, transportation, and provide a range of options, and to improve shoveling to prepare the planting area. Farmers targeting. Most farmers find CH, especially of who use natural vegetation do not incur these planted species, to be too expensive. Reducing costs; hence, the overall cost of establishing the cost of establishment and maintenance will hedgerows is much lower. certainly improve the economics of CH. The recent popularity of hedgerows of natural Concluding remarks and implications vegetation is due mainly to its cost advantage. This study undertook an economic analysis of There is also an emerging paradigm of CH for soil conservation, specifically the CH technol­ fallow rotations that might provide scope for ogy. The results of the descriptive analysis of realistic and adoptable techniques (Garrity survey data from Cebu and Claveria indicate 1994). Contour hedgerows could be managed in that differences in farmer, farm, and household a fallow rotation system and hence could serve characteristics may explain the differences in as a superior way to improve fallows in de­ adoption decisions of upland farmers. Econo­ graded land. More intensive research is needed metric estimates of the factors that determine the to further explore this issue. likelihood and extent of adoption indeed show that several socioeconomic and biophysical Contour hedgerows are but one of the ways factors affect farmers' adoption decisions. to reduce soil erosion. Farmers in the study area Farmers' perceptions about the CH technology, use many other complementary and substitute including its benefits, costs, and problems, methods such as contour plowing, mulching, suggest that cost considerations are also para­ other physical barriers, diversion canals, and mount in farmers' adoption decisions. fallowing. One or a combination of these methods may be more suitable in a specific An important implication of the analysis situation, depending on field conditions and presented in this study is that policy support to farmers' resource constraints. Promotion of

32 these other methods and improvement of their countries, a tailor-made approach to technology effectiveness will provide more choices to development is obviously not feasible. It would farmers, thereby allowing them to choose the be difficult to make a major impact without a methods most appropriate to their conditions. broader perspective that recognizes farmers' Promotional activities most often narrowly innovativeness, knowledge, and capacity to target a specific technology and ignore other adapt technologies. The participatory approach options that may be equally effective or more to technology development and adaptation may effective than the one being promoted. An have a lot to offer in this regard, although the output-oriented (such as area covered by differ­ cost of implementing such an approach can ent soil conservation methods and the extent of often be high (Bentley 1994). soil erosion reduced) rather than a physical target-oriented (meters of CH established) A question often raised in the context of incentive structure is needed to encourage investments in conservation is that of subsidy. extension agents and technology promoters to Should the public sector subsidize the cost of take on a broader perspective. soil conservation investments? Economists would argue that the case for subsidy would A range of field-, fann-, and farmer-specific exist only if the externalitiesare large enough to factors condition the adoption of soil conserva­ cover the cost of subsidies. Although it is tion technology. Factors such as low population generally accepted that conservation practices density, low slope, insecurity of tenure, low generate off-sitebenefits, such benefits are initial productivity, and limited access to the rarely assessed adequately, leading to a some­ market reduce incentives to conserve soil. what ad hoc determination of subsidies. One of Incentives are higher in the opposite situation. the major problems in making a satisfactory Careful targeting of technology in areas with assessment of off-site effectsis the lack of favorable conditions, provision of information necessary data. Additional effortsto collect and about the consequences of continued soil analyze data on the effectsof various land-use erosion, demonstration and adaptation of soil patternsin the upper parts of the toposequence conservation technologies under farm- and on stream flow and sedimentation load seem farmer-specific conditions, and provision of warranted. technical assistance and training could encour­ age wider adoption. In areas where available Recent changes in production systems in the technologies are less likely to be adopted, efforts Asian uplands indicate that factors that lead to are needed to widen the domain through further the adoption of erosive land-use practices often improvements in technology. originate outside the upland system. Macro and sectoral policies that encourage a subsistence The diversity of factors that condition the mode of agricultural production and reduce adoption of soil conservation technologies labor absorption outside agriculture are major implies that an extension approach that encour­ contributing factors to land degradation in the ages experimentation and adaptation by farmers uplands. In addition, poorly defined and unen­ is likely to be more suitable for promoting forceable property rights to land can aggravate conservation technologies (Fujisaka 1993). the degradation problem. Hence, institutional Often, promotional activities narrowly target a and policy refom1s, as well as technologies that specific technology judged to be technically not only reduce soil erosion but also directly superior and ignore other options that may not increase farmers' income, are needed. A greater be as effective but are perhaps more suited to understanding of the dynamics of land-use farmer needs. In addition, farmersmay already changes in the uplands is likewise essential in be adopting other substitute practices. Given the designing technological, institutional, and policy diversity of environmental and social conditions interventions for reducing soil erosion and under which farming is carried out in developing enhancing sustainability.

33 References Cenas P, Pandey S. 1996. Contour hedgerow Alferez A. 1980. Utilization of Leucaena as technology in Claveria, Misamis Oriental. organic fertilizer to food crops. Second Philipp. J. Crop Sci. 21(1&2):34-39. SEARCA Professorial Chair Lecture, 16 Clarke H. 1992. The supply of non-degraded Dec 1980, Agronomy Department, Univer­ agricultural land. Aust. J. Agric. Econ. sity of the Philippines Los Banos, Laguna, 36:31-56. Philippines. Comia R, Paningbatan E, Hakansson I. 1994. Anderson J, Thampapillai J. 1990. Soil conser­ Erosion and crop yield response to soil vation in developing countries: project and conditions under alley cropping systems in policy intervention. Policy and Research the Philippines. Soil Res. 31:249- Series No. 8. New York: Agriculture and 261. Rural Development Department, The World Coxhead I, Jayasuriya S. 1994. Technical Bank. change in agriculture and land degradation Basri I, Mercado A, Garrity D. 1990. Upland in developing countries: a general equilib­ rice cultivation using leguminous tree rium analysis. Land Econ. 70:20-37. hedgerows on strongly acid soils. Paper Cramb R, Nelson R. 1997. Investigating con­ presented at the Meeting of the American straints to the adoption of recommended soil Society of Agronomy, 21-26 Oct 1990, San conservation technology in the Philippines. Antonio, Texas. Paper presented at the Workshop on Assess­ Baum E, Wolff P, Zobisch. MA. 1993. Accep­ ing the Causes and Impacts of Soil Erosion tance of soil and water conservation: at Multiple Scales, 17-20 Nov 1997, Bogar, strategies and technologies. Federal Repub­ Indonesia. lic of Germany: German Institute for Cruz W, Repetto R. 1992. The environmental Tropical and Subtropical Agriculture. effects of stabilization and structural adjust­ Bentley JW. 1994. Facts, fantasies and failures ment program: the Philippine case. Wash­ of farmer participatory research: agriculture ington, D.C.: World Resources Institute. and human values. J. Agric. Food Hum. Duncan G, Leigh D. 1985. The endogeneity of Values Soc. 11:140-150. union status: an empirical test. J. Labor Binswanger H, Pingali P. 1987. The evolution of Econ. 3:385-402. farming systems and agricultural technology Ehui S. 1993. Cote d'Ivoire. In: Sustainable in sub-Saharan Africa. In: Ruttan V, Pray C, agriculture and the environment in the editors. Policy for agricultural research. humid tropics. Committee on Sustainable Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. Agriculture and the Environment in the Boserup E. 1965. The conditions of agricultural Humid Tropics, Board on Agriculture and growth. London: Allen and Unwin. Board on Science and Technology for Boserup E. 1981. Population and technological InternationalDevelopment, and National change: a study of long-term trends. Chi­ Research Council. Washington, D.C.: cago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press. National Academy Press. Bromley D, ed. 1992. Making the commons Ehui S, Kang B, Spencer D. 1990. Economic work: theory, practice, and policy. San analysis of soil erosion effectsin alley Francisco, California:ICS Press. cropping, no-till and bush fallowsystems in Byiringiro F, Reardon T. 1996. Farm productiv­ South Western Nigeria. Agric. Syst. 34:349- ity in Rwanda: effects of farm size, erosion, 368. and soil conservation investments. Agric. English J, Tiffen M, Mortimore M. 1994. Land Econ. 15:127-136. resource management in the Machakos Capalbo S, Antle J, eds. 1988. Agricultural District, Kenya, 1930-1990. World Bank productivity: measurement and explanation. Environment Paper No. 5. New York: World Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future. Bank.

34 Ervin C, Ervin D. 1982. Factors affecting the use Garcia J, GeITits R. 1995. Soil conservation in of soil conservation practices: hypotheses, an upland farming system in Cebu: a socio­ evidence, and policy implications. Land economic survey. Survey Report No. 1. Los Econ. 58:277-292. Banos, Philippines: SEARCA-UQ Uplands Ervin D. 1986. Constraints to practicing soil Research Project. conservation: land tenure relationships. In: Garcia J, Gerrits R, Cramb R, Saguiguit G. Lovejoy S, Napier T, editors. Conserving 1995-97. Socioeconomic survey reports 1-7. soil: insights from socioeconomic research. Los Banos, Philippines: SEARCA-UQ Ankeny, Iowa: Soil Conservation Society of Upland Research Project. America. Garrity D. 1994. Improved agroforestrytech­ Feder GR, Just E, Zilberman D. 1985. Adoption nologies for conservation farming: pathways of agricultural innovations in developing toward sustainability. Paper presented at the countries: a survey. Econ. Dev. Cultural InternationalWorkshop on Conservation Change 33:255-298. Farming for Sloping Uplands in Southeast Francisco H. 1994. Upland soil resources of the Asia: Challenges, Opportunities, and Philippines: resource assessment and Prospects, 20-26 Nov 1994, Manila, Philip­ accounting forsoil depreciation. Manila, pines. Philippines: INNOTECH. Garrity D, Kummer D, Guiang E. 1993. The Fuglie K, Bosch D. 1995. Economic and envi­ Philippines. In: and ronmental implications of soil nitrogen the environment in the humid tropics. testing: a switching-regression analysis. Am. Committee on Sustainable Agriculture and J. Agric. Econ. 77:891-900. the Environment in the Humid Tropics, Fujisaka S. 1989. A method for farmer-partici­ Board on Agriculture and Board on Science patory research and technology transfer: and Technology for International Develop­ upland soil conservation in the Philippines. ment, and National Research Council. Exp. Agric. 25:423-433. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press. Fujisaka S. 1993. A case of farmer adaptation Greene W. 1997. Econometric analysis. New and adoption of contour hedgerows for soil York: MacMillan Publishing Co. conservation. Exp. Agric. 29:97-105. Guevarra A. 1976. Management of Leucaena Fujisaka S, Cenas P. 1993. Contour hedgerow leucocephala (Lam.) de Wet for maximum technology in the Philippines: not yet yield and nitrogen contribution to inter­ sustainable. Indigenous Knowledge Dev. cropped corn. PhD dissertation. University Monit. l(l):14-16. of Hawaii, Honolulu. Fujisaka S, Garrity D. 1988. Developing sustain­ Hayami Y, Ruttan V. 1985. Agricultural develop­ able foodcrop farming systems for the ment: an internationalperspective. Balti­ sloping acid uplands: a farmer-participatory more, Maryland: The Johns Hopkins Uni­ approach. Paper presented at the 4th South­ versity Press. east Asian Universities Agroecosystem Hanxiong Z. 1993. The experiences and benefits Network (SUAN) Research Symposium, of integrated control in the Ansai soil and Khon Kaen, Thailand. Agricultural Econom­ water conservation experimental area. In: ics Department Paper No. 88-16. Baum E, Wolff P, Zobisch M, editors. Fujisaka S, Sajise P, de! Castillo R. 1986. Man, Topics in applied resource management in agriculture, and the tropical forest: change the tropics. Vol. I . The extent of soil erosion and development in the Philippine uplands. - regional comparisons. Federal Republic of Bangkok, Thailand: Winrock International Germany: German Institute for Tropical and Institute for Agricultural Development. Subtropical Agriculture. Gabunada F, Barker R. 1995. Adoption of Hoover H, Wiitala M. 1980. Operator and contour hedgerow technology in Matalom, landlord participation in soil erosion in the Leyte, Philippines. (Unpublished.) Maple Creek Watershed in northeast Ne-

35 braska. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department NCSO (National Census and Statistics Office). of Agriculture. 1997. Philippine statistical yearbook 1996. Kang B, Ghuman, B. 1991. Alley cropping as a Manila, Philippines: NCSO. sustainable system. In: Moldenhauer WC, Nelson R, Cramb R, Mamicpic M. 1996a. Costs Hudson NW, Sheng TC, Lee SW, editors. and returnsof hedgerow intercropping and Development of conservation farming on open-field maize farming in the Philippine hillslopes. Ankeny, Iowa: Soil and Water uplands. Working Paper No. I I. Los Banos, Conservation Society. Philippines: SEARCA-UQ Uplands Re­ Lapar ML, Pandey S. 1997. Estimating the search Project. productivity effects of soil conservation in Nelson R, Grist P, Menz K, Paningbatan E, the Philippine uplands. Paper presented at Mamicpic M. 1996b. A cost-benefit analysis the I 997 Annual Meeting of the American of hedgerow intercropping in the Philippine Agricultural Economics Association, 27-30 uplands using SCUAF. Working Paper No. Jul 1997, Toronto, Canada. 7. Los Banos, Philippines: SEARCA-UQ Lutz E, Pagiola S, Reiche, C. 1994. The costs Uplands Research Project. and benefits of soil conservation: the O'Sullivan T. 1985. Farming systems and soil farmers' viewpoint. World Bank Res. management: the Philippine/Australian Observer 9:273-295. development assistance program experience. Ly Tung, Alcober D. 1991. Natural grass strips In: Craswell E, Remenyi J, Nallana L, are preferred. ILEIA Newsl. 2(2):27-28. editors. ACIAR Proceedings Series 6. Maddala GS. 1977. Self-selectivity problems in Canberra, Australia: Australian Centre for econometric models. In: Krishnaiah PR, International Agricultural Research. editor. Applications of statistics. New York: Pandey S. I 996. Socioeconomic context and North-Holland Publishing Co. priorities for strategic research in Asian Maddala GS. I 983. Limited dependent and upland rice ecosystems. In: Piggin C, qualitative variables in econometrics. Courtois B, Schmit V, editors. Upland rice Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University research in partnership. Manila, Philippines: Press. InternationalRice Research Institute. Maddala GS. 1986. Disequilibrium, self­ Paningbatan E, Ciesolka C, Coughlan C, Rose selection, and switching models. In: C. 1995. Alley cropping for managing soil Griliches Z, Intriligator M D, editors. erosion of hilly lands in the Philippines. Soil Handbook of econometrics. Vol. 3. New Technol. 8: 193-204. York: North-Holland Publishing Co. Pitt M. I983. Farm-level fertilizer demand in Marquis MS, Phelps CE. 1987. Price elasticity Java: a meta-production function approach. and adverse selection in the demand for Am. J. Agric. Econ. 65:502-508. supplementary health insurance. Econ. Place F, Hazell P. 1993. Productivity effects of Inquiry 25:299-313. indigenous land tenure systems in sub­ McConnell K. 1983. An economic model of soil Saharan Africa. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 75:10- conservation. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 65:83-89. 19. McDonald J, Moffitt, R. 1980. The uses of tobit Rahm M, Huffman W. 1984. The adoption of analysis. Rev. Econ. Stat. 62:318-321. reduced tillage: the role of human capital Mercado A, Montecalvo A, Garrity D, Basri I. and other variables. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 1992. Upland rice and maize response in a 66:405-413. contour hedgerow system on a sloping acid Sajise P, Ganapin D. Jr. I 991. An overview of upland soil. Paper presented at the 8th upland development in the Philippines. In: Annual Scientific Meeting of the Federation Blair G, Lefroy R, editors. Technologies for of Crop Science Societies of the Philippines, sustainable agriculture on marginal uplands 24-28 May 1992, Zamboanga City, Philip­ in Southeast Asia. ACIAR Proceedings No. pmes. 33. Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research. p 31-44.

36 Shinawatra B. 1985. Highland-lowland interrela­ Tunali I. 1985. Mobility, earnings, and selectiv­ tionships in northernThailand: a study of ity. PhD dissertation. University of Wiscon­ production, distribution, and consumption. sin-Madison. PhD dissertation. Michigan State University, Tunali I. 1994. Rationality of migration. Depart­ East Lansing, Michigan. ment of Economics, Tulane University. Shively G. 1996. Upland cornyields in a con­ USAID (U.S. Agency for International Develop­ tour hedgerow system: a production function ment). 1995. Sustainable agriculture and the approach. Working Paper No. 8. Los Baiios, environment: Philippine case study. Work­ Philippines: SEARCA-UQ Uplands Re­ ing Paper No. 202. Center for Information search Project. and Evaluation. Washington, D.C.: USAID. Sia! M, Carter M. 1992. Is targeted small farm Vergara N. 1982. Sustained outputs from legume credit necessary?: a microeconometric tree-based agroforestry systems. In: N. analysis of capital market efficiency in the Vergara, editor. New directions in Punjab. Department of Agricultural Eco­ agroforestry: the potential of tropical nomics StaffPaper Series No. 354. Wiscon­ legume trees. Los Baiios (Philippines): sin: University of Wisconsin-Madison. Southeast Asian Regional Center forGradu­ Tacio H. 1993. Sloping agricultural land tech­ ate study and Research in Agriculture. nology (SALT): a sustainable agroforestry Young A. 1989. Agroforestry for soil conserva­ scheme for the uplands. Agrofor. Syst. tion. Wallingford: CAB International. 22: 145-152.

37 Appendix A. A microeconomic model of soil conservation.

Soil conservation is an investment to enhance through agricultural use as defined in equation the future productive capacity of the soil. Hence, 3. The natural regeneration rate is given by � a microeconomic model of investment analysis and the rate of depletion of soil quality as a can be used to study adoption behavior. Several result of production activity is y: specifications of such models are available in the literature. For the present analysis, we use the model by Clarke (1992), which is a modified Qo = Q(O) (2) version of the basic model by McConnell !lQ ( 1983). For the sake of exposition, farmers are = l(t)-/3Q(t}-yF(Q, X,,L,) (3) assumed to maximize the present value of dt income (J) from farming over an infinite plan­ ning horizon by allocating labor and other inputs The simplified representation of the produc­ for current production, as well as forenhance­ tion-investment problem depicted above cap­ ment of the productive capacity of the soil. The tures the major factors that determine the extent basic model is specified in equation 1. of investment a farmer would make in enhancing the productive capacity of the soil (or soil conservation). These major factors are the length of the planning horizon, the discount rate, Max J = J e-•, A [PF(Q L,.X 1) (1) the land area available for production, the price () of output, the marginal productivity of soil -ql(L2 .X 2 )-c(L1, 1 )]dt X quality as well as substitutability (or comple­ mentarity) between Q and other inputs, the cost Yield is assumed to be a function (F) of the of investment in soil quality improvement, the productive capacity of soil (Q) and labor (L1) natural rate of soil regeneration, and the rate of and other inputs (such as fertilizer) used for soil depletion associated with agricultural production (X). The production function F production. Some of these factors define the , exhibits diminishing marginal returnsto Q, L1 initial conditions and are given for a farm at a and X1 • Farmers alter the productive capacity of point in time, whereas others can be manipulated the soil by using labor (L2) and other inputs through technology and policy interventions. ). (X2 The improvement in the productive capacity of the soil is defined by the function I. The solution to the model above indicates The cost of a unit improvement in soil quality is that a longer planning horizon, a lower discount assumed to be constant at q. The cost of inputs rate, and a lower cost of investment for a unit used to produce the output is given by the cost improvement of soil quality would encourage a function (C). The area of the farm and the higher level of investment in soil improvement. discount rate are indicated by A and 8. The Similarly, as Clarke (1992) has shown, a higher maximization problem above is subject to the output price will encourage investment if soil initial stock of soil quality (equation 2) and the quality and other inputs are complementary net change in soil quality resulting from invest­ goods. Incentives to improve soil quality will be ment, natural enhancement, and degradation lower if the above conditions are opposite.

38 The model presented above captures only and off-siteexternalities (such as downstream the on-site economic costs and benefitsthat effectsof soil erosion) are additional reasons determine the present value of net returnsto why society may want to invest more in soil farmers. On-site externalities (such as preserva­ conservation than what would be optimal for a tion of soil biodiversity and aesthetic benefits) present-value-maximizing farmer.

Appendix B. Distribution of sample respondents by survey site and villages.

Sample size Villages Adopters Nonadopters

Claveria Ane-i 11 7 Cabacungan 2 1 Hinaplanan 2 1 Lanesi 5 3 Mat-i 3 1 Patrocenio 11 6 Plaridel 1 Poblacion 3 2 Rizal 1

Total 39 21

Cebu Adlaon 9 9 Lusaran 4 4 Taptap 6 6 Tabunan 6 6 Cambinocot 6 6 Sirao 4 4

Total 35 35

39 Appendix C. Estimating the productivity effects of soil conservation.

An econometric framework that adjusts for self­ The estimation of the parameters in the selection in estimating the productivity effects of output supply function (equation I) is compli­ soil conservation is presented below. This cated because adoption status is endogenously framework is an improvement over the usual use determined in a way that may be systematically of ordinary least squares in evaluating the related to the expected output effects of adop­ effectsof conservation on farm productivity. tion. That is, a farmer who adopts a soil conser­ vation technology may also have a larger farm Let Y(.) be the expected output supply, size, a larger income to finance input use, more defined as a function of inputs and other charac­ education, and/or just be a better farmer. Under teristics. The output for the ith farmer is pro­ this endogenous sorting, adopters probably have duced according to one of the two production systematically differentcharacteristics from regimes: those of nonadopters. Thus, while E(v) = 0 for an individual farmer randomly chosen fromthe overall population, the latent variable v prob­ = Yu rf3 +8fx; +(v;1 +E;i) ifan adopter i Y; { : , (1) ably has a nonzero conditional expectation for Y;0 -/3 x; +(v;o + Ew) ifa nonadopter the nonrandomly sorted subsamples of adopters and nonadopters. There is a need, therefore, to where x is a vector of observable variables specify the nonrandom process that sorts indi­ representing market conditions, prices, and viduals into adopters and nonadopters in order to resources including farm and farmer characteris­ obtain consistent estimates of the production tics. The �s give the effectof the observable regime parameters and determine the effectof variables on output without adoption, while the adoption. parameters (�+o) give the effect of the observ­ able variables on output under the regime of The process that sorts adopters and adoption. The latent variables are divided into nonadopters into the two production regimes those that are known (the vis) and those that are involves the decision of the individual farmer to not known (the £is). The vis give the effect of adopt or not adopt a soil conservation technol­ latent individual productivity attributes on ogy. This can be modeled as a decision by a output. We can assume that this latent variable is farmer to adopt a soil conservation technology scaled such that E(v) = 0 for an individual when the expected utility from adoption is selected at random fromthe overall population greater than the utility from nonadoption. What of adopters and nonadopters. The vis are allowed is observable, however, is the farmer's adoption to differ across the two production regimes in status of being an adopter or a non adopter. Thus, the full-switching regression specification to we can model the farmer's adoption decision as accommodate the productivity effect of differ­ a binary variable (B)I that equals one for an ences in the characteristics of adopters and adopter and O otherwise. (B) is thus the result of nonadopters. For example, adoption of a soil a latent adoption status variable (a) that is conservation technology may result in larger scaled such that an individual farmer becomes returns to latent farming skills such as in the an adopter when ai >O. A reduced form specifi­ management of input use and cropping patterns. cation for latent adoption status can be written

The £is are the conventional, unanticipated as random supply shocks that are not known ex 0 a; = c'i'( Y,1- Y,o- K )+1J,, ante and we assume that E (£) = 0. ( = c'i'X; +1J,' 2)

40 where K* is the anticipated costs of adoption, x; From equation (7), consistent estimates of the is a vector of variables that determine the structural parameters can be obtained and the adoption status, 8' is a vector of parameters, and effects of adoption estimated. 11;is an error component reflecting random and latent factors that influence the adoption deci­ Three measures of the effects of adoption on sion. Thus, the sample separation process can be output can be obtained from the preceding written as econometric model. The average productivity effect measure determines the effect of adoption I if a;> O. B;= { (3) on output for an individual farmer selected at 0 otherwise. random from the overall population of farmers. This is the expected effectof adoption on the The expected output supply conditional on output of an average farmer without any inter­ the endogenous sample separation process and vening systematic selection or conditioning on observable characteristics can then be written as the basis of the unobserved individual character­ istics. This average productivity effect is as E(Y) B;=I) =( /3+8 f x;+E(v) B;= I) (4a) follows: E(Y;nl B;=O)= /3'x; + E(v;) 8; = 0) (4b) E(y,,I B)- E(Y,ol B )= { /J x. +E( v,1 I B)] - [ /3'x,+ E( vwl B )] 8( a) where conditioning on the observable variables =8' X; x has been suppressed. 1 From (3) and ( 4), the full endogenous switching regression model2 can The counterfactual effect (see Tunali 1985) be written as compares the output anticipated by a farmer under the actual adoption status were he/she in I ifa,>O (5a) the counterfactual state. That is, it compares the 13;={ 0 othenvise output anticipated by a nonadopter were that E(Y;1 I 13;=1 )=.(/3+8 f x; +P,A;1 (Sb) same individual an adopter and, similarly, the E(y;0I 13;=0)=./Jx,+P,,A;o· (5c) output anticipated by an adopter were that same individual a nonadopter. Let us call the Alternatively, it is possible and often counterfactual effectthe returns to adoption and desirable to estimate (5) using all the observa­ the returns to nonadoption, which are shown as tions in Y; (Maddala 1983). Note that equations (8b) and (8c), respectively. Alterna­ tively, these are also referred to as conditional

E(Y; )=E(y;,I B, = I)Prob(B, =I)+ E(y,0 1 B, =O)Prob(B,=0), (6) effects (see Sia! and Carter 1992).

so that

E( Y, )= /3'x;+ o'[

1 The conditional expectations on the right-handside of equations(4a) and (4b) can be wriuen as (I) E(v,,JB,= I)= E(v.,ITJ,>-6' x) and (II) E(v �IB,= 0) = E(v�Jri ,<- 6 'x,). 1l1e problem of intrinsic productivity differences betweenadopters and nonadopters can be clearly seen from (I) and (II). If latent productivity attributes are systematically related to adoption status, then the conditional expectations in (4) will not be zero. On the other hand. the problematic correlation between v, and T\, indicates that the latter. in fact, provides information on the latent variable v,. Thus, the parameters of interest can be consistently estimated by using this information • to control for the latent characteristics v,, and v,0 This can be done by making distributional assumptions to substitute for the latent information. From the sample selection literature, it is possible to separately identify the effectof latent individual attributes and obtain consistent estimates of the structural parameters of the output ) supply function conditional on assumptions about the error structure. Following Maddala (1983). assume that the error vector (11,, v,,. v,0 is distributed multivariate normal with zero expectations and positive definitematrix.

'p1 = Cov(TJ,,v,.)/Var(TJ,)and p0 = Cov(TJ,,v.,)/Var(TJ,) are the population regression coefficients relating v,, and v�· respectively;\'= (j)(C,)i(C,)and)-..,"= (j)(C,)11- (C)are the estimates of T).given the adoption status and C= o 'x/Var(TJ ); and (j)(.)and(.) are the standard normal density and cumulative distribution functions. resp�ctively. l11eparameter� of this system can be estimated'using 'maxim�m likelihood methods. Heckmanproposes a two-stage procedure for estimating consistent but less efficientparameters of equation (5) (Maddala 1983). Consistent estimates of 13may be obtained through separate OLS regressions of the two conditional output supply functions in (5) (see Pitt 1983. Tunali 1994, and Fuglie and Bosch 1995, for example).

41 = = = E( Yii 18;= 1)-E ( Ywl 8; 1) [ /3'x;+ E( vii 18,= 1)] -[ /3'x, + E( v;0I8, 1)] (8b) = o'x,+(p,-po);.,il

= = = = = E(Y,o I 8, 0)-E( Yi/ 18; 0) [ /3'x;+ E(v, 0 I 8, 0))-[ /3'X; +E(v) 8; 0)] (8c) = -o'x;+( P0-p1 )).'°

Note that the conditional effect is the sum of the the gains or losses from latent productivity average productivity effect(equation 8a) and the attributes, the level of which is measured by A. differentiation effect, the parameter (p1_p0), or

42