Overcoming Deflation and Moving Forward

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Overcoming Deflation and Moving Forward Overcoming Deflation and Moving Forward Yoshio Okubo Vice-Chairman, Japan Securities Dealers Association (JSDA) ive years have passed since the global financial monetary policy, as part of the three-pronged ap- crisis, but the risk of deflation is still present proach of “Abenomics”, an economic policy strate- Fin the global economy. Japan’s recent signs of gy of the new government headed by Prime Minis- economic recovery and improved market senti- ter Shinzo Abe. This three-pronged policy consists ments provide an excellent opportunity to recon- of bold monetary easing, flexible fiscal policy, and sider the challenges of overcoming deflationary a growth strategy to promote private investment. expectations. This article argues that overcoming entrenched deflationary expectations rests pri- Markets have so far responded favorably to this marily on monetary policy and that its success new policy initiative. The Nikkei 225 stock mar- will depend on credible fiscal policies to reduce ket index rose by 38 percent in the first six months public deficits. The overall long-term policy goal since Prime Minister Abe took office. The develop- is to encourage entrepreneurship and foster inno- ments in currency markets have helped ease de- vation, which proves difficult under a deflationary flationary pressures caused earlier by larger scale environment. Such policies should be supported monetary easing in the U.S. and Europe. The opti- by a regulatory framework that can ensure fair and mism in Japan’s stock markets has also been helped transparent functioning of capital markets, there- by the buoyancy of U.S. stock markets, where in- by enabling efficient pricing of risks in allocating vestors have become more sanguine about the re- scarce risk-taking capital. covery of the U.S. economy. There are now more signs that the recovery in Japan is gaining momen- Bold Monetary Policy tum, gradually spreading the optimism that the prolonged period of deflation will be finally over Monetary policy in major countries has played a in the near future. predominant role in responding to the global fi- nancial crisis. In the wake of the failures of many Lingering Nervousness large financial institutions, major central banks provided liquidity to the financial systems under In Japan, given the prolonged and entrenched de- unprecedented stress. They also assumed a deci- flationary expectations, it is not easy to completely sive role in macroeconomic management, resort- reverse such expectations. Nervousness and skep- ing to nontraditional policies both in terms of in- ticism still remain about “Abenomics” and these struments used and in terms of the scale in which new policies in the mind of some critics. These they implemented them. feelings seem to have been heightened by the recent volatility in the stock and currency markets, which The Bank of Japan (BoJ) had pursued a strategy, have been driven primarily by the concern that now being followed by other major central banks the program of large-scale bond purchases in the after the crisis, centered on very low interest rates U.S. will be tapered off much earlier than had been and quantitative easing (QE). With an aim of dis- expected. This nervousness has spread around the pelling prolonged deflationary expectations, the world, but it has been most pronounced in Japan, BoJ recently embarked on a significantly bolder where it is thought that a rise in long-term interest THINK TANK 20: The G-20 and Central Banks in the New World of Unconventional Monetary Policy 55 rates would have an adverse impact on the health interest rates above 2 percent from the current level of the banks that have been the major holders of of slightly below 1 percent. The key to the success government bonds. With the level of outstanding of a bold monetary policy lies in ensuring the sta- government debt extremely high, there are also bility of long-term real interest rates, and will de- worries that the impact on the government’s bor- pend crucially on the ability of the government to rowing costs might further enlarge fiscal deficit. set its deficits on a sustainable path toward reduc- This concern seems to be amplified by the signs tion. If the ability of the government to ensure the of a stronger recovery that may edge up long-term sustainability of debt were to be seen as fragile, the interest rates, adversely affecting a long-term re- perceived risk of the premature increase in interest covery prematurely. rates would be heightened, jeopardizing the favor- able impact of the bold monetary policy to sustain While uncertainties are inherent in markets, the and support real economic activity. The effective- nervousness in the Japanese markets may be exag- ness of the bold monetary policy therefore cannot gerated for several reasons. Compared with other be separated from the credibility of fiscal policy in countries, the level of long-term interest rates is controlling deficits over the medium term. In this still the lowest in Japan. At the same time, the stock environment, the “exit” policy of the central banks and bond markets are in the process of digesting will not be an easy road back to the normal conduct the policy changes and it will take some time for of monetary policy, but will involve pressing the a new steady-state to emerge. No signs have yet government to proceed with fiscal consolidation. emerged that would encourage inflationary ex- pectations to rise. In fact, an interesting analysis Preventing Deflation by the IMF’s World Economic Outlook1 argues that over the past decade or so, inflation in advanced Following the global financial crisis, prevent- economies has become less responsive to changes ing deflation has become a main policy agenda in economic slack and that long-term inflation in many countries. The bold monetary policies expectations have become more firmly anchored. pursued by major central banks reflect the sense This suggests that ongoing monetary policy ac- of urgency with which they aim to prevent defla- commodation is unlikely to have significant infla- tion and a return to recession, having in mind the tionary consequences as long as inflation expecta- prolonged deflation which has persisted after the tions remain anchored. This analysis is particularly bubble burst in Japan. Five years after the crisis, valid for Japan, where deflationary expectations however, the fight against deflation and recession are deeply entrenched. In addition, while the po- is not yet over in many countries. tential impact of the rise in long-term interest rates may have an adverse impact on the profitability of Deflation can be very dangerous. It threatens the banks, it is believed that the effect would be limit- stability of the economy and the society in the ed. In fact, encouraging banks to increase lending long-run. Deflation makes firms and households in order to support investment by borrowers, and excessively risk-averse, due to the devaluation of discouraging them from sitting on investments assets held by households and firms. Inability to in government bonds, is an important part of the lower real interest rates toward zero hampers overall economic policy strategy. monetary policy. Households and firms who have outstanding debt suffer from the real increase in Obviously, it is premature to prescribe an “exit” the debt burden. With the prospect of decreasing from the unconventional monetary policy in Japan. prices, household consumption is postponed and Deflationary expectations will have to be dispelled businesses become cautious in making investment and replaced by expectations of “price stability”, decisions given the perceived high real interest defined as an inflation rate of 2 percent. This pro- rate. Business sentiment is also adversely affected cess will certainly entail a rise in nominal long-term by greater uncertainties about the future of the THINK TANK 20: The G-20 and Central Banks in the New World of Unconventional Monetary Policy 56 economy and the undervaluation of the market safety net should not be underestimated. In the capitalization of firms in the stock market. Risk- immediate aftermath of the financial crisis, pri- taking activities, necessary for innovation, are gen- vate sector net savings spiked as households and erally suppressed and the economy starts shrink- firms cut investment, and households saved more, ing, depriving the youth of job opportunities and resulting in a huge increase in budget deficit. Tax on-the-job learning—an impact that could last a revenues fell sharply while expenditures adjusted generation. Investments are likely to shift abroad slowly, serving as an automatic stabilizer in the due to high real exchange rates, further depriving economy. Fiscal policies have also been used more job opportunities at home. proactively to fight deflation and reduce unem- ployment. Expenditures on the social safety net When deflation is mild, however, such danger may have helped alleviate the burden that falls on the not be fully recognized by political leaders or by socially vulnerable, including the young and the the public. The danger of prolonged mild deflation unemployed. Fiscal expenditures on infrastructure is likely to be underestimated and fighting defla- projects helped upgrade the quality of public ser- tion might not gain policy priority. In fact, there vices, which may have been needed regardless of are some segments of society, such as pensioners, the economic situation. who may benefit from prolonged mild deflation. The public begins to accept a zero increase or mild Overall, however, the effects of fiscal policy on decrease in the consumer price index as price reversing deflationary expectations seem to have stability, not recognizing the real dangers. Defla- been limited. The ballooning deficits have raised tionary expectations become entrenched, leaving concerns about debt sustainability, and eventually the long-term real interest rate at a high level and eroded confidence in the ability of government to slowly depriving the economy of entrepreneur- sustain the level of public services and social safety ship and the risk-taking that is necessary to move nets including public pensions and medical in- the economy forward.
Recommended publications
  • Monetary Policy in Economies with Little Or No Money
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY IN ECONOMIES WITH LITTLE OR NO MONEY Bennett T. McCallum Working Paper 9838 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9838 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2003 This paper was prepared for presentation at the December 16-17, 2002, meeting of the Hong Kong Economic Association. I am indebted to Marvin Goodfriend, Lok Sang Ho, Allan Meltzer, and Edward Nelson for helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research ©2003 by Bennett T. McCallum. All rights reserved. Short sections of text not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit including © notice, is given to the source. Monetary Policy in Economies with Little or No Money Bennett T. McCallum NBER Working Paper No. 9838 July 2003 JEL No. E3, E4, E5 ABSTRACT The paper's arguments include: (1) Medium-of-exchange money will not disappear in the foreseeable future, although the quantity of base money may continue to decline. (2) In economies with very little money (e.g., no currency but bank settlement balances at the central bank), monetary policy will be conducted much as at present by activist adjustment of overnight interest rates. Operating procedures will be different, however, with payment of interest on reserves likely to become the norm. (3) In economies without any money there can be no monetary policy. The relevant notion of a general price level concerns some index of prices in terms of a medium of account.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Policy in an Unemployment Crisis∗
    Fiscal Policy in an Unemployment Crisis∗ Pontus Rendahly University of Cambridge, CEPR, and Centre for Macroeconomics (CFM) April 30, 2014 Abstract This paper shows that large fiscal multipliers arise naturally from equilibrium unemploy- ment dynamics. In response to a shock that brings the economy into a liquidity trap, an expansion in government spending increases output and causes a fall in the unemployment rate. Since movements in unemployment are persistent, the effects of current spending linger into the future, leading to an enduring rise in income. As an enduring rise in income boosts private demand, even a temporary increase in government spending sets in motion a virtuous employment-spending spiral with a large associated multiplier. This transmission mechanism contrasts with the conventional view in which fiscal policy may be efficacious only under a prolonged and committed rise in government spending, which engineers a spiral of increasing inflation. Keywords: Fiscal multiplier, liquidity trap, zero lower bound, unemployment inertia. ∗The first version of this paper can be found as Cambridge Working Papers in Economics No. 1211. yThe author would like to thank Andrea Caggese, Giancarlo Corsetti, Wouter den Haan, Jean-Paul L'Huillier, Giammario Impulitti, Karel Mertens, Emi Nakamura, Kristoffer Nimark, Evi Pappa, Franck Portier, Morten Ravn, Jon Steinsson, Silvana Tenreyro, and Mirko Wiederholt for helpful comments and suggestions. I am grateful to seminar participants at LSE, Royal Economic Society, UCL, European Univer- sity Institute, EIEF, ESSIM 2012, SED 2013, Bonn University, Goethe University, UAB, and in particular to James Costain, and Jonathan Heathcote for helpful discussions and conversations. Financial support is gratefully acknowledge from the Centre for Macroeconomics (CFM) and the Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET).
    [Show full text]
  • The Financial and Economic Crisis of 2008-2009 and Developing Countries
    THE FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC CRISIS OF 2008-2009 AND DEVELOPING COUNTRIES Edited by Sebastian Dullien Detlef J. Kotte Alejandro Márquez Jan Priewe UNITED NATIONS New York and Geneva, December 2010 ii Note Symbols of United Nations documents are composed of capital letters combined with figures. Mention of such a symbol indicates a reference to a United Nations document. The views expressed in this book are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the UNCTAD secretariat. The designations employed and the presentation of the material in this publication do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Secretariat of the United Nations concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area, or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. Material in this publication may be freely quoted; acknowl edgement, however, is requested (including reference to the document number). It would be appreciated if a copy of the publication containing the quotation were sent to the Publications Assistant, Division on Globalization and Development Strategies, UNCTAD, Palais des Nations, CH-1211 Geneva 10. UNCTAD/GDS/MDP/2010/1 UNITeD NatioNS PUblicatioN Sales No. e.11.II.D.11 ISbN 978-92-1-112818-5 Copyright © United Nations, 2010 All rights reserved THE FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC CRISIS O F 2008-2009 AND DEVELOPING COUN T RIES iii CONTENTS Abbreviations and acronyms ................................................................................xi About the authors
    [Show full text]
  • Short-Term Currency in Circulation Forecasting for Monetary Policy Purposes: the Case of Poland
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Koziński, Witold; Świst, Tomasz Article Short-term currency in circulation forecasting for monetary policy purposes: The case of Poland e-Finanse: Financial Internet Quarterly Provided in Cooperation with: University of Information Technology and Management, Rzeszów Suggested Citation: Koziński, Witold; Świst, Tomasz (2015) : Short-term currency in circulation forecasting for monetary policy purposes: The case of Poland, e-Finanse: Financial Internet Quarterly, ISSN 1734-039X, University of Information Technology and Management, Rzeszów, Vol. 11, Iss. 1, pp. 65-75, http://dx.doi.org/10.14636/1734-039X_11_1_007 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/147121 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: a Business Perspective
    Deflation: a business perspective Prepared by the Corporate Economists Advisory Group Introduction Early in 2003, ICC's Corporate Economists Advisory Group discussed the risk of deflation in some of the world's major economies, and possible consequences for business. The fear was that historically low levels of inflation and faltering economic growth could lead to deflation - a persistent decline in the general level of prices - which in turn could trigger economic depression, with widespread company and bank failures, a collapse in world trade, mass unemployment and years of shrinking economic activity. While the risk of deflation is now remote in most countries - given the increasingly unambiguous signs of global economic recovery - its potential costs are very high and would directly affect companies. This issues paper was developed to help companies better understand the phenomenon of deflation, and to give them practical guidance on possible measures to take if and when the threat of deflation turns into reality on a future occasion. What is deflation? Deflation is defined as a sustained fall in an aggregate measure of prices (such as the consumer price index). By this definition, changes in prices in one economic sector or falling prices over short periods (e.g., one or two quarters) do not qualify as deflation. Dec lining prices can be driven by an increase in supply due to technological innovation and rapid productivity gains. These supply-induced shocks are usually not problematic and can even be accompanied by robust growth, as experienced by China. A fall in prices led by a drop in demand - due to a severe economic cycle, tight economic policies or a demand-side shock - or by persistent excess capacity can be much more harmful, and is more likely to lead to persistent deflation.
    [Show full text]
  • This Is the Heritage Society After All – to 1893, and the Shape of This
    1 IRVING HERITAGE SOCIETY PRESENTATION By Maura Gast, Irving CVB October 2010 For tonight’s program, and because this is the Irving Heritage Society, after all, I thought I’d take a departure from my usual routine (which probably everyone in this room has heard too many times) and talk a little bit about the role the CVB plays in an historical context instead. I’m hopeful that as champions of heritage and history in general, that you’ll indulge me on this path tonight, and that you’ll see it all come back home to Irving by the time I’m done. Because there were really three key factors that led to the convention industry as we know it today and to our profession. And they are factors that, coupled with some amazing similarities to what’s going on in our world today, are worth paying attention to. How We as CVBs Came to Be • The Industrial Revolution – And the creation of manufacturing organizations • The Railroad Revolution • The Panic of 1893 One was the industrial revolution and its associated growth of large manufacturing organizations caused by the many technological innovations of that age. The second was the growth of the railroad, and ultimately the Highway system here in the US. And the third was the Panic of 1893. The Concept of “Associations” 2 The idea of “associations” has historically been an American concept – this idea of like‐minded people wanting to gather together in what came to be known as conventions. And when you think about it, there have been meetings and conventions of some kind taking place since recorded time.
    [Show full text]
  • Research & Policy Brief No.47
    Research & Policy Briefs From the World Bank Malaysia Hub No. 47 May 24, 2021 Demand and Supply Dynamics in East Asia during the COVID-19 Recession Ergys Islamaj, Franz Ulrich Ruch, and Eka Vashakmadze The COVID-19 pandemic has devastated lives and damaged economies, requiring strong and decisive policy responses from governments. Developing Public Disclosure Authorized the optimal short-term and long-term policy response to the pandemic requires understanding the demand and supply factors that drive economic growth. The appropriate policy response will depend on the size and duration of demand and supply shocks. This Research & Policy Brief provides a decomposition of demand and supply dynamics at the macroeconomic level for the large developing economies of East Asia. The findings suggest that both demand and supply shocks were important drivers of output fluctuations during the first year of the pandemic. The demand shocks created an environment of deficient demand—reflected in large negative output gaps even after the unprecedented policy response—which is expected to last through 2021. The extant deficient demand is suggestive of continued need to support the economic recovery. Its size should guide policy makers in calibrating responses to ensure that recovery is entrenched, and that short-term supply disruptions do not lead to long-term declines in potential growth. The Pandemic-Induced Shock Low external demand will continue to affect economies reliant on tourism, while sluggish domestic demand will disproportionally affect The pandemic, national lockdowns, and reverberations from the rest economies with large services sectors. Understanding the demand of the world inflicted a massive shock to the East Asia and Pacific and supply factors that drive economic growth is critical for region in 2020 (World Bank 2020a).
    [Show full text]
  • Carbonomics Innovation, Deflation and Affordable De-Carbonization
    EQUITY RESEARCH | October 13, 2020 | 9:24PM BST Carbonomics Innovation, Deflation and Affordable De-carbonization Net zero is becoming more affordable as technological and financial innovation, supported by policy, are flattening the de-carbonization cost curve. We update our 2019 Carbonomics cost curve to reflect innovation across c.100 different technologies to de- carbonize power, mobility, buildings, agriculture and industry, and draw three key conclusions: 1) low-cost de-carbonization technologies (mostly renewable power) continue to improve consistently through scale, reducing the lower half of the cost curve by 20% on average vs. our 2019 cost curve; 2) clean hydrogen emerges as the breakthrough technology in the upper half of the cost curve, lowering the cost of de-carbonizing emissions in more difficult sectors (industry, heating, heavy transport) by 30% and increasing the proportion of abatable emissions from 75% to 85% of total emissions; and 3) financial innovation and a lower cost of capital for low-carbon activities have driven around one-third of renewables cost deflation since 2010, highlighting the importance of shareholder engagement in climate change, monetary stimulus and stable regulatory frameworks. The result of these developments is very encouraging, shaving US$1 tn pa from the cost of the path towards net zero and creating a broader connected ecosystem for de- carbonization that includes renewables, clean hydrogen (both blue and green), batteries and carbon capture. Michele Della Vigna, CFA Zoe Stavrinou Alberto Gandolfi +44 20 7552-9383 +44 20 7051-2816 +44 20 7552-2539 [email protected] [email protected] alberto.gandolfi@gs.com Goldman Sachs International Goldman Sachs International Goldman Sachs International Goldman Sachs does and seeks to do business with companies covered in its research reports.
    [Show full text]
  • The Interaction Between Monetary and Fiscal Policy: Insights from Two Business Cycles in Israel
    The interaction between monetary and fiscal policy: insights from two business cycles in Israel Kobi Braude and Karnit Flug1 Abstract Comparing the two significant recessions Israel experienced over the last decade, we highlight the importance of sustained fiscal discipline and credible monetary policy during normal times for expanding the set of policy options available at a time of need. In the first recession Israel was forced to conduct a contractionary fiscal and monetary policy, whereas in the second one it was able to pursue an expansionary policy. The difference in the effect of the policy response between the two recessions is sizable: it exacerbated the first recession while it helped to moderate the second one. Keywords: Fiscal policy, fiscal discipline, public debt, monetary policy, counter-cyclical policy, business cycles JEL classification: E52, E62, H6 1 Bank of Israel. We thank Stanley Fischer and Alon Binyamini for helpful comments and Noa Heymann for her research assistance. BIS Papers No 67 205 Introduction Over the last decade Israel experienced two significant business cycles. The monetary and fiscal policy response to the recession at the end of the decade was very different from the response to recession of the early 2000s. In the earlier episode, following a steep rise in the budget deficit and a single 2 percentage point interest rate reduction, policy makers were forced to make a sharp reversal and conduct a contractionary policy in the midst of the recession. In the second episode, monetary and fiscal expansion was pursued until recovery was well under way. This note examines the factors behind the difference in the policy response to the two recession episodes.
    [Show full text]
  • Rebuilding the Public Sector for Economic Recovery and Resilience
    REBUILDING THE PUBLIC SECTOR FOR ECONOMIC RECOVERY AND RESILIENCE Sara Hinkley, Ph.D. March 2021 Executive Summary As the country crests the most devastating wave yet of the COVID-19 pandemic, there is growing optimism that the new administration will act quickly to stem the economic crisis: both by deploying the federal government’s leadership to control the pandemic itself and by using the federal government’s fiscal capacity to mitigate the economic damage caused by the public health crisis. The Biden administration will need to turn around both of these failures quickly in order to prevent further catastrophe for millions of Americans and a sustained recession. But the disaster unfolding now is not just a result of policy failures over the past eleven months; it is the result of decades of disinvestment and austerity, accelerated during the Great Recession, which made us more vulnerable to this crisis. Local, state, and national austerity set the country up for a harsh, prolonged, and profoundly unequal recession. We face a pivotal moment now: we can repeat those mistakes, leaving us more vulnerable to future crises, or we can build back our public sector to make us more economically resilient. groundworkcollaborative.org REBUILDING THE PUBLIC SECTOR FOR ECONOMIC RECOVERY AND RESILIENCE | 1 It is certainly bad luck that the long-predicted1 economic downturn was sparked by a pandemic, but our failure to meet this crisis with an effective public response is the outcome of years of deliberate policy choices. The austerity implemented after the Great Recession decimated both our ability to weather an economic downturn and our ability to handle any crisis requiring a strong public response.
    [Show full text]
  • The Bulgarian Financial Crisis of 1996/1997
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Berlemann, Michael; Nenovsky, Nikolay Working Paper Lending of first versus lending of last resort: The Bulgarian financial crisis of 1996/1997 Dresden Discussion Paper Series in Economics, No. 11/03 Provided in Cooperation with: Technische Universität Dresden, Faculty of Business and Economics Suggested Citation: Berlemann, Michael; Nenovsky, Nikolay (2003) : Lending of first versus lending of last resort: The Bulgarian financial crisis of 1996/1997, Dresden Discussion Paper Series in Economics, No. 11/03, Technische Universität Dresden, Fakultät Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Dresden This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/48137 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten,
    [Show full text]
  • Money Creation in the Modern Economy
    14 Quarterly Bulletin 2014 Q1 Money creation in the modern economy By Michael McLeay, Amar Radia and Ryland Thomas of the Bank’s Monetary Analysis Directorate.(1) This article explains how the majority of money in the modern economy is created by commercial banks making loans. Money creation in practice differs from some popular misconceptions — banks do not act simply as intermediaries, lending out deposits that savers place with them, and nor do they ‘multiply up’ central bank money to create new loans and deposits. The amount of money created in the economy ultimately depends on the monetary policy of the central bank. In normal times, this is carried out by setting interest rates. The central bank can also affect the amount of money directly through purchasing assets or ‘quantitative easing’. Overview In the modern economy, most money takes the form of bank low and stable inflation. In normal times, the Bank of deposits. But how those bank deposits are created is often England implements monetary policy by setting the interest misunderstood: the principal way is through commercial rate on central bank reserves. This then influences a range of banks making loans. Whenever a bank makes a loan, it interest rates in the economy, including those on bank loans. simultaneously creates a matching deposit in the borrower’s bank account, thereby creating new money. In exceptional circumstances, when interest rates are at their effective lower bound, money creation and spending in the The reality of how money is created today differs from the economy may still be too low to be consistent with the description found in some economics textbooks: central bank’s monetary policy objectives.
    [Show full text]