Chapter Four the 1920S

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Chapter Four the 1920S CHAPTER FOUR THE 1920S: INTERNATIONAL HIGH FINANCE AND THE LAZARD FIRMS For Frank Altschul, back from the war, the 1920s were a time when he was consolidating his position in Lazard Frères, New York. This was something of a challenge for him. Still only thirty-three in 1920, he was overshadowed by the dynamic and vigorous George Blumenthal, then sixty-two, who had been with Lazard’s New York house since the 1890s, and despite long absences remained its dominant force until the end of 1925. In these years, Blumenthal found himself at odds on policy with the Paris partners, with whom ultimate control of the New York house rested. On the financial front, American and European bankers of the 1920s were extremely active participants in initiatives to regenerate the European economies as a functioning system. Some of their moves to do so were undertaken as part of the course of normal business. Others represented international efforts by American and European private bankers, usually with quiet backing from their own governments, to settle the problems of Europe and provide financing that would underpin the restoration of economic stability throughout Europe. The Lazard firms did not take the lead in these ventures, but throughout the 1920s their partners would participate in multiple aspects of international financial diplomacy. This was particularly true of the London firm, Lazard Brothers, two of whose partners, Sir Robert Kindersley and Robert Brand, were heavily involved in British efforts to resolve the controversial postwar issues of German reparations and Allied war debts. These activities sometimes gave rise to strains with their French partners, who largely followed their own government’s line. A recent historian of the Lazard firms argues that “Lazard was an American firm in the United States, a French firm in France, and a British firm in the U.K.”1 In broad policy, this was not always an advantage. By the 1920s, each bank had effectively gone native, making it extremely difficult for them to act as a united front, even though they could cooperate on particular issues. During the 1920s Lazard Brothers was extremely active in seeking international business and expanding its overseas profile, efforts which likewise sometimes brought it into conflict with the French house when they involved dealings on behalf of German firms. The ambitions of the London house also had the potential to affect the pattern of operations of Lazard Frères in New York. In the mid-1920s, Brand and Kindersley proposed that the New York house should radically change its own business profile, primarily as a means of boosting the standing of the British firm and facilitating its access to American financial resources, which were far more munificent than those available to them in London. As he gradually established himself as the leading partner in New York, Frank Altschul had to keep his own counsel while steering a complicated course among his battling colleagues. Only in the late 1920s did he really begin to come into his own. 1 William D. Cohan, The Last Tycoons: The Secret History of Lazard Frères & Co. (New York: Doubleday, 2007), 20. 1 For much of the 1920s, it seems, Frank Altschul found discretion the better part of valor. His father, now retired from business, faced fewer constraints upon the expression of his opinions, and until his death in 1927 commented extensively on international affairs. The disappearance of Woodrow Wilson from the political scene did much to reconcile Charles Altschul to the League of Nations whose supposed shortcomings he had previously roundly condemned. Interestingly, Charles Altschul, probably correctly, did not interpret the outcome of the 1920 presidential election as a repudiation of American membership in “ANY League of Nations.” He told Arthur Goodhart, his son Frank’s brother-in-law, that American voters had a “general desire for a change,” but that if a referendum had been held as to whether to join the League with the reservations the Republicans had attached to the covenant, “it would have been carried with enthusiasm.” By 1923, he believed that “the people of this country have grown tired of watchful waiting and want the Administration to do something constructive in Europe.” Replying to a query from Goodhart as to “why America is not equally bound to aid Asia if morally bound to assist Europe,” Charles Altschul made it clear that, in his view, American interests overseas were largely restricted to Europe, stating: This country is populated by the immigrants from Europe or their descendants; its civilization is principally Anglo-Saxon -- strictly so as far as the essentials are concerned; all other European countries have contributed to its customs and have exercised an influence on its development. We would be touched to the core if the nations of Europe should relapse into anarchy or become materially weakened morally and physically. It is of the greatest importance to this country to keep alive in Europe the respect for government and a condition of living which corresponds to our civilization. If either of these should disappear we would feel a terrible recoil. But if similar conditions should develop in Asia, they would not affect us because the conditions and the state of civilization there are not in immediate touch with our own. Europe stands in an entirely special position as regards our country. By early 1923, Altschul “believe[d] that there is growing in our country a very decided sentiment in favor of participation in European affairs, as a matter of self-protection and preservation, and in recognition of a high moral and ethical responsibility.” He believed that the American people had a “desire to do our bit in peace as well as in war; to bring some order out of confusion; to endeavor to cement and heal breaks; to bring our more normal temper to bear upon the distracted 2 peoples of Europe.” Regretfully, in 1924 Charles Altschul reported that American “antipathy against the League of Nations seems unabating, altho’ nourished on prejudice, ignorance, and party politics.”3 Charles 2Charles Altschul to Arthur Goodhart, January 8, 1923, File Arthur Goodhart, Charles Altschul Files, Altschul Papers. 3 Charles Altschul to Hammerschlag, January 29, 1924, File Paul Hammerschlag 1923-1924, Charles Altschul Files, Altschul Papers. 2 Altschul deprecated any proposals that might weaken the League of Nations and World Court, 4 which he continued to hope the United States would eventually join in some form or another. By 1924, he felt that the recent London conference on reparations and the Geneva conference to strengthen the League of Nations had “brought about a different atmosphere and may . be the beginning of a new era.”5 He likewise welcomed “the spread of the Locarno spirit,” named for the treaties of late 1925 whereby Germany accepted its 1919 frontiers with France in exchange for membership of the League of Nations and a complete Allied evacuation of the Rhineland. Altschul nonetheless displayed some apprehension as to what Benito Mussolini, Italy’s 6 increasingly assertive Fascist leader, was likely to do in the future. Charles Altschul’s reconciliation with the League of Nations could scarcely have been more complete. He was privy to and approved proposals, drawn up in 1923 by his old wartime associate Prof. James T. Shotwell of Columbia University, head of the Division of History and Economics of the Carnegie Endowment, to submit all disputes among states that were members of the League of Nations to compulsory arbitration, an initiative that provided the germ of the 1924 Geneva Protocol. A second scheme, drafted by Shotwell in 1925 and published in 1926, initially envisaged that the United States would join the International Court associated with the League of Nations, upon condition that the court then call an international conference of all its members, to negotiate a general treaty that would submit all disputes among the signatory nations to arbitration by the court, effectively outlawing war. Watered down, with all reference to the International Court removed, this proposal eventually became one of the impulses that propelled the United States government to move to negotiate the 1928 Kellogg-Briand Pact outlawing war.7 In November 1926 Altschul deplored President Calvin Coolidge’s acquiescence in Senate reservations that stymied the administration’s previous efforts to bring about United States membership in the World Court, “which many of us had been confident enough to consider an American conception.” He praised, moreover, the “excellent work done in the interest of the League by many unofficial Americans, in Austria, in Poland, in Greece, on the Dawes Committee,” and on legal and academic issues in Geneva. Altschul trusted, therefore, 8 that “the day will come when this country will realize that it owes a great duty to Europe.” 4Charles Altschul to James G. McDonald, March 16, 1925, File James G. McDonald, Charles Altschul Papers; Altschul to Goodhart, January 8, 1923, File Arthur Goodhart, Charles Altschul Papers. 5 Altschul to Hammerschlag, September 8,1924, File Paul Hammerschlag 1923-1924, Charles Altschul Files, Altschul Papers. 6Altschul to Simonds, September 12, 1926, File Frank H. Simonds, Charles Altschul Papers. 7 “Statement drawn up on June 19, 1925 by group meeting at the home of Professor James T. Shotwell, 257 West 86th Street, New York, File James T. Shotwell, Charles Altschul Files, Altschul Papers. On this proposal, see also Charles Altschul to Brand, December 21, 1926, File 73/1, Brand Papers; James T. Shotwell, The Autobiography of James T. Shotwell (New York: Bobbs Merrill, 1961), chs. 10-12; Harold Josephson, James T. Shotwell and the Rise of Internationalism in America (Cranbury, NJ: Associated University Presses, 1975), 116-132, 140-176; Patrick O. Cohrs, The Unfinished Peace after World War I: America, Britain and the Stabilisation of Europe 1919-1932 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006), 451-455.
Recommended publications
  • Memorandum of Discussion
    MEMORANDUM OF DISCUSSION A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System in Washington, D. C., on Monday, November 27, 1967, at 9:30 a.m., at the call of Chairman Martin. PRESENT: Mr. Martin, Chairman 1/ Mr. Brimmer Mr. Francis Mr. Maisel Mr. Mitchell Mr. Robertson Mr. Scanlon Mr. Sherrill Mr. Swan Mr. Wayne 1/ Messrs. Ellis, Hickman, and Galusha, Alternate Members of the Federal Open Market Committee Mr. Irons, President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Mr. Holland, Secretary Mr. Sherman, Assistant Secretary Mr. Kenyon, Assistant Secretary Mr. Broida, Assistant Secretary Mr. Hackley, General Counsel Mr. Brill, Economist Messrs. Baughman, Garvy, Hersey, Koch, Partee, and Solomon, Associate Economists Mr. Holmes, Manager, System Open Market Account Mr. Cardon, Legislative Counsel, Board of Governors Mr. Fauver, Assistant to the Board of Governors Mr, Williams, Adviser, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors Mr. Reynolds, Adviser, Division of International Finance, Board of Governors 1/ Left the meeting at the point indicated. 11/27/67 -2 Mr. Axilrod, Associate Adviser, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors Miss Eaton, General Assistant, Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors Miss McWhirter, Analyst, Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors Messrs. Bilby, Eastburn, Mann, Brandt, and Tow, Vice Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks of New York, Philadelphia, Cleveland, Atlanta, and Kansas City, respectively Mr. MacLaury, Assistant Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Mr. Deming, Manager, Securities Department, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Mr.
    [Show full text]
  • Studies in Applied Economics
    SAE./No.128/October 2018 Studies in Applied Economics THE BANK OF FRANCE AND THE GOLD DEPENDENCY: OBSERVATIONS ON THE BANK'S WEEKLY BALANCE SHEETS AND RESERVES, 1898-1940 Robert Yee Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and the Study of Business Enterprise The Bank of France and the Gold Dependency: Observations on the Bank’s Weekly Balance Sheets and Reserves, 1898-1940 Robert Yee Copyright 2018 by Robert Yee. This work may be reproduced or adapted provided that no fee is charged and the proper credit is given to the original source(s). About the Series The Studies in Applied Economics series is under the general direction of Professor Steve H. Hanke, co-director of The Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and the Study of Business Enterprise. About the Author Robert Yee ([email protected]) is a Ph.D. student at Princeton University. Abstract A central bank’s weekly balance sheets give insights into the willingness and ability of a monetary authority to act in times of economic crises. In particular, levels of gold, silver, and foreign-currency reserves, both as a nominal figure and as a percentage of global reserves, prove to be useful in examining changes to an institution’s agenda over time. Using several recently compiled datasets, this study contextualizes the Bank’s financial affairs within a historical framework and argues that the Bank’s active monetary policy of reserve accumulation stemmed from contemporary views concerning economic stability and risk mitigation. Les bilans hebdomadaires d’une banque centrale donnent des vues à la volonté et la capacité d’une autorité monétaire d’agir en crise économique.
    [Show full text]
  • List of Certain Foreign Institutions Classified As Official for Purposes of Reporting on the Treasury International Capital (TIC) Forms
    NOT FOR PUBLICATION DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY JANUARY 2001 Revised Aug. 2002, May 2004, May 2005, May/July 2006, June 2007 List of Certain Foreign Institutions classified as Official for Purposes of Reporting on the Treasury International Capital (TIC) Forms The attached list of foreign institutions, which conform to the definition of foreign official institutions on the Treasury International Capital (TIC) Forms, supersedes all previous lists. The definition of foreign official institutions is: "FOREIGN OFFICIAL INSTITUTIONS (FOI) include the following: 1. Treasuries, including ministries of finance, or corresponding departments of national governments; central banks, including all departments thereof; stabilization funds, including official exchange control offices or other government exchange authorities; and diplomatic and consular establishments and other departments and agencies of national governments. 2. International and regional organizations. 3. Banks, corporations, or other agencies (including development banks and other institutions that are majority-owned by central governments) that are fiscal agents of national governments and perform activities similar to those of a treasury, central bank, stabilization fund, or exchange control authority." Although the attached list includes the major foreign official institutions which have come to the attention of the Federal Reserve Banks and the Department of the Treasury, it does not purport to be exhaustive. Whenever a question arises whether or not an institution should, in accordance with the instructions on the TIC forms, be classified as official, the Federal Reserve Bank with which you file reports should be consulted. It should be noted that the list does not in every case include all alternative names applying to the same institution.
    [Show full text]
  • The Balance Sheet Policy of the Banque De France and the Gold Standard (1880-1914)
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE PRICE OF STABILITY: THE BALANCE SHEET POLICY OF THE BANQUE DE FRANCE AND THE GOLD STANDARD (1880-1914) Guillaume Bazot Michael D. Bordo Eric Monnet Working Paper 20554 http://www.nber.org/papers/w20554 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 October 2014 We are grateful from comments from Vincent Bignon, Rui Esteves, Antoine Parent, Angelo Riva, Philippe de Rougemont, Pierre Sicsic, Paul Sharp, Stefano Ungaro, François Velde, as well as seminar participants at the University of South Danemark, Sciences Po Lyon, Federal Reserve of Atlanta and Banque de France. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Bank of France, the Eurosystem, or the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2014 by Guillaume Bazot, Michael D. Bordo, and Eric Monnet. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. The Price of Stability: The balance sheet policy of the Banque de France and the Gold Standard (1880-1914) Guillaume Bazot, Michael D. Bordo, and Eric Monnet NBER Working Paper No. 20554 October 2014 JEL No. E42,E43,E50,E58,N13,N23 ABSTRACT Under the classical gold standard (1880-1914), the Bank of France maintained a stable discount rate while the Bank of England changed its rate very frequently.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy Rules in the Pre-Emu Era Is There a Common Rule?1
    WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 659 / JULY 2006 MONETARY POLICY RULES IN THE PRE-EMU ERA IS THERE A COMMON RULE? ISSN 1561081-0 by Maria Eleftheriou, Dieter Gerdesmeier 9 771561 081005 and Barbara Roffia WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 659 / JULY 2006 MONETARY POLICY RULES IN THE PRE-EMU ERA IS THERE A COMMON RULE?1 by Maria Eleftheriou 2, Dieter Gerdesmeier and Barbara Roffia 3 In 2006 all ECB publications will feature This paper can be downloaded without charge from a motif taken http://www.ecb.int or from the Social Science Research Network from the €5 banknote. electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=913334 1 The paper does not necessarily reflect views of either the European Central Bank or the European University Institute. 2 European University Institute, Economics Department, e-mail: [email protected]. Supervision and support by Professor Helmut Lütkepohl and Professor Michael J. Artis are gratefully acknowledged. 3 European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany; fax: 0049-69-13445757; e-mail: [email protected] and e-mail: [email protected] Very useful comments by F. Smets and an anonymous referee are gratefully acknowledged. © European Central Bank, 2006 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Internet http://www.ecb.int Fax +49 69 1344 6000 Telex 411 144 ecb d All rights reserved. Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, whether printed or produced electronically, in whole or in part, is permitted only with the explicit written authorisation of the ECB or the author(s).
    [Show full text]
  • The Discount Mechanism in Leading Industrial Countries Since World War Ii
    FUNDAMENTAL REAPPRAISAL OF THE DISCOUNT MECHANISM THE DISCOUNT MECHANISM IN LEADING INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES SINCE WORLD WAR II GEORGE GARVY Prepared for the Steering Committee for the Fundamental Reappraisal of the Discount Mechanism Appointed by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Digitized for FRASER http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The following paper is one of a series prepared by the research staffs of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and of the Federal Reserve Banks and by academic economists in connection with the Fundamental Reappraisal of the Discount Mechanism. The analyses and conclusions set forth are those of the author and do not necessarily indicate concurrence by other members of the research staffs, by the Board of Governors, or by the Federal Reserve Banks. Digitized for FRASER http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis THE DISCOUNT MECHANISM IN LEADING COUNTRIES SINCE WORLD WAR II George Garvy Federal Reserve Bank of New York Contents Pages Foreword 1 Part I The Discount mechanism as a tool of monetary control. Introduction 2 Provision of central bank credit at the initiative of the banks • . , 4 Discounts 9 Advances . , 12 Widening of the range of objectives and tools of monetary policy 15 General contrasts with the United States 21 Rate policy 33 Quantitative controls 39 Selective controls through the discount window 48 Indirect access to the discount window . 50 Uniformity of administration 53 Concluding remarks 54 Part II The discount mechanism in individual countries. Introduction 58 Austria . f 59 Belgium 71 Canada 85 France 98 Federal Republic of Germany 125 Italy 138 Japan 152 Netherlands l66 Sweden 180 Switzerland 190 United Kingdom 201 Digitized for FRASER http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ Federal Reserve Bank of St.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Was Monetary Policy So Inept?
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Great Contraction, 1929–33 Volume Author/Editor: Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz Volume Publisher: Princeton University Press Volume ISBN: 0-691-00350-5 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/frie65-1 Publication Date: 1965 Chapter Title: Why Was Monetary Policy So Inept? Chapter Authors: Milton Friedman, Anna Jacobson Schwartz Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c9280 Chapter pages in book: (p. 111 - 123) THE GREAT c:0NTRAcTI0N 7. Why Was Monetary Pohcy SoIncp:.' We trust that, in light of the preceding sections ofthis chaptet, the adjective used in the heading of this one to characterize monetary policy during the critical period from 1929 to 1933 strikes OUt readersas it does us, as a plain description of fact. The monetarysystem collapsed, hut it clearly need not have done so. The actions required to prevent monetary collapse didnot call for a level of knowledge of the operation of the banking systemor of the work- ings of monetary forces or of economic fluctuations whichwas developed only later and was not available to the Reserve System. Onthe contrary. as we have pointed out earlier, pursuit of the policies outlined by the System itself in the 192O's, or for that matter by Bagehot in 1873,would have prevented the catastrophe. The men'ho established thFederal Reserve System had many misconceptions about monetary theoryand banking operations. It may well be that a policy in accordancewith their understanding of monetary matters would not have preventedthe decline in the stock of mone' from 1929 to the end of 1930.562 But theyunder- For example, H.
    [Show full text]
  • Maximizing Profits Or Pursuing the Public Good? the Bank of Spain As a Central Bank
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Martín Aceña, Pablo; Martínez Ruiz, Elena; Nogués-Marco, Pilar Article Maximizing profits or pursuing the public good? The Bank of Spain as a central bank The Journal of European Economic History Provided in Cooperation with: Associazione Bancaria Italiana, Roma Suggested Citation: Martín Aceña, Pablo; Martínez Ruiz, Elena; Nogués-Marco, Pilar (2020) : Maximizing profits or pursuing the public good? The Bank of Spain as a central bank, The Journal of European Economic History, ISSN 2499-8281, Associazione Bancaria Italiana, Roma, Vol. 49, Iss. 1, pp. 111-140 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/231550 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]
  • The Inability of the Bretton Woods Monetary System and the British Search for a New International Economic Framework in the 1950'S
    Working Paper Series E-2012-01 The inability of the Bretton Woods monetary system and the British Search for a new international economic framework in the 1950's Mei Kudo (Institute of International and Cultural Studies, Tsuda College) ©2012 Mei Kudo. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit is given to the source. 1 The inability of the Bretton Woods monetary system and the British Search for a new international economic framework in the 1950’s1 Mei Kudo (Institute of International and Cultural Studies, Tsuda College) Summary How is the reality of the Bretton Woods system and “embedded liberalism” ideology immediately after the Second World War II? What is the meaning of European integration in relation to the international economic regime? To approach these questions, this paper, taking the two UK proposals of floating rate and sterling convertibility – “Operation Robot” and “Collective Approach” – , argues, because of the ineffectiveness of both Keynesian policy and the IMF, in the 1950’s, some of the UK policy-makers try to apply more market-oriented policy to resolve balance of payments crisis, but rejected by those who thought market solution expose the welfare state in danger. This paper also analyses reaction from the continental Europeans. Although they too recognized the limit of the IMF, and Marjolin was even looking for new Atlantic framework, their idea was not corresponded to the “Collective Approach”. What they want was the convertibility through existing EPU framework, which is more reliable and effective than the IMF.
    [Show full text]
  • Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C
    Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. Effective Lower Bound Risk Timothy S. Hills, Taisuke Nakata, and Sebastian Schmidt 2019-077 Please cite this paper as: Hills, Timothy S., Taisuke Nakata, and Sebastian Schmidt (2019). “Effective Lower Bound Risk," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2019-077. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2019.077. NOTE: Staff working papers in the Finance and Economics Discussion Series (FEDS) are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. The analysis and conclusions set forth are those of the authors and do not indicate concurrence by other members of the research staff or the Board of Governors. References in publications to the Finance and Economics Discussion Series (other than acknowledgement) should be cleared with the author(s) to protect the tentative character of these papers. Effective Lower Bound Risk∗ Timothy Hillsy Taisuke Nakataz Sebastian Schmidtx New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank First Draft: February 2016 This Draft: September 2019 Abstract Even when the policy rate is currently not constrained by its effective lower bound (ELB), the possibility that the policy rate will become constrained in the future lowers today's inflation by creating tail risk in future inflation and thus reducing expected inflation. In an empirically rich model calibrated to match key features of the U.S. economy, we find that the tail risk induced by the ELB causes inflation to undershoot the target rate of 2 percent by as much as 50 basis points at the economy's risky steady state.
    [Show full text]
  • The Federal Reserve's Response to the Global Financial Crisis In
    Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 209 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2014/0209.pdf Unprecedented Actions: The Federal Reserve’s Response to the Global Financial Crisis in Historical Perspective* Frederic S. Mishkin Columbia University and National Bureau of Economic Research Eugene N. White Rutgers University and National Bureau of Economic Research October 2014 Abstract Interventions by the Federal Reserve during the financial crisis of 2007-2009 were generally viewed as unprecedented and in violation of the rules---notably Bagehot’s rule---that a central bank should follow to avoid the time-inconsistency problem and moral hazard. Reviewing the evidence for central banks’ crisis management in the U.S., the U.K. and France from the late nineteenth century to the end of the twentieth century, we find that there were precedents for all of the unusual actions taken by the Fed. When these were successful interventions, they followed contingent and target rules that permitted pre- emptive actions to forestall worse crises but were combined with measures to mitigate moral hazard. JEL codes: E58, G01, N10, N20 * Frederic S. Mishkin, Columbia Business School, 3022 Broadway, Uris Hall 817, New York, NY 10027. 212-854-3488. [email protected]. Eugene N. White, Rutgers University, Department of Economics, New Jersey Hall, 75 Hamilton Street, New Brunswick, NJ 08901. 732-932-7363. [email protected]. Prepared for the conference, “The Federal Reserve System’s Role in the Global Economy: An Historical Perspective” at the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, September 18-19, 2014.
    [Show full text]
  • 494. the Bank of France in Its Relation to National and International
    61ST CONGRESS \ SENATE j DOCUMENT 2d Session j ( No. 494 NATIONAL MONETARY COMMISSION The Bank of France in Its Relation to National and International Credit By MAURICE PATRON Barrister And an Article upon French Savings By ALFRED NEYMARCK Editor of the "Rentier" Washington : Government Printing Office : 1910 Digitized for FRASER http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis NATIONAL MONETARY COMMISSION. NELSON W. ALDRICH, Rhode Island, Chairman. EDWARD B. VREELAND, New York, Vice-Chairman. JULIUS C. BURROWS, Michigan. JESSE OVERSTREET, Indiana. EUGENE HALE, Maine. JOHN W. WEEKS, Massachusetts. PHILANDER C. KNOX, Pennsylvania. ROBERT W. BONYNGE, Colorado. THEODORE E. BURTON, Ohio. SYLVESTER C. SMITH, California. JOHN W. DANIEL, Virginia. LEMUEL P. PADGETT, Tennessee. HENRY M. TELLER, Colorado. GEORGE I?. BURGESS, Texas. HERNANDO D. MONEY, Mississippi. ARS£NE P. PUJO, Louisiana. JOSEPH W. BAILEY, Texas. ARTHUR B. SHELTON, Secretary. A. PiATT ANDREW, Special Assistant to Commission. Digitized for FRASER http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis TABLE OF CONTENTS. THE BANK OF FRANCE IN ITS RELATIONS TO NATIONAL AN& INTERNATIONAL CREDIT. BY MAURICE PATRON. Page. Introduction 7 PRELIMINARY CHAPTER. The Bank of France and its metal holdings: SECTION I.—Cash holdings of the Bank 11 SECTION II.—Immediate results of the dominating position of the Bank 27 PART I. PLACE OF THE BANK OF FRANCE IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE NATIONAL CREDIT 38 Chapter I. Place of the Bank of France in the distribution of credit 40 SECTION I.—Local banks and the financial institutions 40 SECTION II.—In what manner the Bank of France promotes the free distribution of credit in France 46 SECTION III.—In what measure the Bank must control credit-- 50 Conclusion 57 Chapter II.
    [Show full text]