BA Semester IV- Rise of the Moderns West-II (BAHS CC 401) Dr. Mukesh Kumar UNIT-I 17 Century European Crisis

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

BA Semester IV- Rise of the Moderns West-II (BAHS CC 401) Dr. Mukesh Kumar UNIT-I 17 Century European Crisis BA Semester IV- Rise of the Moderns West-II (BAHS CC 401) Dr. Mukesh Kumar UNIT-I 17th Century European Crisis: The two decades of war and occupation in the mid-17th century, which in the case of Lithuania gave a foretaste of the 18th-century partitions, ruined and exhausted the Commonwealth. Famines and epidemics followed hostilities, and the population dropped from roughly 11 to 7 million. The number of inhabitants of Kraków and Warsaw fell by two-thirds and one-half, respectively. Wilno was burned down. The Khmelnytsky uprising decimated the Jews in Ukraine, even if they recovered fairly rapidly demographically. The productivity of agriculture diminished dramatically owing to labour shortages, the destruction of many farm buildings and farming implements, and the loss of numerous cattle. The dynamic network of international trade fairs also collapsed. Grain exports, which had reached their peak in the early 17th century, could not redress the un favourable balance of trade with western Europe. Losses of art treasures the Swedes engaged in systematic looting were irreplaceable. The Commonwealth never fully recovered, unlike Muscovy, which had suffered almost as much during the Time of Troubles. Twentieth-century Marxist historians blamed the manorial economy based on serf labour for pauperizing the masses and undermining the towns, yet the Polish economy was not unique in that respect. Moreover, some attempts to replace serfs with rent-paying tenants did not prove to be a panacea. The economic factor must therefore be treated jointly with other structural weaknesses of the Commonwealth that militated against recovery. The 17th-century crisis a European phenomenon was basically a crisis of political authority. In the Commonwealth the perennial financial weakness was the central issue. The state budget in the second half of the century amounted to 10-11 million złotys, as compared with the equivalent of about 360 million in France or 240 million in England. About nine-tenths of it went for military purposes, compared with half in Brandenburg and more than three-fifths in France and Russia. This was true even after the chastising experience of the Swedish “deluge.” Most nobles contented themselves with invoking the special protection of St. Mary, symbolically crowned queen of Poland, as a sufficient safeguard. Political stagnation Those wishing to reform the state without strengthening the monarchy wanted to make the Sejm an effective centre of power. In 1652 the notorious and often misunderstood practice of liberum veto (free veto) appeared: a single negative vote by a member of the Sejm was considered sufficient to block the proceedings. It was argued that unanimity was essential for passing laws, for deputies, as representatives of the local sejmiki, were bound by instructions. Moreover, a majority could disregard local interests and be corrupted by the administration. Hence, liberum veto came to be regarded as the kernel of liberty and a safeguard against tyranny. In reality, the dissenting deputy was usually an instrument of a magnate or even of the king. The liberum veto could paralyze the functioning of the state, and in the 17th century it was used sparingly. The weakening of the Sejm meant that some of its functions, notably in matters of taxation, had to pass to local sejmiki. Without a central bureaucracy and with a dual structure of offices in the Crown and Lithuania, the fragmentation of sovereignty became increasingly ominous. The attempts at reform by John Casimir and his energetic wife, Marie Louise, may have been ill-conceived, but, given the factional strife within the oligarchy, it was difficult for the monarch to find a stable base of support. The szlachta, ever suspicious of anything that could smack of absolutism, was naturally opposed. The royal plans were defeated by a rokosz in 1665- 66 led by Marshal Jerzy Lubomirski. Two years later the frustrated John Casimir abdicated and settled in France, having prophetically warned the Sejm that Poland would fall victim to its rapacious neighbours unless it reformed its ways. Cultural changes- The prevalent mentality in the Commonwealth in the 17th century manifested itself in Sarmatism. The name came from alleged ancestors of the Sarmatians, and the concept served to integrate the multiethnic nobility. Representing a symbiosis of a political ideology and a lifestyle typical of a landowning, rather provincial, tightly knit, and increasingly xenophobic culture, Sarmatism extolled the virtues of the szlachta and contrasted them with Western values. An Orientalization of Polish-Lithuanian culture (including modes and manners) was occurring. Roman Catholicism was Sarmatized in its turn, assuming a more intolerant posture toward other denominations. The struggles against Lutheran Swedes and Prussians, Orthodox Russians, and Muslim Turks and Tatars strengthened the belief in Poland’s mission as a Catholic bastion. The expulsion in 1658 of Polish Brethren accused of collaboration with the Swedes when taken together with the virtual elimination of non-Catholics from public offices, was the first harbinger of the Pole-Catholic syndrome (the notion that a true Pole must be a Catholic). Decline and attempts at reform The Lubomirski rokosz was barely over and the truce with Muscovy newly signed when the Cossacks in the Polish part of divided Ukraine submitted to Turkey and called for Tatar aid against Poland. Victories won by Hetman Jan (John III) Sobieski only temporarily forestalled the threat, and in 1672 the Commonwealth faced a major invasion by Turkey. The fall of the key border fortress Kamieniec Podolski was followed by the humiliating Peace of Buczacz. The Commonwealth lost the provinces of Podolia and Bratslav and part of Kiev, which remained under Turkish rule for more than 20 years, and it had to pay a tribute to the Sublime Porte. Sobieski’s victory over the Turks at Chocim in 1673 was not exploited, because of the lack of financial means, but it paved the way for Sobieski’s election to the Polish throne. His predecessor, Michael Korybut Wiśniowiecki who had followed John Casimir reigned for only four years (1669-73) and proved utterly incapable. Sobieski, ruling as John III (1674-96), sought to improve Poland’s position and at first considered conquering Prussia in alliance with France. But that plan did not succeed. With the papacy and the Habsburgs preparing for all-out war against Turkey, John reverted to an anti- Turkish policy and concluded an alliance with Austria. In 1683 he led a relief army to a Vienna besieged by the Turks and, as supreme commander of the allied forces, won a resounding victory that marked the beginning of Turkish withdrawal from Europe. The Commonwealth, however, did not share in the subsequent victorious Austrian campaigns. Poland became a secondary partner, and, when the final peace with Turkey was concluded with the Treaty of Carlowitz in 1699, the Poles recovered only the lost Ukrainian lands. By that time John was no longer alive, and Augustus II, the elector of Saxony, had succeeded him on the throne (reigned 1697–1733). The English revolution and preludes to the industrial revolution- Defoe, traversing England in 1722, drew a patriotic picture of “the most flourishing and opulent country in the world,” of green fields and overflowing crops, of pastures rambled by golden fleece, of lush grass turning into plump kine, of peasants roistering in rural sports, squires organizing peasants, nobles organizing squires, lordly manors giving law and discipline to villages, and now and then, refuge to poets and philosophers. Word peddlers tend to idealize the countryside, if they are exempt from its harassments, boredom, insects, and toil. Rural life in the England of 1715 was very much as it had been for a thousand years. Each village almost each household was a self-contained economic unit, growing its own food, making its own clothing, cutting its timber for building and fuel from the adjacent woods. Each family baked its bread, hunted its venison, salted its meat, made its butter, jellies, and cheese. It spun and wove and sewed; it tanned leather and cobbled shoes; it made most of its utensils, implements, and tools. So father, mother, and children found work and expression not only in the summer fields but in the long winter evenings; the home was a hub of industry as well as of agriculture. The wife was an honored mistress of many arts, from nursing her husband and rearing a dozen children to making frocks and brewing ale. She kept and dispensed the household medicines; she took care of the garden, the pigs, and the fowl. Marriage was a union of helpmates; the family was an economic as well as a social organism, and had thereby a solid reason and basis for its unity, multiplication, and permanence. The peasants might have been content with the varied vitality of their homes if they had been allowed to preserve their ancient ways in the fields. They remembered when the landlord had permitted them, or their forebears, to graze their livestock on the manor’s common fields, to fish freely in its streams, to cut wood in its forest; now, by a process begun in the sixteenth century, most of the “commons” had been enclosed by the owners, and the peasants found it hard to make ends meet. There was no serfdom left, and no formal feudal dues; but enterprising landlords, and city merchants investing in land, were farming on a larger scale, with more capital, better implements, greater skill, and wider markets than were available to yeomen tilling their narrow areas. Gregory King had reckoned some 180,000 such freeholders in the England of 1688. Voltaire, about 1730, reported “in England many peasants with 200,000 francs’ worth of property, and who do not disdain to continue cultivating the earth that has enriched them, and in which they live free”; but this may have been propaganda for French stimulation.
Recommended publications
  • New Working Papers Series, Entitled “Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics”
    Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 74 the other canon foundation, Norway Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn Ragnar Nurkse Department of Innovation and Governance CONTACT: Rainer Kattel, [email protected]; Wolfgang Drechsler, [email protected]; Erik S. Reinert, [email protected] 80 Economic Bestsellers before 1850: A Fresh Look at the History of Economic Thought Erik S. Reinert, Kenneth Carpenter, Fernanda A. Reinert, Sophus A. Reinert* MAY 2017 * E. Reinert, Tallinn University of Technology & The Other Canon Foundation, Norway; K. Car- penter, former librarian, Harvard University; F. Reinert, The Other Canon Foundation, Norway; S. Reinert, Harvard Business School. The authors are grateful to Dr. Debra Wallace, Managing Director, Baker Library Services and, Laura Linard, Director of Baker Library Special Collections, at Harvard Business School, where the Historical Collection now houses what was once the Kress Library, for their cooperation in this venture. Above all our thanks go to Olga Mikheeva at Tallinn University of Technology for her very efficient research assistance. Antiquarian book dealers often have more information on economics books than do academics, and our thanks go to Wilhelm Hohmann in Stuttgart, Robert H. Rubin in Brookline MA, Elvira Tasbach in Berlin, and, above all, to Ian Smith in London. We are also grateful for advice from Richard van den Berg, Francesco Boldizzoni, Patrick O’Brien, Alexandre Mendes Cunha, Bertram Schefold and Arild Sæther. Corresponding author [email protected] The core and backbone of this publication consists of the meticulous work of Kenneth Carpenter, librarian of the Kress Library at Harvard Busi- ness School starting in 1968 and later Assistant Director for Research Resources in the Harvard University Library and the Harvard College 1 Library.
    [Show full text]
  • Creating Economy: Merchants in Seventeenth-Century England
    Georgia State University ScholarWorks @ Georgia State University History Theses Department of History 12-11-2017 Creating Economy: Merchants in Seventeenth-Century England Braxton Hall Georgia State University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.gsu.edu/history_theses Recommended Citation Hall, Braxton, "Creating Economy: Merchants in Seventeenth-Century England." Thesis, Georgia State University, 2017. https://scholarworks.gsu.edu/history_theses/116 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Department of History at ScholarWorks @ Georgia State University. It has been accepted for inclusion in History Theses by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks @ Georgia State University. For more information, please contact [email protected]. CREATING ECONOMY: MERCHANTS IN SEVENTEENTH-CENTURY ENGLAND by BRAXTON HALL Under the Direction of Jacob Selwood, PhD ABSTRACT Between 1620 and 1700, merchants in England debated the economic framework of the kingdom. The system they created is commonly referred to as ‘mercantilism’ and many historians have concluded that there was a consensus among economists that supported the balance of trade and restricted foreign markets. While that economic consensus existed, merchants also had to adopt new ways of thinking about religion, foreigners, and naturalization because of the system they created. Merchants like Josiah Child in the latter part of the seventeenth century were more acceptant of strangers and they were more tolerant of religion that their predecessors
    [Show full text]
  • Enlightened Dissent: the Voices of Anti-Imperialism in Eighteenth Century Britain Andrew Victor Gaiero Thesis Submitted to the F
    Enlightened Dissent: The voices of anti-imperialism in eighteenth century Britain Andrew Victor Gaiero Thesis submitted to the Faculty of Graduate and Postdoctoral Studies in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Doctorate in Philosophy degree in History Department of History Faculty of Arts University of Ottawa © Andrew Victor Gaiero, Ottawa, Canada, 2016 ii ABSTRACT “Enlightened Dissent: The voices of anti-imperialism in eighteenth century Britain” Author: Andrew Gaiero Supervisor: Richard Connors Submission Year: 2016 This dissertation explores and analyzes anti-imperial sentiments in Britain throughout the long eighteenth century. During this period of major British state formation and imperial expansion, there were a surprisingly large number of observers who voiced notable and varied concerns and opposition towards numerous overseas ventures, yet who have not since received significant attention within the historical record. Indeed, many critics of British imperialism and empire-building, from within Britain itself, formed extensive and thoughtful assessments of their own nation’s conduct in the world. Criticism ranged widely, from those who opposed the high economic costs of imperial expansion to those worried that a divine retribution would rain down upon Britain for injustices committed by Britons abroad. Such diversity of anti-imperial perspectives came from a clearly enlightened minority, whose limited influences upon broader public opinions had little effect on policies at the time. Successive British administrations and self-interested Britons who sought their fortunes and adventures abroad, often with little regard for the damage inflicted on those whom they encountered, won the political debate over empire- building. However, in the aftermath of the Napoleonic Wars, the perspectives of many of these individuals would increasingly become highly regarded.
    [Show full text]
  • C:\Documents and Settings\John Munro\My
    Prof. John H. Munro [email protected] Department of Economics [email protected] University of Toronto http://www.economics.utoronto.ca/munro5/ Revised: 9 September 2010 ECO 303Y1: The Economic History of Modern Europe, to 1914 Topic No. 2: Early-Modern “Mercantilism”: Money, Economic Nationalism, and the State in Early Modern Europe: READINGS: the more important are indicated by asterisks * Within each of the following sections, readings are listed in the chronological order of original publication, when that can be ascertained, except for some collections of republished essays. A. General Studies on European Mercantilism and International Trade 1. Gustav Schmoller, The Mercantile System and Its Historical Significance (1884; reissued New York, 1967). A classic study, from the 19th-century German ‘historical school.’ * 2. Eli Heckscher, ‘Mercantilism’, Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences, Vol. X (1930; reissued 1937, 1950), pp. 333-39. * 3. Eli Heckscher, Mercantilism, 2 vols., 1st edition, 1931; 2nd edition revised by Heckscher and ed. by E.F. Soderlund, trans. by Mendel Shapiro (London, 1955). (a) Vol. I: Part I: ‘Mercantilism as a Unifying System’, esp. pp. 19-44. (b) Vol.II: Parts II-V. Part II: ‘Mercantilism as a System of Power’, pp. 13-49. Part III: ‘Mercantilism as a System of Protection’, pp. 53-172. * Part IV: ‘Mercantilism as a Monetary System’, pp. 175-66. Part V: ‘Mercantilism as a Conception of Society’, pp. 269-339. * Conclusion: ‘Keynes and Mercantilism’, pp. 340-359. 4. Eli Heckscher, ‘Revisions in Economic History: Mercantilism’, Economic History Review, 1st ser. 7 (1936-37). Republished in: 2 (a) Donald C.
    [Show full text]
  • Mercantilism
    ΕΘΝΙΚΟ & ΚΑΠΟΔΙΣΤΡΙΑΚΟ ΠΑΝΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΙΟ ΑΘΗΝΩΝ ΤΜΗΜΑ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ ΤΟΜΕΑΣ ΠΟΛΙΤΙΚΗΣ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΑΣ Ιστορία Οικονομικών Θεωριών Νίκος Θεοχαράκης Απρίλιος 2010 Ιστοσελίδες για τον Μερκαντιλισμό Bullionists “W.S.” (John Hales d.1571, Sir Thomas Smith ) A Discourse of the Common Weal of this Realm of England, 1581 or A Compendious; Or Briefe Examination of Certayne Ordinary Complaints of Diuers of Our Countrymen in These Our Dayes (Written 1541, not by William Shakespeare despite the 1751 edition) Thomas Milles, c.1550-1627. The Customers Replie, or Second Apologie :…, An Aunswer to a confused Treatise of Publicke Commerce . in favour of the . Merchants Adventurers,' &c., 1604 Gerard de Malynes, c.1586-1641 Saint George for England Allegorically Described, 1601. A Treatise on the Canker of England's Commonwealth, 1601. Consuetudo vel Lex Mercatoria or the Ancient Law- Merchant, 1622. The Maintenance of Free Trade, 1622. The Centre of the Circle of Commerce, 1623. Ν. Θεοχαράκης, ΕΚΠΑ, ΤΟΕ, Μερκαντιλιστές 1/5 Παραδοσιακοί Μερκαντιλιστές John Wheeler, c.1553-1611. Treatise on Commerce, 1601 Edward Misselden, 1608-1654. Free Trade and the Means to Make Trade Flourish, 1622 Circle of Commerce 1623. Thomas Mun, 1571-1641. A Discourse of Trade from England unto the East- Indies, 1621. in England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, 1664. (Written 1628) facsimile Lewis Roberts, 1596 – 1640 The Merchantes Mappe of Commerce , 1638 The Treasure of Traffike, 1640 John Locke, 1632-1704. A Letter Concerning Toleration, 1689. Two Treatises on Government, 1690. An Essay Concerning Human Understanding, 1690. pt 2 Some Considerations of the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and Raising the Value of Money, 1692 Further Considerations Concerning Raising the Value of Money, 1695.
    [Show full text]
  • Download (1MB)
    Swann, Adam (2014) 'Nature’s coyn must not be hoorded': Milton and the economics of salvation, 1634-1674. PhD thesis. http://theses.gla.ac.uk/4823/ Copyright and moral rights for this thesis are retained by the author A copy can be downloaded for personal non-commercial research or study, without prior permission or charge This thesis cannot be reproduced or quoted extensively from without first obtaining permission in writing from the Author The content must not be changed in any way or sold commercially in any format or medium without the formal permission of the Author When referring to this work, full bibliographic details including the author, title, awarding institution and date of the thesis must be given. Glasgow Theses Service http://theses.gla.ac.uk/ [email protected] ‘Nature’s coyn must not be hoorded’: Milton and the Economics of Salvation, 1634-1674 Adam Swann Submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Ph.D. in English Literature School of Critical Studies College of Arts University of Glasgow January 2014 2 Abstract Milton’s use of economic tropes has attracted very little critical attention, and the connections between economics and theology in his thought have not yet been explored. Blair Hoxby’s Mammon’s Music: Literature and Economics in the Age of Milton (2002) focuses on the influence of economic ideas on Milton’s political thought, arguing that the poet persistently associates trade monopolies with autocratic abuses of monarchical power. David Hawkes places Milton’s lifelong professional usury at the centre of his 2009 biography, John Milton: A Hero of Our Time, and his 2011 essay, ‘Milton and Usury,’ fruitfully reads key passages from Paradise Lost in relation to contemporary tracts on usury.
    [Show full text]
  • Cameralism, Capitalism, and the Making of the Modern Economic Mind Philipp Robinson Rössner
    Introduction: Cameralism, Capitalism, and the Making of the Modern Economic Mind Philipp Robinson Rössner Capitalism is often assumed to have been invented in the Anglosphere. Writings by David Hume and Adam Smith have been named as corner- stones in the making of capitalism and modern economic knowledge. But as Alexander von Rüstow, a leading twentieth-century German Ordo-lib- eral thinker argued, during the nineteenth century, Adam Smith’s vision of the market as a natural and God-given order had degenerated into a dark theology of ruthless laissez-faire which, in the German case, had led to the common Schumpeterian perversions of capitalism: high economic inequality, monopoly, and cartelization and national socialism (Rüstow 2009; on economic theology and neoliberalism, see Schwarzkopf 2019). Like Rüstow, however, present-day historians of political economy have tended to miss crucial bits of the story. First, Smith’s and the other Enlight- enment Scots’ works1 built on a commercial tradition that had been mani- fest in Anglo-Saxon economics since the sixteenth century or earlier. Sec- ond, this tradition of thinking about commercial society became quite widespread and in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries extended to the entire European continent, where it became commonly known, at least today, under the name Cameralism. The usual group of suspects starts with mercantilist authors such as Thomas Mun and Gerard de Malynes, earlier Correspondence may be addressed to Philipp Robinson Rössner by email: philipp.roessner@ manchester.ac.uk. I would like to thank Carl Wennerlind and Kevin Hoover for useful comments. 1. On Hume’s economics, see Schabas and Wennerlind 2020.
    [Show full text]
  • The Survival of Aristotelianism in Early English Mercantilism Hengstmengel, Joost
    Tilburg University The survival of Aristotelianism in early English mercantilism Hengstmengel, Joost Published in: Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics DOI: 10.23941/ejpe.v10i1.266 Publication date: 2017 Document Version Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record Link to publication in Tilburg University Research Portal Citation for published version (APA): Hengstmengel, J. (2017). The survival of Aristotelianism in early English mercantilism: An illustration from the debate between Malynes and Misselden. Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics, 10(1), 64-82. https://doi.org/10.23941/ejpe.v10i1.266 General rights Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. • Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain • You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal Take down policy If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim. Download date: 24. sep. 2021 Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics, Volume 10, Issue 1, Spring 2017, pp. 64-82. https://doi.org/ 10.23941/ejpe.v10i1.266 The survival of Aristotelianism in early English mercantilism: an illustration from the debate between Malynes and Misselden JOOST W.
    [Show full text]
  • England's Internal Colonies
    EARLY MODERN CULTURAL STUDIES Ivo J(amps) Series Editor PUBLISHED BY P ALGRAVE MACMILLAN ENGLAND'S INTERNAL COLONIES CLASS, CAPITAL, AND THE Idols of the Marketplace: Idolatry and Commodity Fetishism in English Literature) 1580-1680 LITERATURE OF EARLY MODERN by David Hawkes ENGLISH COLONIALISM Shakespeare among the Animals: Nature and Society in the Drama of Early Modern England by Bruce Boehrer Mark Netzloff Maps and Memory in Early Modern England: A Sense of Place by Rhonda Lemke Sanford Debating Gender in Early Modern England) 1500-1700 edited by Cristina Malcolmson and Mihoko Suzuki Manhood and the Duel: Masculinity in Early Modern Drama and Culture by Jennifer A. Low Burning Women: Widows) Witches) and Early Modern European Travelers in India by Pompa Banerjee England)s Internal Colonies: Class) Capital) and the Literature of Early Modern English Colonialism by Mark Netzloff Turning Turk: English Theater and the Multicultural Mediterranean by Daniel Vitkus Money and the Age of Shakespeare: Essays in New Economic Criticism edited by Linda Woodbridge ENGLAND'S INTERNAL COLONIES © Mark Netzloff, 2003. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be used or reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission except in the case of brief quotations embodied in critical articles or reviews. CONTENTS * First published 2003 by PALGRAVE MACMILLAN™ 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, N.Y. 10010 and Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire, England RG21 6XS Companies and representatives throughout the world PALGRAVE MACMILLAN is the global academic imprint of the Palgrave Macmillan division of St. Martin's Press, LLC and of Palgrave Macmillan Ltd . Illustrations Vll Macmillan® is a registered trademark in the United States, United Kingdom Acknowledgments ix and other countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Merchants and Councilors: Intellectual Divergences in Early 17Th Century British Economic Thought
    Merchants and councilors: intellectual divergences in early 17th century British economic thought Carlos Eduardo Suprinyak Professor do Cedeplar/UFMG Palavras-chave Resumo Abstrac pensamento econômico Durante o início da década de 1620, a Inglater- During the early 1620’s, England went through a pré-clássico, mercantilismo, ra enfrentou um período de intensas dificulda- period of intense economic disorders which sparked século XVII, Inglaterra Stuart, des econômicas que despertou o interesse de the interest of many in economic reasoning. The Thomas Mun. muitos pela reflexão acerca dos fenômenos em decade witnessed the emergence of the most relevant curso. A década testemunhou o surgimento das pieces of economic literature of the early Stuart Classificação JEL B11, B31, mais relevantes obras econômicas do início do era, but the debate was not restricted to the abstract N23. período Stuart; porém, o debate não esteve res- trito às confrontações abstratas dos autores es- confrontation of economic writers. The fundamental pecializados. A questão fundamental em dispu- issue at stake in the controversies between Malynes, ta nas controvérsias entre Malynes, Misselden Misselden, and Mun – the integration of money e Mun – como integrar a moeda e o comércio and international trade in a coherent explanation internacional em uma explicação coerente dos of economic phenomena – was also the subject fenômenos econômicos – foi também objeto of much care in the public sphere at large. The de muita atenção na esfera pública, em senti- parliamentary session of 1621, in particular, put do amplo. A Sessão Parlamentar de 1621, em in evidence not only the fundamental relevance of particular, colocou em evidência não apenas a Key-words the matter for understanding England’s economic relevância fundamental do tema para a com- maladies, but also the great difficulties involved pre-classical economics, preensão dos problemas econômicos da In- th in its investigation.
    [Show full text]
  • An Illustration from the Debate Between Malynes and Misselden
    Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics, Volume 10, Issue 1, Spring 2017, pp. 64-82. https://doi.org/ 10.23941/ejpe.v10i1.266 The survival of Aristotelianism in early English mercantilism: an illustration from the debate between Malynes and Misselden JOOST W. HENGSTMENGEL Tilburg University Abstract: Handbooks of the history of economic thought typically assume a strict fault line between scholastic economics and mercantilism. Historically, the distinction between the two streams of thought was less evident—especially when it came to the style of argumentation, in which there is much continuity between the scholastic doctors and early mercantilists. However, although the latter did not employ the scholastic method, both traditions frequently called upon classical authorities to strengthen their arguments. What is striking is the high regard for Aristotle among the late-sixteenth and early- seventeenth century English mercantilists. By way of illustration, this article reviews the surprising role of Aristotelian ideas, primarily from the Metaphysics and Physics, within the debate between Gerard Malynes and Edward Misselden on England’s economics crisis. Keywords: Aristotle, Aristotelianism, mercantilism, Malynes, Misselden JEL Classification: B11, B31 I. INTRODUCTION Of the handbooks on the history of economic thought that do pay attention to the ‘prehistory’ of economics, most assume a strict fault line between scholastic economics and mercantilism. Late medieval and early-modern economic thought literally comprise different chapters in the subject’s history. Of course, there are many good reasons for regarding these traditions separately. Anyone who has glanced at the economic writings from the successive periods is struck by manifest differences, which is AUTHOR’S NOTE: Previous versions of this paper were discussed in Rotterdam at the 2013 OZSW conference and a PhD seminar at the Erasmus Institute for Philosophy and Economics in November 2013.
    [Show full text]
  • Classical Economics Today: Essays in Honor of Alessandro Roncaglia
    i Classical Economics Today ii ANTHEM OTHER CANON ECONOMICS The Anthem Other Canon Economics series is a collaboration between Anthem Press and The Other Canon Foundation. The Other Canon— also described as “reality economics”— studies the economy as a real object rather than as the behavior of a model economy based on core axioms, assumptions and techniques. The series includes both classical and contemporary works in this tradition, spanning evolutionary, institutional and post- Keynesian economics, the history of economic thought and economic policy, economic sociology and technology governance, and works on the theory of uneven development and in the tradition of the German historical school. Series Editors Erik S. Reinert— Chairman, The Other Canon Foundation, Norway and Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia Rainer Kattel— Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia Wolfgang Drechsler— Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia Editorial Board Ha- Joon Chang— University of Cambridge, UK Mario Cimoli— UN- ECLAC, Chile Jayati Ghosh— Jawaharlal Nehru University, India Steven Kaplan— Cornell University, USA, and University of Versailles, France Jan Kregel—Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, USA, and Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia Bengt- Åke Lundvall— Aalborg University, Denmark Richard Nelson— Columbia University, USA Keith Nurse— University of the West Indies, Barbados Patrick O’Brien— London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE), UK Carlota Perez—London School of Economics, Technological University of Tallinn,
    [Show full text]