<<

Manufacturing Revolutions: Industrial Policy and Industrialization in South Korea*

Nathan Lane†

Current Version: September 2021 [First Draft: October 2016]

Abstract

I study the impact of industrial policy on industrial development by considering a canonical intervention. Following a political crisis, South Korea dramatically altered its development strategy with a sector-specific industrial policy: the Heavy and Chemical Industry (HCI) drive, 1973-1979. With newly assembled data, I use the sharp introduction and withdrawal of industrial policies to study the impacts of industrial policy—during and after the intervention period. I show (1) HCI promoted the expansion and dynamic comparative advantage of directly targeted industries. (2) Using variation in exposure to policies through the input-output network, I show HCI indirectly benefited downstream users of targeted intermediates. (3) I find direct and indirect benefits of HCI persisted even after the end of HCI, following the 1979 assassination of the president. These effects include the eventual development of directly targeted exporters and their downstream counterparts. Together, my findings suggest that the temporary drive shifted Korean manufacturing into more advanced markets and created durable industrial change. These findings clarify lessons drawn from South Korea and the East Asian growth miracle. JEL: L5 O14 O25 N6. Keywords: industrial policy, East Asian miracle, , industrial development, Heavy-Chemical Industry Drive, Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive.

1 Introduction

Miracles by nature are mysterious. The forces behind the East Asian growth miracle are no exception. Industrial policy (IP) has defined Asia’s striking postwar transformation (Rodrik 1995). The ambitious

*I benefited from conversations with , Robert Allen, Sam Bazzi, Sascha O. Becker, Nils Bohr, Timo Bop- part, David Cole, Arin Dube, Samantha Eyler-Driscoll, Alice Evans, Mounir Karadja, Max Kasy, Oliver Kim, Changkeun Lee, Weijia Li, Ernest Liu, Andreas Madestam, Javier Mejia, Matti Mitrunen, Aldo Musacchio, Suresh Naidu, Nathan Nunn, Veronica Perez, Dwight Perkins, Pseudorasmus, Erik Prawitz, Pablo Querubin, Dani Rodrik, Martin Rotemberg, Todd Tucker, Eric Verhoogen, Robert Wade, and Lisa Xu. I would like to thank audiences at American University, Australia Na- tional University Economics, Australia National University—Crawford School, CSAE Oxford, College de France, Geneva Graduate Institute Blended Finance Conference, EBRD, European Econometric Society Summer and Winter Meetings, Har- vard, IMT Lucca, Institute of New Structural Economics–Peking University, INSEAD, Kellogg School of Management, Ko- rean Development Institute, LSE ID, MIT, NBER SI, Nottingham University, NYU-Abu Dhabi, Univ. of Oxford, OzClio, Seoul National University, Sussex University, UMASS–Amherst, University of Melbourne, UNSW, University of Technology Sydney, and University of Wollongong for their helpful comments. I would especially like to thank my committee: Melissa Dell, Torsten Persson, James Robinson, and David Stromberg. This study was made possible with excellent assistance from Kim Chan, BoSuk Hong, Veronic Perez, Cheong Yeon Won, and Hye Jin Won. I would also like to thank the staff of the Bank of Korea and the Korean Development Institute. † and SoDa Labs (Monash). See nathanlane.info or contact me at [email protected]

1 development strategies pursued across this region have shaped global industrial strategy, from Southeast Asia to Sub-Saharan Africa (Rodrik 2005; Robinson 2010; Lin 2012). With rare exception, every developing country has pursued some type of IP intervention. Early development economists argued that these strategies play a fundamental role in industrialization (Rosenstein-Rodan 1943; Hirschman 1958). Others argued IP is inherently deleterious (Baldwin 1969; Krueger 1990), and its role in East Asia was counterproductive (Pack 2000). While industrial policies have re-entered the broader policy arena, empirical evidence surrounding their failures and successes in the developing world is scant.1 This holds for an episode associated with their use, the East Asian miracle.

South Korea embodied the transformation of East Asian economies. The economy entered the 1960s as an un- stable industrial laggard. By the 1980s it had undergone a manufacturing transformation that had taken West- ern nations over a century to achieve (Nelson and Pack 1998).2 How did South Korea transition from a light export economy to an industrial powerhouse?

I explore the role of industrial policy in Korea’s transformation. By industrial policy, or IP, I mean something specific: deliberate state action intended to shift the composition of national economic activity (Lindbeck 1981; Chang 2003; Noland and Pack 2003). In developing countries, like South Korea in the 1980s, this shift is hoped to be growth enhancing. To study IP I turn to a key South Korean intervention that sought to change the in- dustrial trajectory of the small, open economy.

The policy in question is South Korea’s Heavy and Chemical Industry (HCI) drive, 1973 to 1979. HCI was a definitive postwar industrial strategy. In some dimensions, such as its emphasis on industry spillovers and capital accumulation, HCI shared similarities with early postwar policy-making (Rosenstein-Rodan 1943; Nurkse 1953). In other dimensions, it was synonymous with the East Asian miracle (Vogel 1991). Its outward orientation resembled policies pursued by contemporaries. HCI was itself inspired by Japan’s earlier policy, and resembled contemporaries, like Taiwan (Cheng 1990, 2001). Korea’s own industrial drive influenced strategies across the globe, as economies, such as Malaysia, “looked east” for developmental templates. The varied record of imitators, however, has fueled HCI’s notoriety.3 Among industrial policies, HCI looms large.

This study aims hopes to address some empirical issues surrounding industrial policy. Like many controver- sial East Asian policies—and infant industry policy broadly—evidence around its efficacy is incomplete (Lane 2020). This study confronts two challenges that complicate analysis of infant industry IP, in particular research design. Using newly assembled data, I also confront empirical obstacles to studying the East Asian miracle.

For over a century economists have discussed the empirical obstacles to studying industrial policy (Meredith 1906; Grubel 1966). Theoretically, most optimal policies are temporary, and justifications rely on assisting sec- tors with either dynamic comparative advantage (Greenwald and Stiglitz 2006) and (or) spillovers (for exam- ple, inter-industry linkages or across firm learning) (Hirschman 1958; Grossman 1990). Tests of theoretical jus- tifications, however, are moot against many unobserved political realities surrounding IP (Rodrik 2005, 2012). These political confounders mean that IP often goes to sub-optimal and politically motivated recipients. These same political realities also mean that IP is seldom temporary (Juhasz 2018). Last, political confounders mean that de jure sectoral policy may not translate into de facto policy. For these reasons, I argue that the HCI context provides an important vehicle for studying the impact of industrial policy on industrial development.

I use variation introduced by South Korea’s HCI episode to estimate the impact of purposeful IP on short-run, as well as persistent, Korean industrial development. I do so by using variation introduced by the HCI context.

1Recent contributions exceptions are discussed below. See Lane (2020) for review of the current empirical literature and policies. 2According to the Penn World Tables, in 1960 South Korea’s per capita national income lagged behind Cameroon, the Central African Republic, Haiti, Madagascar, Morocco, Niger, and Tanzania (Werlin 1991; Feenstra, Inklaar, and Timmer 2015). 3For global experience of HCI-style policies, see Kim et al. (2013); Moreira (1994); Lall (1995); Lall (1996).

2 I argue that external politics precipitated HCI’s start in 1973 and its termination in 1979. President Nixon’s promise to withdraw U.S. forces from the Asia-Pacific area shook regional allies. Like Southern Vietnam, the Republic of Korea relied on U.S. support against Communist-backed North. Washington’s about-face catalyzed South Korea to incubate a heavy industrial complex. Rigorously implemented under the duress of crisis, the drive targeted strategic, yet feasible, infant industries (Stern et al. 1995; B.-k. Kim and Vogel 2011). However, this drive was temporary. The assassination of the president in 1979 ended his regime’s core project. I argue this variation is a useful natural experiment for estimating the impacts of IP on Korea’s industrial development.

Studying the HCI experience entails constructing new data on industrial outcomes spanning South Korea’s miracle period (1967-1986). I do so by harmonizing material from archival sources, digitized industrial sur- veys, and vintage machine-readable statistics into consistent panel data. Importantly, I combine industry-level data with digitized input-output accounts. The result is a data set spanning a key episode of East Asian devel- opment.

HCI’s setting provides an estimation strategy. I study the impact of IP by comparing changes in outcomes between targeted versus non-targeted manufacturing industries each year, before and after, the HCI announcement. This dynamic differences-in-differences (DID) strategy captures the impacts of HCI policies (investment incentives and trade policy). Pre-trends represent Korea’s counterfactual sectoral structure. Absent these interventions, industries would have evolved according to their pre-1973 pattern—or static comparative advantage. Post-1973 differences reveal the efficacy of IP in promoting sectors where South Korea had unrealized potential—or latent comparative advantage. I estimate these impacts using traditional two-way fixed effect (TWFE) estimators, as well new semiparametric estimation procedures (Callaway and Sant’Anna 2020; Sant’Anna and Zhao 2020).

My empirical strategy allows me to examine two principal justifications of industrial policy (See: Krueger and Tuncer 1982). First, by comparing the evolution of treated versus non-treated industries after Park’s assassina- tion, I confirm if that infant industry interventions were durable. In fact, I show some aspects of the drive only fully emerge after the policy drive. In doing so, I test for the dynamic impacts of IP. Second, another motiva- tion for IP is that benefits accrue to industries external to treated sectors. I explore this by estimating the im- pact of IP on industries differentially exposed to targeted sectors through industrial linkages. With measures constructed from historical input-output accounts, I compare the evolution of (non-targeted) industries with weak links to industries with strong linkages to HCI sectors.

I highlight three findings. First, I show significant, positive impacts of IP across industrial development out- comes in targeted (treated) industries. Relative to pre-HCI levels, HCI industries expanded their output over 100 percent more than non-treated sectors; labor productivity is over 60 percent higher. I show the relative ex- pansion of HCI industry does not result from a decline in non-treated industries. I find significant effects of IP on employment growth and export performance, and show output prices were 10 percent lower for HCI industry after 1973.

Second, the impact of HCI on industrial transformation is durable, and HCI promotes the long-run, dynamic comparative advantage of targeted export industry. Post-1979, industrial development outcomes—such as the share of economic activity—remained significantly higher compared to counterfactual industry. Moreover, HCI targeting is associated with the striking expansion of export industry. I estimate that HCI products were 13 percent more likely to achieve comparative advantage in global export markets after 1973. The revealed comparative advantage of HCI products increased 30 percent more than other manufacturing exports over the same period. Event study estimates show this ascent came to a head after the end of the policy. Hence, policies may have dynamic, long-run benefits beyond the planning period.

3 Third, HCI policies positively impacted the development of external, downstream industry, and promoted longer-run comparative advantage among downstream exporters. Downstream sectors with strong linkages to HCI industry expanded during the HCI period. During the drive, comparative advantage emerged among downstream exporters, yet the advantage fully materialized after 1979. Conversely, I show the backward- linkage effects of IP were, at best, limited. Thus, I find HCI supported development through supply-side effects passed through forward linkages. This comports with recent work on optimal interventions in networks by Liu (2019), who uses data from this paper to show that upstream sectors targeted by Korea correspond to sufficient statistics for industrial targeting.

Additionally, I show policies defy some characterizations of East Asian industrial policies and HCI. I do not find that HCI relied on strong, nominal trade barriers to protect output markets. Moreover, I do not find that HCI resembled import substitution (ISI) policies to which it has been compared. Rather, I find the HCI bundle likely operated through investment subsidies, promoting the capital formation and financing intermediates in targeted industry.

With these results I contribute to three literature. First, I build on nascent studies which use contemporary econometrics to study the efficacy of IP. This includes Nunn and Trefler (2010)’s work on structure of trade policy and industrial development, and recent country case-studies by Aghion et al. (2015) and Criscuolo et al. (2019). A complementary, parallel literature in empirical IO has begun articulating a structural framework for analyzing sector-specific policy bundles (see thoughtful work by Kalouptsidi (2018) and Barwick, Kalouptsidi, and Zahur (2019)).4 In development, work by Rotemberg (2017) and Martin, Nataraj, and Harrison (2017) have explored issues at the heart of IP through the experience of Indian SME policy. Though industrial policy is ubiquitous in practice, the literature remains notoriously underdeveloped (Lane 2020).

I contribute to the empirical study of industrial policy through natural experiments and historical case studies. I join Juhasz (2018), who uses Napoleonic Blockade to test for infant industry policy in historical France. Related work by Inwood and Keay (2013) and Harris, Keay, and Lewis (2015) study the developmental effects of output market protection with Canada’s early tariff experiments. Like this work, I find long-run effects of industrial policy, but in a contemporary setting and through contemporary export-oriented policies . These results dovetail with work studying dynamic comparative advantage and temporary natural experiments (Hanlon 2020; Mitrunen 2019; Pons-Benaiges 2017).5 Thus, I join historical work highlighting the potential of transitory policy to promote the evolution of “sunrise” industry. I do so by examining a purposeful, targeted intervention in a modern context. In analyzing intentionally targeted policies, I speak to a growing body of work evaluating place-based IP, which uses variation introduced by institutional aspects of policy. Notably, Criscuolo et al. (2019), use exogenous variation to study the impact of IP support targeted at lagging (UK) geographies; and Becker, Egger, and Ehrlich (2010) for lagging EU industry. I show the impact of policies aimed at sunrise industries in a (former) developing country setting, rather than lagging regions.

Second, I contribute to unresolved debates on the role of industrial policy and development, specifically con- troversies around East Asian miracle. Influential qualitative work emphasized the role of IP in newly industri- alizing economies.6 Wade (1990) and Amsden (1992) argue IP was vital to Taiwan’s and South Korea’s ascent. A sizable economics literature emphasized the implicit flaws of infant industry interventions (Baldwin 1969; Krueger 1990; Lal 1983).7 Economists challenged the lessons gleaned from East Asia, specifically with respect to targeting (Weinstein 1995; El-Agraa 1997; Lawrence and Weinstein 1999). Krueger (1995) and Pack (2000)

4Kalouptsidi (2018) shows the potential to use theoretically-grounded inference to detect commonly unobserved indus- trial policies. This IO literature shares likeness with an the earlier “new trade” literature, which used calibration exercises to study the impacts of infantry industry interventions (Baldwin and Krugman 1988; Head 1994; Irwin 2000). 5Hanlon (2020) studies the initial cost advantages of early steel shipbuilders, while Mitrunen (2019) examines the im- pact of Stalin’s export reparations policy on Finnish industry. For temporary government procurement policy, technology and managerial training, see Jaworski and Smyth (2018) and Giorcelli (2019). 6The qualitative literature is vast. See seminal work by Johnson (1982); Wade (1990); Vogel (1991); Amsden (1992); Evans (1995); Chibber (2002); and Kohli (2004) 7See: extensive critical discussions by Pack and Saggi (2006) and Noland and Pack (2003).

4 contend newly industrialized countries developed despite industrial strategy. Yoo (1990) argues HCI may have, in fact, harmed South Korea’s export performance relative to contemporaries.

Correlation studies of East Asia have shown a negative relationship between interventions and industry devel- opment, and argue that IP did not target high-spillover sectors (Lee 1996; Beason and Weinstein 1996; Noland 2004).8 My study parallels macro-theoretical contributions by Liu (2019); alongside his work, my results sug- gest that Korean targeting may not have been incoherent.My study is a first attempt to reconcile the debate in East Asia miracle with modern causal tools.

Third, I contribute to the discussion on the role of the state and development (Besley and Persson 2010, 2011; Dell, Lane, and Querubin 2018; Acemoglu et al. 2015)—especially their role in promoting industrial change (Kohli 2004). Using Vietnamese history as a case study, my work with Dell, Lane, and Querubin (2018) explores the effect of the Weberian state and its capacity to implement successful developmental policy in East versus Southeast Asia.

In sum, this study attempts to discipline a key episode of industrial policy with the toolbox of causal infer- ence. The goal is to structure coherent insights around a key, historical case of industrial transformation. By doing so, I hope to extract coherent workings of the policy—those that are useful more broadly—and to em- phasize a more empirically-grounded narrative around East Asian interventions.

I organize my study in the following way. First, section 2 discusses the institutional and historical setting of the HCI drive. Second, section 3 describes the data construction effort. Section 4 presents estimates of the di- rect impact of industrial policies on targeted industries. Section 5 turns to estimates of HCI’s spillovers into external sectors via input-output linkages. Last, section 6 concludes with a discussion of these findings.

2 Institutional Context and Political Variation

I use the historical and institutional details of South Korea’s HCI drive, which I use to identify the impact of IP in the proceeding sections (section 4). I focus on three aspects of the context: first, the geopolitical crisis that shifted in Korea’s development strategy and catalyzed HCI. Second, I detail the policy instruments that consti- tuted the intervention. Last, I describe the withdrawal of these policies, following President Park’s assassina- tion in 1979.

A) External Political Drivers A political crisis propelled South Korea’s HCI drive, which was fundamentally security driven.9 Events in the late 1960s and early 1970s created a political impasse. The first, was a sharp change in U.S. foreign policy in Asia and North Korea’s militarization (Kim 1997; Moon and Lee 2009). In 1969, President Nixon announced the end of direct U.S. military support for Asia-Pacific allies. This “Nixon Doctrine” effectively ended decades of large-scale military presence in the region. South Korea, an anti-Communist stalwart, was shocked. U.S. disengagement created the risk of full U.S. troop withdrawal from the Korean Peninsula (Nixon 1969; Kim 1970; Kwak 2003). Like their South Vietnamese allies, South Korea believed they would need to defend against a more militarized, Communist-backed neighbor. Further historical context for the nature of the “Nixon shock” is provided in the history section of the Online Appendix, including sources as to the surprise, shock-like nature of the intervention in historical literature.

8For Korea, Lee (1996) finds a negative relationship between postwar IP interventions and industry-level outcomes. Thoughtful work by Beason and Weinstein (1996) argues Japanese IP was not positively related to industry development, nor directed at sectors with scale economies. Noland (2004) similarly argues Korean policy did not target sectors with high spillovers (linkages). 9The security pretext of the policy is widely documented. “When President Richard M. Nixon declared his Guam Doc- trine in 1969 to initiate U.S. military disengagement from Asia, Park’s fear of the Americans’ departure pushed him to initi- ate an aggressive HCI drive to develop a defense industry by 1973” (Moon and Jun 2011, 119). See H.-A. Kim (2011) for HCI and the evolution of defense industry.

5 Figure 1: Political Events Surrounding HCI - US Withdrawal and Korean Provocations

Panel A) South Korean Articles on DPRK Provocations, Panel B) Mentions of U.S. Troop Withdrawal from South Korea, Top Domestic Newspapers Share of Annual Stories in New York Times 400

0.03

300

0.02 200 Number of Articles

(Major Newspapers) 0.01 100 Share of Articles Published x 100 Share

0 0.00

1961 1969 1973 1978 1961 1969 1973 1978 HCI HCI Nixon's Nixon's

Announcment Announcment

Notes: Figure shows the military−political crisis facing South Korea vis−a−vis U.S. and South Korean newspaper reporting. Panel A (left) shows the number of articles (count) in Donga and Kyunghyang newspapers matching a Korean−language dictionary of 'provocation' keywords (examples in text). I provide a list of Korean−language terms in the Online Appendix, which also details the selection of these terms using ‘‘‘word2vector‘‘‘−style models. The count includes articles matching dictionary terms that appear before page 5. The 'provocation' count in panel B matches the same count by Choi (1989) of DPRK actions violating the Korean War armistace, shown in Figure 1 of Online Appendix. Panel B (right) shows the share of New York Times news stories referring to troop withdrawal. Share is measured as the total number of full− text article hits divided by number of stories published (times 100). The search term used is 'South Korea+Troop Withdrawal', via The New York Times Lab API.

Figure 1 panel B plots coverage of U.S. troop withdrawal in the American press, measured as the share of New York Times articles containing “South Korea” and “troop withdrawal.” The first hump appears around 1970, corresponding to confirmation of American withdrawal from the peninsula. Crystallization of the withdrawal “profoundly” shocked the Park administration, who expected exemptions from Nixon’s doctrine [Trager (1972); Rogers (1970); Nixon (1970); Kwak (2003); p.34]. News attention grew through the 1971 pullout (24,000 troops, three air force battalions) from the peninsula which was seen as only the beginning of US demobilization. The second jump in panel Fig. 1 corresponds to the 1976 U.S. presidential campaign, and Jimmy Carter’s promise to end U.S. military assistance to Park. A critic of Korea’s human rights record, Carter reaffirmed his commitment after his election (Han 1978; Taylor, Smith, and Mazarr 1990; Lee 2011).10

Shifts in U.S. foreign policy came at a critical juncture for South Korea. The threat of withdrawal coincided with the militarization of North Korea and renewed provocations (Ostermann and Person 2011). Panel A of Figure 1 reports increasing antagonism by North Korea surrounding Nixon’s announcement, as reported by South Korean media. Using the full-text archive of large Korean newspapers, Dong-A Ilbo and Kyunghyang Shinmun, panel A plots the number of articles reporting on North Korean provocations. This count is constructed using a dictionary of Korean-language keywords for military antagonism (e.g. 도발(provocation), 교전(engagement), 남침(invasion of the South), 침투(infiltration), 폭파 (explosion), 포격(shelling)). The construction of this dictionary—using seed terms along with a word2vec-style model—is described in the Online Appendix. Importantly, the trends shown in panel A align with hand-collected data on military altercations by Choi and Lee (1989), shown in Figure 1 of the Online Appendix.11

10HCI’s pretext was “magnified by the Carter administration’s plan to completely withdraw U.S. ground forces.” (Kim, Shim, and Kim 1995, 186). Park’s eventual assassination complicated Carter’s commitment. 11Older versions of the paper used this data, but I turned to NLP tools since North Korea’s escalation looked quite extreme. Nevertheless, both charts supported one another.

6 Panel A conveys the wave of attacks launched by the DPRK following Nixon’s announcement, and the rising tensions before the HCI announcement in 1973. Starting in the late 1960s, South Korea experienced a string of high-profile security emergencies (Scobell and Sanford 2007).12 In the early 1970s the DPRK rivaled the South militarily. The North emerged from the Korean War with an industrial advantage, and since the 1960s pursued a total military-industrialization campaign (Hamm 1999). Relying on U.S. military support, South Korea had not done the same. During the events shown in Figure 1, South Korea had no domestic arms industry, nor the scale of industry to support it. Without U.S. troops, South Korea relied on vintage arms, and stocks incapable of absorbing a DPRK blitz (Cushman 1979; Eberstadt 1999).

These military-industrial deficiencies drove HCI policy, both in the timing and sectoral scope of policy, which I turn to now.

B) Sectoral Choice The HCI drive was announced on January 12, 1973, after a period of covert planning.13. The HCI plan is often conflated with Korea’s Third Five Year Economic Development Plan (1972-1976), which the HCI announcement effectively interrupted (Lee 1991). Using investment incentives and trade policy, HCI targeted six broad classes of strategic industry: steel, non-ferrous metals, shipbuilding, machinery, electronics, and petrochemicals (ibid; Stern et al. 1995). Table A2 lists translated names for harmonized 5-digit industries that fell under HCI priority sectors.

Two concerns dominated the choice of industry. First, HCI sectors were necessary if South Korea was to pursue military-industrial modernization, in anticipation of a future without U.S. military presence (Woo- Cumings 1998; H.-A. Kim 2011). Upstream heavy industries were the linchpin. For the Park regime, inputs like steel embodied one such critical industry (Rhyu and Lew 2011). Before 1973, the economy lacked inputs to develop a military-industrial base comparable to North Korea, which was endowed with heavy industry and pursued Communist-supported militarization. Early forays into arms manufacturing in the South were unsuccessful, with “inadequate materials and the lack of precision production. Koreans realized the critical importance of creating a more advanced industrial base” [Horikane (2005); p.375].

Second, crisis compelled Korea to choose wisely. Technocratic planning limited IP to a set of viable target sec- tors, and HCI planners used feasibility studies to winnow the scope of policies (Stern et al. 1995).14 In doing so, the regime carefully studied the industrial strategies of other small open economies (Perkins 2013). Fur- ther historical details on Korea’s technocratic planning are also provided in the History section of the Online Appendix.

Korea attempted to choose sectors for which it had a latent comparative advantage. To this end, planners saw the economy as akin to Japan—lagged. In fact, Japan’s experience was less a metaphor than a blueprint. For instance, the New Long-Range Economic Plan of Japan (1958–68) was one such technocratic blueprint, and Japan’s experience gave South Korea a template of sectors for which they had potential (Kong 2000; Moon and Jun 2011).15

C) HCI Policy Levers and Temporal Variation The HCI drive was a shift in South Korean economic policy, from generalist to targeted. Before 1973, Korea pursued a broad, export promotion development strategy

12By 1971, U.S. officials warned “our front-line is a half step before crisis” [Kim (2001); p.55]. 13See extensive treatments by Horikane (2005) and H.-A. Kim (2011) 14Jet engines and missiles, for example, were rejected as beyond their capability. For South Korea’s planning bureau- cracy, see Adelman (1969). “Planning” here refers to indicative (not central) planning inspired by France, West Germany, and Japan. 15Beyond steel and metals, shipbuilding is an example of using Japan to justify sectoral choice. “Korea found in Japan’s shipbuilding industry a cynosure” argues Woo (1991), were “the Korean strategy to promote shipbuilding was very simply a carbon copy of Japan’s” (p.137). Government documents from 1973 “dutifully note Japan’s export performance in 1955-71 and its composition of manufactures” [Kim and Leipziger (1993); p.18-19].

7 (Krueger 1979; Westphal and Kim 1982; Westphal 1990).16 The HCI-era, in contrast, was decidedly industry specific and surgical.

These surgical policies can be summarized in two broad categories: investment and production-type incen- tives, and trade policy. Investment incentives were a critical policy ingredient, notably credit for inputs and capital formation (see: Woo 1991). Starting in 1974, the National Investment Fund (NIF) promoted long-term investment with subsidized loans to HCI sectors (Koo 1984; Kim 2005).17 These “policy-oriented” loans were lent through commercial banks and state-run development banks (Koo 1984).

Figure (left) A1 shows the pattern—and volume—of lending by a key NIF lender, the Korea Development Bank (KDB), before and during HCI. The plot shows the differential pattern of lending between sectors (2-digit level). Targeted sectors are shown in red. Non-targeted are shown in black. KDB-NIF lending in Figure (left) A1 is only representative of the trend in lending however. A great deal of which was still done through the commercial banking system, which, by the HCI period, had come under various forms of state control. The line “between commercial and specialized banks [like those in Fig. A1] became blurred and both served as instruments” for government directed credit [Cho (1989); p.93].

The right panel of Figure A1 provides another view of incentives over the HCI period, and conveys differ- ences in the cost of capital across sectors. Specifically, the right panel plots estimates of effective tax rates on the returns to capital, accounting for the package of industry-specific subsidies through the HCI drive (calculated by Kwack 1985; Stern et al. 1995). Thick lines show average rates in HCI versus non-HCI sectors. Thin lines are average rates disaggregated at the 2-digit industry level. Post-1973, the rates across industries diverge markedly, reflecting the HCI drive’s sectoral bias (Kwack 1984; Kim 1990).18

Second, trade policy shifted from general export promotion to HCI promotion. Pre-1973, exporters enjoyed a “virtual free trade regime” and were exempted from a number of import restrictions on inputs (Nam 1980; Westphal 1990). HCI ended this early program, eliminating the allowances and import subsidies granted, broadly, to exporters. Post-1973, however, HCI industries enjoyed 1960s-style import assistance and exemptions (Woo 1991; Cho and Kim 1995). For example, HCI producers were exempted from up to 100 percent of duties and tariffs on imports.19

HCI had an unexpected expiration date. On October 26, 1979, President Park was assassinated by Korean Cen- tral Intelligence Agency director, Kim Jae-kyu. The assassination ended Park’s regime and its keystone indus- trial drive (Cho and Kim 1995; Lee 1980). The successor regime rejected the dirigisme of the Park era and ratio- nalized HCI policy in repeated rounds of economic liberalization.20

Thus, post-1979, South Korea dismantled HCI incentives, pursuing “investment adjustment” for targeted sectors and further trade liberalization (Kim 1988, 1994; Kim and Leipziger 1993). The import liberalization ratio climbed from 68.6 in 1979 to 76.6 by 1982, and restrictions were further reductions between 1982 and

16Conditional on manufacturing, this policy was broad. As these export incentives “were administered uniformly across all industries” [Westphal and Kim (1982); p.217-218]. For example, the main role of credit policies “was to support export ‘activity’ rather than specific industries” [Cho (1989); p.93]. 17The NIF was largely funded through bond sales of financial institutions. According to Byung-kook Kim, “NIF was an outright forced savings program,” selling bonds on public non-banking institutions and then requiring 8 percent of wage income to be levied into pensions [B.-k. Kim and Vogel (2011); p.226]. 18Previous export tax incentives “no longer played a central role compared to that played by [the] industry incentive scheme,” which directed investment to “a relatively small number of industries” [Trela and Whalley (1990); p.19]. “Spe- cial Tax Treatment for Key Industries” under the Tax Exemption and Reduction Control Law was one such example of HCI investment incentives. 19According to Park (1977)’s calculation for the period “key industries,” on average, enjoyed 80 percent tariff exemptions across industries (with the exception of petrochemicals) (p.212). Meanwhile, HCI exporters were allowed to purchase inputs from foreign investors and licensors (Castley (1997)). 20HCI was not without its cracks. Earlier in 1979, the government had announced the “Comprehensive Stabilization Pro- gram,” in efforts to address the apparent macroeconomic instability brought on by turbulent world economic conditions and exacerbated by HCI lending. Nevertheless, Park’s removal meant wide scale retrenchment of HCI in earnest.

8 1984. The banking sector was also liberalized, with notable reforms in 1981 and again in 1983. The share of government “policy loans” to industry shrank, and interest rates between strategic and non-strategic sectors converged (Cho and Cole 1986; Nam 1992). By 1982, the gap in effective corporate tax rates between strategic and non-strategic industries was also closed (Kwack and Lee 1992) (reported in A1).

3 Data Construction

I construct new data on industrial development over South Korea’s miracle period (1967-1986). Below I describe the construction and harmonization of this data. Since, however, harmonization required nearly a dozen crosswalk schemas, I provide additional technical details in the data section of the Online Appendix.

Table A1 shows pre-1973 statistics (mean and standard deviation) for core variables. For visibility, A1 mostly reports non-normalized values. Throughout this paper, however, I default to inverse hyperbolic sine (ihs throughout) normalization, which accommodates 0s and negative values. Variables, such as disaggregated investment data, contain zeros, and inventories contain both zeros and negative values. This is especially prescient in higher resolution industrial panels.

The Long and Short of Industrial Panels The empirical strategy of this paper requires following industries consistently through time. I construct industry-level panels using digitized data from the Economic Planning Board’s (EPB) Mining and Manufacturing Surveys and Census (MMS). True to its name, the HCI drive was a fundamentally industry-level intervention. To this end, MMS industry data is apt for studying sectoral policy. It is high quality; reports manufacturing outcomes across the study period; and importantly, it is available at a fine level of disaggregation.

The MMS published census data nearly every five years (1970, onward, with annual intercensal surveys) at the 5-digit industry level, and aggregated from establishment-level enumeration.21 I supplement digitized MMS statistics with vintage MMS tape data (1977–1986) sold by the EPB in the 1980s. Additional data on prices are digitized from historical and contemporary Bank of Korea producer price index publications.

Creating consistent industry panels is non-trivial. Specifically, following industries through the HCI period (and beyond) requires extensive concordance and harmonization. Between 1967-1986, the horizon of this study, the EPB updated Korea’s industrial codes (KSIC, based on the international ISIC standard) four times, with a major revision in 1970.

Thus, I use two harmonized panels throughout this study, which are shown in Table A1. Part A of Table A1 reports values from the shorter, granular 5-digit industry panel, which is harmonized from 1970 to 1986. Part B reports values from the longer, but much more aggregated, 4-digit panel. This data is harmonized from 1967 to 1986. I choose 1986 as the end date of the panel, as it is when my mainframe data series ends and it is the year before the disrupting transition to democracy in 1987.

The harmonization process accounts for industry code changes in official Korea manufacturing data and in- troduces a trade-off.22 On the one hand, shorter panel data (1970-1986) accommodates more industry observa- tions, but does so over a smaller period. Thus, 5-digit data requires less harmonization as it is closer to origi- nal MMS values. On the other hand, longer data (1967-1986) covers fewer industries, but does so over a longer period. Thus, 4-digit data requires more harmonization (thus aggregation), but encompasses critical pre-HCI periods.

21To illustrate this level of aggregation consider two sectors: 35291, Manufactures of adhesives and gelatin products, and 35292, Manufactures of explosives and pyrotechnic products. Note that because the census is enumerated at the establishment- level, as opposed to the firm, this precludes analysis of firm competition. Micro data is not readily available for this early period. 22Fundamentally, this harmonization process entailed digitizing and rebuilding official crosswalks. I provide details of the process in Data Appendix.

9 Linkage and Trade Data Data on sectoral linkages come from the Bank of Korea’s 1970 “basic” input-output tables. These are the most disaggregated available for the period, and cover around 320 sectors. Hard copies were translated to English and then digitized.23 I also construct Leontief input-output coefficients from 1970 tables, which I describe in section 5.1.

Bank of Korea data and MMS industrial surveys use different coding schemes. This means that combining input-output accounts with industry data requires further harmonization. The Online Data Appendix describes this process, along with other harmonization and cross-walk procedures required by my analysis.

I supplement the 1970 input-output tables with 1975 tables. Though produced during the HCI drive, the 1975 tables distinguish between domestic and imported intra-industry flows. I return to this distinction in the net- work analysis section 5.1. Throughout the study, I default to referring to the “general” 1970 linkages, unless otherwise specified.

I use international trade flow and trade policy data as a standalone panel. This trade panel is also mapped to the “long”, 4-digit industrial panels described above. Trade flows come principally from the UN-COMTRADE database and are originally reported at the 4-digit SITC (Rev.1) level. Thus, I also construct crosswalks to con- nect trade-level data to Korean industrial data.

Trade policy—product-level measures of quantitative restriction (QRs) coverage and tariffs—are digitized from Luedde-Neurath (1986) (at the Customs Commodity Code Number [CCCN] level). This data is available for 1968, 1974, 1976, 1978, 1980, and 1982. This is the most disaggregated, readily-available data for the period (Westphal 1990). Moreover, these statistics are notable in that they contain measures of core non-tariff barriers, notably quantitative restrictions (QRs) (Goldberg and Pavcnik 2016).24

I use trade policy data to calculate separate measures of output and input market protection.25 Output pro- tection for industry 8 is simply the average tariff or QR score for that sector: output-tariff8. HCI used exemp- tions from import barriers as a policy tool. Thus I calculate measures of input protection. Input tariffs faced by 8 (or QRs) are calculated as the weighted sum of tariff (QR) exposure, with weights taken from the 1970 I- O accounts (following Amiti and Konings 2007). As such, exposure is calculated as input-tariff = Í 8 9 98 × output-tariff9, where 98 are input cost-shares for industry 8.

I now consider how the HCI industrial policy bundle might propagate through the input-output network.

4 Direct Impacts of Industrial Policy

4.1 Empirical Framework

This section explores how HCI industrial policy impacted the evolution of targeted industry—during and after the policy period. I use this variation to estimate the impact of HCI industrial policy. This section describes how. First, I describe how the HCI context is useful in estimating the impact of industrial policy. Second, I show how this variation informs a differences-in-differences estimation strategy.

Empirical Import of HCI Variation The HCI episode sharply altered the sectoral bias of Korean industrial strategy, while its introduction and withdrawal were driven by external political forces. From an empirical point of view, the context of the HCI is a useful experiment for estimating the impact of industrial policy.

23At the time of this study, machine readable I-O tables for 1970, were not available from the Bank of Korea. Note that 1970 tables report total values of inter-industry flows and do not differentiate between domestic and imported activity. 24Archival administrative data has been collected as of this study. Most empirical studies of Korean trade policy use highly aggregated data. I describe Luedde-Neurath (1986)’s coding of QRs in the Data Appendix. 25For simplicity, this study follows the contemporary practice of using nominal, statutory measures, though I also calculate measures weighted by input share for the corresponding year.

10 First, in practice industrial policy is often negatively correlated with industry fundamentals. Clientelism and capture mean policies go to industries that contradict comparative advantage (Rodrik 2005; Lin 2012). Yet be- yond rent-seeking, it is common for IP to support stagnating industries (“sunset” IP as opposed to infant in- dustry IP).26. While sunset policies or industry support are often driven by political demand, they may also be socially optimal (Hillman 1982; Flam, Persson, and Svensson 1983). Given this policy orientation, empirical work often shows a negative relationship between IP and industrial development outcomes (Harrison 1994; Harrison and Rodriguez-Clare 2009; Rodriguez and Rodrik 2001).

HCI, however, is an infant industry policy aimed at sectors for which South Korea has unrealized—or latent— comparative advantage. Critically, the HCI episode distinguishes between sunrise and sunset policies.27 Sim- ilarly, HCI was a top-down shift in national industrial strategy, whose sectoral bias was not driven by politi- cal constituencies. President Park’s consolidation of power allowed the creation of a technocratic Heavy and Chemical Industry Planning Board that transcended competing state factions.

Second, the external politics of HCI meant that de jure policy was binding. In practice, industrial policy pro- nouncements often depart from actual implementation. Even where policy is coherent and deployed, polit- ical constraints can undermine the quality of administration. Subsidized credit may not be directed toward prioritized industry (Lazzarini et al. 2015; Musacchio, Lazzarini, and Aguilera 2015), and trade policies may be undermined by capacity constraints (Panchamukhi 1978). Thus, regressing outcomes of statutory IP mea- sures may not reveal the impact of policy, but the quality of implementation. The politics behind HCI, how- ever, meant policy was incentive compatible. Expedient political factors made HCI binding—both its imple- mentation and removal.

Third, the HCI drive (1973-1979) was temporary. The theoretical case for infant industry policy often involves temporary policy (Melitz 2005). Historically, however, temporary policies often become permanent (Juhasz 2018), complicating empirical tests. For HCI, the 1979 assassination of President Park effectively ended HCI. I use the post-1979 period to examine the long-run impacts of the policy.

Fourth, HCI was a purposeful shift in national industrial policy toward a discrete set of infant industries. Given the complications of estimating the impact of IP, researchers have used valuable natural experiments that mimic policy variation (e.g. Juhasz (2018) and Hanlon (2020)). Broadly, however, the case for IP hinges on policy being allocated intentionally—according to technocratic criteria. This rationale can make it difficult to glean insights from random variation that does not embody this criteria (Rodrik 2004).28 The HCI episode provides useful temporal and sectoral variation for studying industrial policy “in the wild.”

The HCI episode thus provides a useful setting to estimate the short and longer run impacts of industrial pol- icy. HCI industries selected were nascent industries, as opposed to sunset industries. The geopolitical crisis meant IP was purposeful; planned in secret; and implemented, top-down, by a government, limiting the scope of domestic lobbying. A planning apparatus reduced—intentionally so—the potential of choosing sectors that contradicted notions of comparative advantage.

Estimation The temporal and sectoral variation of HCI informs a natural differences-in-differences style strat- egy. I use the January 1973 announcement of HCI as the start date, and 1979 as the de facto end date of HCI. The end date corresponds to President Park’s assassination, which promulgated the repeal of IP incentives by the successor regime.

26Such policies may be permissible under multilateral agreements. 27For example, while Korea’s HCI supported a “sunrise” shipbuilding industry, their Swedish contemporaries supported a “sunset” shipbuilding industry. 28Criscuolo et al. (2019) and Giorcelli (2019) illustrate the possibilities of using random variation in ways that, neverthe- less, address these issues.

11 Using a dynamic differences-in-differences design, I estimate the differences between targeted HCI industries and non-targeted manufacturing industries, each year relative to 1972. I examine these differences, before, dur- ing, and after the policy. Formally, I estimate the following

Õ  9  Õ 9 . = C  Targeted Year -0 Year Ω & 8C 8 + + 9 · 8 × C + 8 × C 9 + 8C (1) 9≠1972 9≠1972

8 indexes each 5-digit or 4-digit manufacturing industry, and C denotes the year. For the long 4-digit panel, C takes the values 1967 1986, and 1970 1986 for the more granulate 5-digit panel. Outcome . is an industrial − − development outcome. For industrial data (see section 3) I will make ample use of the inverse hyperbolic sine transformation (ihs) for outcomes.

The main effects of the policy are estimated using the term, Targeted, a binary variable equal to if HCI targets an industry, and zero otherwise. This “sharp” treatment term has a number of benefits. First, this simple indi- cator allows me to visually assess counterfactual industry dynamics, by clearly plotting pre-trends and group averages (see results section Figure 2). Second, it allows clearer comparisons with the semi-parametric estima- tors described below, which require binary treatment. Third, binary treatment easily codifies HCI targeting for industries that fall under the drive’s list of key strategic industries.

The baseline equation (1) is a linear two-way fixed effects (TWFE) specification. Industry fixed effects,

8, mean that I use variation within each industry. Time effects, C, control for common temporal shocks. Standard errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and clustered at the industry-level, allowing for within-industry correlation.

I include a set of baseline pre-treatment controls which attempt to capture unobserved productivity correlated with the intervention. These include measures of total material costs, average wage bill, average plant size, and labor productivity. Since these averages do not change through time, I interact them with period effects, - Year. Thus, their effect is allowed to flexibly vary through time. 80 ×

The coefficients of interest, 9, describe the evolution of manufacturing industries through time. The set of these 9s are the differences between targeted and non-targeted industries for each year 9, relative to the pre-treatment year 1972, with the coefficient for 1972 normalized to 0.

The set of 9 convey three aspects of how HCI industries evolved between 1967 and 1986.

First, estimates after 1972 show the average impact of the policy package for each period after the start of HCI. If HCI is associated with short-run (that is, during the six year drive) industrial development, we should ob- serve increasing differences in . between 1973 and 1979: 9 1973,   ...  . ≥ ˆ1974 ≤ ˆ1975 ≤ ≤ ˆ1979 Second, estimates after 1979 describe the more durable, long-run impacts of the temporary infant industry policy. In the parlance of the IP literature, the longevity of these effects indicate the potential “dynamic effects” of IP. Be they through dynamic scales economies, forms of learning-by-doing, or other forces that transform temporary advantages into persistent effects. For 9 > 1979, estimates   ...  , would be ˆ1979 ≤ ˆ1980 ≤ ˆ1986 compatible with a more persistent, or dynamic impact of the policy.

Third, estimates before 1972 describe average differences between HCI and non-HCI industry before the policy. Thus, they convey information—with caveats—for the common trend assumption of the research design. Pre-1972, we should not observe systematic differences between treatment and control industries:

12    0. Thus, I provide joint tests for whether  are not equal to 0 over the pre-treatment ˆ1967 ≈ ˆ1968 ≈ ˆ1972 ≈ 9 period.29

Accordingly, the identifying assumption behind equation (1) is that differences in industrial development be- tween treated and non-treated industries would have evolved similarly in the absence of the policy. I assume the comparative advantage of HCI industries was latent, and thus had not materialized—and may not have, absent the HCI policy bundle.

Although pre-treatment movements in targeted sectors is helpful to this end, the analysis in the second part of this paper may also be useful (section 5.3.2). Movements—or lack thereof—in industries downstream or upstream from targeted sectors can potentially reveal aspects of the pre-1973 HCI environment that may not be directly observable in HCI sectors themselves. Movements in external sectors—upstream or downstream— may be informative as to supply-side or demand-side trends that may confound estimates of HCI’s impact over the period.

Thus far, I have focused on the impacts of HCI for each point in time. Yet, it is useful to consider the average impact of HCI an either side of the intervention—before and after 1973. Consider a simplified specification,

 Õ 9 . = C  Targeted PostC -0 Year Ω & . 8C 8 + + · 8 × + 8 × C 9 + 8C (2) 9≠1972

where the binary treatment variable Targeted8 is now interacted with a simple binary PostC indicator (zero before 1973, one after).30 This interaction is the core difference between (2) and the dynamic specification (1). Thus, (1) estimates one , the average impact of HCI before and after 1973.

Nevertheless, empirical issues can complicate interpreting  as the average total impact of the HCI bundle. An emerging literature has documented why such linear estimates may be sensitive to a number of assumptions, such as heterogeneity of treatment and dynamic impacts of policy (Sloczynski 2018). In my setting, the impact of IP may vary through time. Similarly, the common trend assumption may hold only after conditioning on co- variates (Callaway and Sant’Anna 2020). Both factors can complicate direct interpretations of the total average effect of policy.

The potential shortcomings of linear estimators motivate an alternative means of estimating the average im- pact of HCI, which I turn to now.

Semiparametric DID Estimation and Average Treatment Effects on the Treated I consider a semiparamet- ric version of the linear DID estimator above. Specifically, the doubly-robust DID estimator of Sant’Anna and Zhao (2020), adapted for a multiple-period setting by Callaway and Sant’Anna (2020). Among its advantages, this method relaxes constraints of linear TWFE estimators, and recovers an interpretable overall average treat- ment effect on treated units, or ATT.

Thus, in addition to the linear DID methods above (eq. (2) and (1)), I estimate the impact of HCI for each pe- riod using the following equation,

29Neither individual or joint significance tests are conclusive. Although null results provide information about DID pre- trends assumptions, they cannot, alone, verify the pre-trend assumption. This may be true, in particular, for the “detailed” 5-digit estimates for my study, which have limited pre-treatment periods. 30 Like Targeted, the separate Post is subsumed by the period effects C .

13  - 1 Targeted  ( )( − )   Targeted 1  -  ATTC = E  − ( )  .C . 5 - (3)    − h  - 1 Targeted i  − 1972 − 0,.C .1972  E Targeted E ( )( − )  ( ) − ( )  1  -   − ( )  where (3) is the weighted average differences in industry outcomes. More precisely, (3) is the difference in out- comes between targeted industries (Targeted and non-targeted industries (1 Targeted). ) − Weights in (3) are defined as follows (following Sant’Anna and Zhao (2020) and Callaway and Sant’Anna

(2020)). The term  - E Targeted|X is the propensity score for treated industries. The term 50,.C .1972 - ( ) ≡ [ ] − ( ) ≡ E .C . Targeted=0,X is a regression for the change in outcomes for non-treated industries, between post- [ − 1972| ] = period C and the baseline, pre-treatment period, C 1972. Propensity scores  - and regression 50,.C .1972 - ( ) − ( ) are estimated by logit and OLS, respectively.

The estimator is doubly-robust in the sense that if either component is correctly specified, then (3) is a consistent estimate of the average treatment effect on the treated, or ATT. Confidence intervals for (3) are calculated using a bootstrap procedure, and allow for autocorrelation and industry-level clustering (Callaway and Sant’Anna 2020).

Beyond recovering a coherent ATT, the semiparametric method is useful for the HCI context. The two-step procedure relaxes the functional-form assumptions for the evolution of potential outcomes. The doubly-robust re-weighting estimation procedure ensures balance between targeted and non-targeted industries. Last, the pre-trend assumptions are also less stringent than other estimators. Average effects in (3) do not rely on zero pre-trends over all pre-treatment periods, and instead use a long-difference (between post-period C and the latest pre-treatment period, 1972).

The results in section 4.2 show that patterns estimated by linear TWFE estimation are robust to the semi- parametric procedure. The following empirical analysis relies on a dynamic DID analysis. For familiarity, I default to presenting linear TWFE results (1) first, and then show the corresponding dynamic semiparametric estimates from (3) for core specifications. In addition, I report the average impact of policy pre-post DID estimates. I show OLS estimates alongside estimates of the aggregate semiparametric DID estimates, and the latter are preferred. Note (3) requires a binary treatment and is not used for cases of continuous treatment. This includes the later network analysis in section 5.

4.2 Direct Impacts - HCI Industrial Policy and Industrial Development

This section examines the evolution of treated (HCI) versus and non-treated (non-HCI) industries, before, during, and after the HCI drive. I do so in four steps. First, A) establishes the core impact of HCI on industrial growth and the expansion of real output. Next, part B) moves beyond growth and shows the relationship across a set of industrial outcomes. Importantly, C) focuses specifically on the relationship between HCI and longer-run trade performance, in particular, the dynamic comparative advantage of HCI exporters. Last, in part D) I use a doubly-robust semiparametric procedure to report the overall average impact of HCI policies (ATT), and show that linear estimates are robust to less parametric assumptions.

A) HCI and Output Expansion Figure 2 plots dynamic DID estimates for the impact of HCI on output, measured as real value shipped. Coefficient estimates from (1) are plotted in black, and 95 percent confidence bands are shown in gray. Panel A shows estimates for the detailed (“short”) 5-digit panel, which starts in 1970. Panel B shows estimates for the more aggregated (“long”) 4-digit panel, which start in 1967. Columns show specifications including baseline fixed effects (right) and those with additional controls (left).

14 Figure 2: Differences in Industrial Growth (Real Value Shipped), HCI vs. Non-HCI Industry

The top row of Figure 2 shows mean growth for HCI (red) and non-HCI (black) industries separately. These are simply the averages for treated and non-treated sectors fit from model (1). The bottom row of Figure 2 shows the estimated differences between the treated and non-treated, or traditional differences plots. Corresponding point estimates and standard errors are shown in Table B1, along with tests for joint significance for pre-trends.

Figure 2 presents three key patterns of industrial development associated with the HCI drive. I emphasize pat- terns. Although Figure 2 shows results for manufacturing output specifically, the patterns in 2 will re-appear across outcomes and data throughout this paper.

First, consider the pre-HCI period, 1967-1972. For output, Figure 2 shows that HCI and non-HCI industries evolved similarly. This is clearest in “long”, aggregate 4-digit data. Pre-1973 estimates are virtually zero. Pre- period coefficients are, individually, insignificant, and F-tests in Table B1 report that they are also jointly in- significant.

Second, after the 1973 intervention, Figure 2 shows that marked differences between treated and non-treated sectors emerged. During the HCI drive period, relative to 1972, these differences widen and become salient. This divergence is starkest in estimates for 5-digit data in panel A, and panel B reports similar divergence for aggregate data, mostly significant over the HCI drive period.

The top row of Figure 2 highlights the importance of the counterfactual manufacturing industries used in the DID strategy. The estimated differences shown at the bottom of 2 do not appear to be driven by the decline of

15 control industries. That is, differences may emerge if industrial policies harm control industry, even where they fail to expand HCI output.31

Third, after 1979, Figure 2 shows the effect of the HCI period were not transitory. For the liberalization period, post-1979, HCI and non-HCI industries are still significantly different in terms of the value of output produc- tion, relative to 1972 levels. Following the fall of HCI and the Park regime, estimated differences diminish and become noisier. Nevertheless, the two types of manufacturing industries remain distinct.

The three patterns shown in Figure 2 are similar across measures of output. The patterns above are the same if one measures output as gross output (Table B1 columns 4-6) or value added (Table B1 columns 7-9).

B) Industrial Development Beyond Output Growth HCI is associated with shifts across a wider set of industrial development outcomes. A core aim of HCI was to reallocate manufacturing activity from the light industry—the industry Korea had become associated with during their 1960s expansion—to HCI industry. Figure 3 shows estimates for industrial reallocation estimates (Table B2 column 1), with industrial reallocation measured as industry share of total manufacturing output.

Figure 3 shows that HCI policy coincided with a significant shift in the share of industrial activity to HCI industries. Table B2 reports these estimates, alongside employment share. Estimates in panel A, columns 1 and 8, are significant for both outcomes by 1976 and remain significant thereafter. In the HCI post-period, the share of economic activity in HCI is durable, though estimates are less precise for aggregated data (panel B, columns 1 and 8). Importantly, B2 shows no pre-trends in the reallocation of activity and joint tests reject differences different than zero before the intervention.

Figure 3 also plots the substantial rise in the number of plants operating in HCI markets. The number of HCI plants remains significantly higher, relative to baseline levels, through the liberalization of HCI. Column 4 of Table B2 shows that estimates for plant activity are highly significant, starting immediately after 1973. Although positive, estimates are less precise in 4-digit data. Estimates for plant size, on the other hand, are weak (Table B2 column 5) and imprecisely estimated. Note that size pertains to plant size, not firm size, as the HCI era associated with the expansion of South Korean firms. Firm-side measures, like those related to concentration, are thus not in this study.

Coarse measures and proxies for productivity changed differentially across HCI and non-HCI during the pol- icy period. Figure 3 (Table B2, column 2) shows a relative decline in output prices for HCI industry. These re- sults are most precisely estimated in the 5-digit data (Table B2 part A), with estimates significant through the duration of the program. Estimates are less precise for aggregate 4-digit data (part B). Due to the coarseness of the data, I appeal to proxies of productivity, as industry-level data does not allow me to convincingly esti- mate TFP.

Averages for labor productivity in HCI and non-HCI data are shown in the top row of Figure B1 panel A for the detailed panel, along with estimated differences (bottom row). Trends in the two industries are similar through the mid-1970s and diverge through the HCI period. Table B2 column 3 shows a positive increase in real value added per worker. Here, labor productivity rises through the period, and is significant for a number of post-1973 years in 5-digit data (part A), and less precise for 4-digit data (part B).

Prices, shown in the second row of Figure 3, merit discussion. A naive reading of DID estimates may conclude that prices declined for HCI versus non-HCI. Similarly, pre-1973 differences in Figure 3 may indicate downward pre-trend for output price. Figure 3 panel B, however, shows a more subtle story. Average prices between HCI and non-HCI sectors (top panel B, Fig. B1) show that output prices grew markedly through the

31For example, Cerqua and Pellegrini (2017) shows similar effects for targeted policy in Italian industry, which while beneficial for treated firms, was harmful for un-treated firms.

16 1970s across sectors, due to inflationary pressure in the period. However, during this period, HCI prices break with the control industry averages, and become significantly lower. It is not that prices declined, rather that they remained significantly lower during the period.

Notably, prices are relatively lower in HCI industry. The price effects shown above contrast with industrial policy experiences elsewhere, where inefficient IP and protection are often associated with relative increases in output prices. In Egypt, India, and Turkey, heavy industrial policies may have effectively increased the rel- ative price of capital and intermediate goods (Schmitz Jr 2001). The positive relationship between prices and interventions may be the norm rather than the exception; see Blonigen (2016) for the case of steel.

Table B2 reports that labor outcomes, such as total employment and average wages, responded positively to HCI during and after the period. For total employment, 5-digit estimates are strongest and precisely estimated—significant across most post-HCI periods (part A, col. 6). Estimates are positive, though noisier for aggregate 4-digit estimates (part B, col. 6). Likewise, wages responded positively for both series, though they are noisy. This is not surprising, as through HCI (and beyond) South Korea exercised various forms of wage repression.

Figure 3: Impact of HCI on Key Industrial Development Outcomes

C) HCI and Dynamic Comparative Advantage Export performance was central to the HCI’s quest for industrial transformation (Hong 1987). A key target of the drive was to attain 50 percent share of HCI exports by 1980 (World Bank 1987). This section considers the shifting structure of trade during and after the HCI era.

Since HCI sought to promote industries for which it had unrealized, latent comparative advantage, I consider measures of revealed comparative advantage. Figure 4 shows estimates for the relationship between HCI and revealed comparative advantage (RCA) across SITC (Rev.1, 4-digit) goods, which are more disaggregated than

17 Figure 4: Impact of HCI on the Evolution of Revealed Comparative Advantage, HCI vs. Non-HCI

both industry panels. RCA is measured as the traditional share of exports of a Korean product relative to the world share of exports for that good. Additionally, I create a dummy indicator that takes a value of one if a good’s RCA index is greater than one.32

Figure 4 reports a strong, positive relationship between IP and revealed comparative advantage in treated goods. Estimates across RCA measures show a consistent pattern: First, a jump in the RCA of targeted products following 1973. Second, an upward trend during the HCI period. Third, a sustained export advantage after liberalization.

RCA estimates show that comparative advantage was indeed dynamic—and thus HCI export promotion may have taken time to gestate. This is clearly seen in Table B3 which shows that estimates become highly signifi- cant, and larger, toward the mid-1980s (across specifications). Though Figure 4 shows that the upward trend in HCI comparative advantage emerged during the drive, full comparative advantage is realized only years after.

Thus far, I have considered export performance by considering variation from goods-level trade data, that is, variation across SITC-level goods. This goods-level data is distinct from (and more granular than) industry- based data. Table 4 turns to industry-level trade performance. Here, goods-level (SITC 4-digit) trade values have been aggregated to the 4-digit industry level.

Table 4 column 1 shows a strong increase in the total value of exports and the structure of exports, measured by an industry’s share of manufacturing exports (in the spirit of the export target of HCI). Column 2 shows the value of HCI exports relative to non-HCI exports, post-1973. The magnitude of estimates increase and be- come significant in the latter part of the 1970s, remaining significant through the post-1979 period.

Although HCI explicitly sought to expand HCI exports—and enabled HCI producers to import key intermediates—scholars have characterized HCI as a policy of import substitution industrialization (ISI) (See Dollar and Sokoloff 1990).

In Table 4, estimates for imports seem incompatible with a traditional ISI narrative. Column 4 in Table 4 re- ports that the value of imports for HCI and non-HCI industry is unchanged–and uniformly insignificant–over

- >A40 - >A40 32 8 )>C0; The Balassa measure for industry 8 defined as the ratio of exports (-), RCA8 = / . -,>A;3 -,>A;3 8 / )>C0;

18 the HCI period. The manufacturing share of HCI imports, on the other hand is negative, yet the standard er- rors are large.

The following section puts the export estimates above in context, and shows they are robust to the type of esti- mator.

D) Semiparametric Results and the Average Impact of HCI I now describe the average overall impact of the HCI, and confirm the impact of industrial policy through an alternative means of estimating the DID effects of the policy. I do so by implementing the doubly-robust differences-in-differences estimator proposed by Sant’Anna and Zhao (2020) and Callaway and Sant’Anna (2020).

Figures B2-B4 show that dynamic semiparametric DID estimates of the impact of HCI are similar to TWFE estimates. These plots show estimates of specification (3) across key industrial development outcomes. These semiparametric estimates are comparable to the linear TWFE estimates in the preceding section. These speci- fications include the same set of pre-treatment controls and cluster on the same dimension of the data. Boot- strap confidence intervals are given at the 10 percent and 5 percent levels—light and dark gray, respectively.

Figures B2 and B3 show the relationship between HCI and industrial development using the semiparametric parametric method. Figure B2 reports 4-digit estimates, and Figure B3 reports 5-digit estimates across a selec- tion of code output and industrial development outcomes seen in the previous sections. Similarly, B4 shows semiparametric estimates for export development outcomes, such as revealed comparative advantage.

Qualitatively, the patterns plotted in Figures B2-B4 are similar to linear TWFE estimates. Though the doubly- robust DID relaxes some assumptions of the traditional estimators, the general dynamic pattern associated with HCI is robust. This is important, as this estimator re-weights treatment and control groups for balance.

Consider the overall average impact (specifically, the ATT) of the policy before and after 1972, which is also shown in Figure B2. Red dots demarcate the estimated ATT and the corresponding 95 percent confidence bounds are in pink.

Table 1 reports the average treatment effects, and compares semiparametric and OLS estimates side-by- side. Columns 1-2 list semiparametric results and columns 3-4 list linear TWFE results. Panels A and B, respectively, show estimates for 5-digit and 4-digit datasets. Estimates without controls are shown in columns 1 and 3, and those with controls are shown in columns 2 and 4. Preferred specifications are semiparametric estimates with controls.

ATT results in Table 1 show that the overall average impact of HCI targeting was meaningful and large.33. The preferred estimates in panel B, column 2 imply 130.53 percent growth in output for HCI industry relative to non-HCI manufacturers. Estimates for 5-digit data (panel A col. 2) imply 151.68 percent output growth (all significant at the 1 percent level). The semiparametric estimates for output tend to be larger than OLS estimates.

The average effect on labor productivity (panel A column 2) translates to a 63.88 percent increase in value added per worker for HCI industries after 1973. Labor productivity growth ranges between 38.68% to 63.88% across the estimates in 5-digit data. Productivity estimates are precisely estimated across semiparametric specifications, and across 4- and 5-digit data.

Table 1 also reports striking export development. On average, HCI’s share of manufacturing exports increased 38.31 percent more than other industry. For the value of exports, estimates imply exports were over 200 per-   33The ihs-linear elasticities are calculated using 100 exp  .5 +0Ad  1. At sufficiently high values, ihs approxi- × ˆ − × ( ) − mates log-linear elasticities (Bellemare and Wichman 2020; Aihounton and Henningsen 2020).

19 cent higher for HCI manufacturers compared to non-HCI manufacturers. While dramatic, this is not out of bounds for the period. World Bank reports for the era (Cho and Kim 1995; Kim and Leipziger 1993) show that for HCI industries, the export share of output tripled through the HCI period (Kim and Leipziger 1993), as did the share of total manufacturing exports (Cho and Kim 1995). The grand export target of HCI (of 50 per- cent of manufacturing exports) was, in fact, surpassed by 1983 (ibid).

Table 2 shows the average effect of HCI on comparative advantage. In 1970, the mean RCA index for targeted sectors was .15, while the average RCA for Korea was 1.5. Linear probability estimates in Table 2 show targeted products were 0.13 percent more likely to realize comparative advantage on the world market (significant at 5 percent level). Indeed, estimates for each RCA measure are significant. Preferred RCA scores in column 2 show the revealed comparative advantage in HCI industry increased 29 percent over other manufactured exports (and significant at the 1 percent level).34

For output prices, Table 1 shows that semiparametric estimates are systematically smaller (in absolute terms) than OLS. Nevertheless they are strong (and significant at 1 percent), (col. 2) implying 13 percent lower output prices following HCI (4-digit data). Five-digit estimates imply 12 percent lower output prices.

Average employment effects of HCI in Table 1, too, are substantial. Here, semiparametric DID estimates tend to be larger than OLS DID estimates. Panel A column 2 implies employment grew 68 percent more for HCI manufacturers after 1973 (significant at 1 percent). Four-digit data implies that a 58 effect, though estimates are insignificant (0.508 point estimates with 0.322 standard error).

Discussion Thus, the results in this section show that the HCI policy bundle contributed to the development of targeted industry. The impact of HCI not only seems to have promoted industrial development over the planning period, but these effects have been durable, lasting after the end of the policy and through the period of economic liberalization in the 1980s.

The sections above showed a consistent pattern of industrial development across three sets of outcomes. First, the expansion of industrial output. Second, the development of broader industrial outcomes, such as output prices, value added per worker, and industry employment. Third, and importantly, the evolution of compara- tive advantage among exporters. These patterns are robust across data sets and the type of estimator. Last, the average effects implied by these estimates are economically meaningful.

The empirical relationship between industrial policies and industrial development is not a foregone conclu- sion (Lane 2020). Studying Japan’s postwar industrial strategy, Beason and Weinstein (1996) show a negative relationship between development and targeting policies. Lee (1996) shows a similar negative relationship for South Korea in the 1970s. Researchers find these negative relationships, more broadly, in correlation studies of IP [Rodriguez and Rodrik (2001); Harrison and Rodriguez-Clare (2009); p.4092].35 How may have policy in historical South Korea have been different?

4.3 Direct Results - The Role of Policy

I now consider the policies underlying industrial development. This section does so in two steps. First, by showing how outcomes related to investment and production subsidies changed over the HCI period. Second, I show that the role of trade policy—namely, nominal output market protection—is more ambiguous.

34This refers to ihs-transformed outcome, which allow zero trade values and whose estimates are the most stable. 35A thoughtful study by Pons-Benaiges (2017) has since considered the impacts of Japanese sectoral targeting. Focusing on dynamic and static scale economies.

20 Figure 5: Average Investment Incentive and Trade Policy Outcomes 1967-1986

A) Capital Investment B) Material Costs C) Inventory Investment 1000 30000 1500 750

1000 20000 500

10000 500 250 Value (100 ml. won) Value (100 ml. won) Value (100 ml. won) Value 0 0 0 1967 1972 1979 1986 1967 1972 1979 1986 1967 1972 1979 1982 D) Quant. Restrictions E) Avg. Tariff

1.00 60

0.75 40

0.50 Non−HCI 20 HCI 0.25 Value tariff rate Value

0.00 0 QR coverage (low to high) 1968 1972 1979 1982 1968 1972 1979 1982 Notes: Each panel plots outcomes related to investment and protection. Points are averages across HCI and non−HCI industries. The top row, panels A−C, are outcomes related to investment incentives. Panel A reports mean, real total capital formation across HCI and non− HCI industries. Panel B reports real total inventory investments, a proxy for relaxation of capital constraints. Panel C shows real total material costs. Panels D and E show outcomes for trade policy. Panel D reports average ad valorem tariff rates (percent), and panel E shows quantitative restriction measures (QR). QR is qualitative ranking of coverage on products within an industry, 0 being minimal coverage and 3 being high coverage. See discussion in text.

A) Differential Responses to Investment and Production Incentives Is there evidence that investment incentives changed? In many settings, we do not directly observe investment or production incentives (see Kalouptsidi (2018) for excellent discussion). For HCI in particular, this is complicated by the fact that policy loans were disseminated by both the commercial banking sector and specialized banks (see section 2.C. With this in mind, I study how proximate—or, causally, “downstream”—outcomes changed over the HCI period in response to policy. These outcomes include those related to variable costs (materials expenditure) and fixed costs (total gross fixed capital formation), following the literature on credit policy in developing countries (Banerjee and Duflo (2014); Manova, Wei, and Zhang (2015)). Importantly, I also examine inventory investments. I do so because inventories are sensitive to firm financing (Carpenter et al. 1994), and firms ought to respond differentially to favorable credit conditions and cost of capital (Jones and Tuzel 2013; Dasgupta, Li, and Yan 2019).

I first consider changes in aggregate outcomes between HCI and non-HCI manufacturing industries over the HCI period. The top row of Figure 5 shows changes in average outcomes for treated (red) and control (black) industries from 1967 through 1986. Figure 5 shows a widening gap for fixed (panel A) and variable (panel B) costs across the two types of manufacturing industries. For gross capital formation, panel A shows this wedge begins around the start of the drive and widens through the HCI period. Panel B shows a similar, if not more acute, divergence in total material outlays. Both widen significantly at the onset of the policy. Like the pattern of output, fixed and variable cost measures stay relatively high, despite the decline of HCI policy.

Aggregate inventory changes, panel C of Figure 5, track the rise and fall of HCI policies. Following the 1973 HCI announcement, total inventory investments spike for HCI manufacturers, rising sharply following the

21 HCI announcement in 1974. Inventories spike again in the later 1970s, falling precipitously during the period of HCI’s dismantling. Note the data goes until 1982.

Turning to industry data, Figure 6 shows DID estimates for incentive-related outcomes, from specification (1) from the detailed industry panel. Table C1 shows the full regression estimates and results at the 4-digit level. Like aggregate costs above (Fig. 5), Figure 6 shows this divergence starkest for materials. This divergence in material costs begins in 1973, and widens through the push. Table C1 shows these effects are significant for 5-digit data, starting in 1973, and grow in strength through the HCI period. The relative growth in material costs are also seen across data, yet estimates are noisier in aggregate 4-digit data.

Figure 6 panel C shows divergence in gross capital formation at the 5-digit level. Like material inputs, capital investment diverges between HCI and non-HCI through the HCI period, briefly declining (in HCI alone) post- 1979, and recovering through the 1980s. Four digit estimates shown in panel B of Table C1 reject pre-trends, however, aggregate estimates here tend to be imprecise.36

The overall average (ATT) increase in material and investment after 1973 was substantial. Table 3 shows both doubly-robust semiparametric and linear DID estimates of the average effect. Preferred estimates (col 2, 5-digit panel) translate into a 118.83 percent relative increase in variable costs for HCI over non-HCI manufacturers. DID estimates for materials are highly significant for 5-digit data. Preferred estimates (col. 2) show a total 90.11 percent increase in investment for HCI over non-HCI manufacturers over the study period. All 5-digit DID estimates in panel A are significant, while 4-digit estimates are positive, yet imprecise.

Inventories ought to positively respond to favorable financial conditions in HCI industry. Table C1 column 3 shows that inventory investments track their aggregate counterparts in 5. Inventory estimates show sharp divergence, starting in 1973 (significant at a 1 percent level) and reaching another peak in 1977. Notably, (3) shows these estimates die down in the periods after HCI. Thus, the differential movements in inventories also indicate the favorable investment conditions in HCI industry—but only over the HCI windfall period.

Note that Table 6 shows disaggregated capital investment and further inventory measures. Importantly, Table 6 shows that inventory investment over sales was not changing, but rather levels of inventories (total invest- ment, as well as products). This is important, as the rise in inventories over oil shocks typically refer to the in- ventory to sales ratio, not levels. As well, the increase in this ratio is in large part due to sales responding neg- atively to oil shocks (Herrera 2018). This was not the case during HCI, as sales increased for these sectors, in particular in the early years of the drive.

Korea’s National Investment Fund, a state-administered source of credit for HCI (Section 2), emphasized the financing of machinery for HCI firms. Table 6 shows investment changed significantly across three main asset classes, specifically those related to equipment. Point estimates in Table 6, column 1 shows the results for in- vestment are strongest for machinery and equipment, followed by building and factory-related fixed capital investment (col. 3). Transport equipment also increased during the HCI drive. These are consistent with the investment patterns incentivized by state-lending policy, which emphasized equipment and factory expansion (Yoo 1990; p.39-41; World Bank 1987).

Is it obvious that we would observe responses to investment or production incentives from IP? Based on the history of industrial policy, no. Importantly, if financial policies are redundant, they may not create new investment (outlays)—investment (outlays) that would have still occurred in the absence of policy. Still, in many contexts, de jure investment policy may not bind. Lazzarini et al. (2015) shows that for Brazil, capital from the BNDES development bank did not increase investment, and instead was allocated to politically connected firms where investments would otherwise have taken place. For East Asia, Yang (1993) argues

36In general, the 4-digit capital estimates are noisy, likely due to aggregation across asset class (to construct total investment estimates) and through time (across code changes).

22 investment subsidies in Taiwan (late-1980s) did not contribute to capital formation, echoing a common criticism of industrial investment schemes: that investment would have occurred anyways. DID results above show otherwise, in the case of HCI.

Figure 6: Input Use and Investment During HCI Drive, HCI vs. Non-HCI Industries

Material Costs Material Costs Tot. Investment Tot. Investment (ihs) (ihs) 1000000 13 100000 10 750000 75000 12 9

500000 8 50000 11

Fit Model 7 250000 25000

10 6

(Average Outcomes) (Average 0 0

80000 1.5 600000 1 60000 1.0 400000 40000 0.5 0 200000 20000 (Coefficient) 0.0

0 0 Estimated Differences −1 19701972 1979 1986 19701972 1979 1986 19701972 1979 1986 19701972 1979 1986

Non−HCI HCI Figure shows dynamic differences−in−differences estimates for the relationship between HCI and responses to investment incentives. Panels report estimates for real total input material costs total investment, or total gross capital formation. For comparison with aggeragate plots, both ihs and non−normalized estimates are given. All panels report estimates from 5−digit industry panel (1970−1986). Specifications include controls for (pre−treatment) costs, avg. wages, avg. plant size, and labor productivity, interacted with time effects. Regression tables in Appendix. Figure plots coefficients of interest (black) from intereaction of interest: HCI x Year. Estimates are relative to 1972, the year before the HCI policy intervention. The line at 1973 is the start of the policy. The line at 1979 demarcate the fall of the Park regime. Standard errors are clustered at the industry−level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. Confidence bands are in light grey and correspond to 95 percent confidence interveals. Corresponding regression tables are in Appendix.

B) Trade Policy - Protectionism with an "intensity unmatched" in the postwar period? Narratives of HCI have focused on the central role of trade policy. Many have emphasized output protection and HCI has been popularly characterized as overtly protectionist. Lall described the drive as the “most intensive form of trade intervention in East Asia,” which protected HCI sectors “behind high and variable import protection at a speed and with an intensity unmatched in recent economic history” (Lall 1997).

Figure 5 panels D and E show two simple measures of market protection for HCI and non-HCI industry, for five periods between 1968-1982.37 Panel D reports the average tariff rates (percent), and panel E shows mea- sures of quantitative restriction coverage (QRs) (discrete 0, 1, 2, 3 , low to high).38 { } Panels D and E, Figure 5, show output protection—measured in terms of ad. val. tariffs and QR coverage— was lower in HCI manufacturing industry than in others. Figure 5 reports average measures of nominal protection fell, with a slight rise in the 1970s before ebbing by 1982s. Liberalization of trade policy would occur in full after 1982 (Yoo 1993).

37Undoubtedly, the subsidies and incentives used over the period constitute a form of protection. I focus here on the in- stitutional use of different policy levels, which will have different welfare implications and may have different consequences on the evolution of industry. 38By nature their nature quantitative restrictions can be heterogeneous and aggregating them into single tariff equiva- lents can data intensive. Following one common approach of the non-tariff barrier literature, Luedde-Neurath (1986), coded the severity of quantitative restriction—mainly quotas—for products within 4-digit industries using a 0-3 scale. Zero being no restrictions to three, being most severe.

23 Drilling down, Figure C1 shows convergence in the distribution of output trade policy between HCI and non-HCI manufacturing industry, for five years between 1968-1982. The right column of C1 plots the kernel density estimates for tariff through time. The left column plots the kernel density estimates of QR coverage through time. The distributions start 1968 quite dispersed, but eventually overlap by 1982. Importantly, the distribution of HCI-sector trade policies does not shift toward protectionism during the HCI drive period.

Nevertheless, I evaluate the case for overt protection more formally. I do so by regressing industry-level trade policy outcomes, and measures of input protection, on a binary indicator for HCI industry. I consider the fol- lowing equation,

 . =  Targeted C -0Ω & (4) 8C + · 8 + + 8 + 8C where 8 are industries and C are the five periods covered in by trade policy: 1968, 1974, 1978, 1980, and 1982.

Specification (4) controls for time effects C and includes baseline controls for wage bill, material costs, plant size, labor productivity.

I estimate equation (4) in levels and differences, . and Δ.. The coefficient of interest is , conveys differences in the average level—or change—in policy between HCI and non-HCI industries over the five periods of trade data.

First, consider differences in the level of output protection between treated and non-treated sectors. Table 5 panel A reports that output market protection was, on average lower, for HCI industry. Columns 1-2 shows this for average output tariffs, while columns 5-6 shows this for QR coverage (significant at the 1 percent level). For completeness, column 2 reports estimates weighted by the pre-1973 value of imports. Column 4 restricts the sample to post-1973 observations, and these estimates imply the level of tariffs for HCI industry was 23 percent lower through the HCI period.

Perhaps trade policy changed differentially for HCI? Panel A, columns 9-12 of Table 5 report estimated changes in output protection between 1968 and 1982. All estimates are positive, yet all insignificant. The most liberal estimates suggest that, at best, tariffs increased 4 percent over the period. However, it is likely this is because they fell less for HCI than non-HCI industry, on average.

On the other hand, HCI industries were assisted by trade policy vis-a-vis exemptions on duties and tariffs for imported intermediates (section2) (Mason 1980; Nam 1995). I thus consider the differential exposure to input protection using industry-level measures of input protection built from input-output tables (described in sec- tion 3). These measures of input tariff exposure account for the potential exemptions afforded to HCI industry during the period.

Table 5 panel B reports estimates for input exposure outcomes. Columns 9-12 report estimates for changes in exposure to input protection. Column 10 suggest that HCI manufacturers enjoyed a 6 percent reduction in im- port tariffs due to HCI drive import exemptions. Estimates for reductions in quantitative restrictions, while negative, are insignificant.

Discussion This section explored the potential policies underlying HCI, examining responses to investment incentives and outcomes related to trade policy. This section saw more compelling cases for the former than the latter. In particular, I showed variables (causally) downstream from industrial incentives, such as material costs and capital formation, changed significantly for HCI industries. If control industries serve as appropriate counterfactuals, then incentives likely translated into input use and investment that would not have occurred in the absence of policy.

24 On the other hand, it is unclear whether nominal output market protection was the tip of the HCI spear, at least at the aggregate level. On average, nominal output protection was lower for HCI industry, while changes in output market protection are not easily detectable—at least at the granularity of this paper. Moreover, South Korea trended toward trade policy liberalization, more broadly. This is not to say protection did not exist. After all, subsidies and incentives are seen as non-tariff barriers tantamount to de facto protection. Yet, narratives of overt ISI-style policy seem unlikely.

5 Network Impacts of Industrial Policy

The case for industrial policy has long been motivated by the existence of positive spillovers beyond treated sectors (Krueger and Tuncer 1982; Grossman 1990; Krugman 1993). Classic developmental theorists (Scitovsky 1954; Rasmussen 1956; Hirschman 1958) considered how the effects of industrial interventions might produce spillovers, beyond the recipients of policies, through input-output linkages. This section examines how the de- velopment of HCI sectors impacted non-HCI sectors through the input-output network. Above I showed (sec- tion 4.2) that industrial development outcomes and (section 4.3) policy-related outcomes changed differently for targeted sectors during and after the HCI period. I now consider how this may have impacted external in- dustry.

I use the language of traditional (linkages) to explore network spillovers from HCI. I consider two directions of this propagation. First, through backward linkages. That is, to upstream industries selling inputs to targeted sectors. Second, through forward linkages. That is, to downstream industries purchas- ing inputs from targeted sectors. Throughout, I use the terms “backward” and “forward” from the vantage point of a targeted industry. Both refer to the propagation from the perspective HCI industry. HCI industry affects upstream suppliers through backward linkages. Conversely, HCI industry affects downstream buyers through forward linkages.

The network in Figure D2 visualizes linkages for the pre-HCI Korean economy, using the 1970 South Korea input-output accounts. Red nodes are targeted industries, and gray nodes are non-targeted industries. The size of nodes reflects the total number of connections (or “degrees”).39 The connections shown in D2 indicate a link between two industries. Specifically, nodes are connected if an industry sells its output to another downstream industry. These outward links are thus forward linkages. The Kamada-Kawai (1989) algorithm (1989) determines the proximity of nodes to one another in the figure, where industries with more links appear closer to one another.

5.1 Measuring Linkages

To estimate the impact of industrial policy through linkages, I construct measures of network exposure to HCI targeting using digitized 1970 (“basic”) input-output accounts for South Korea. I use 1970 table, as they pre- date the HCI drive and limit the extent to which links are endogenously formed with respect to the interven- tion.

Formally, consider two industries, where 8 is a non-targeted industry and 9 is a treated industry. The non- targeted industry is backward linked if it supplies output to a treated industry. This direct relationship is thus denoted 89. Firms have many such links. For example, the sum of backward linkages is equal to the weighted sum of links between a producer and those using their output. I measure this as

39For clarity Figure D2 plots “medium” 153 153 input-output accounts. “Treated” HCI nodes in Figures D2 dif- fer slightly from those used in the industrial census× data set as input-output data is presented at a different level of aggregation and using a different coding nomenclature.

25 Õ Sales89 Backward Linkages = with = . (5) 8 89 89 Í Sales 9 90 890

40 where weight 89 is the value of 8’s sales to 9, divided by the total sales from 8 to all industries 90. The denominator of 5 is the sum of industry 8’s sales to all sectors. These include sales to tradable and service buyers, as well 8 sold as final products.

I measure policy exposure by summing the share of sales ( 89 in 5) to targeted industries only, calculated by

Õ Backward HCI Linkages = . 8 89 (6) 9 HCI ∈

In other words, (6) measures only linkages between 8 and targeted buyers 9 HCI, where HCI is the set of tar- ∈ geted industries. The forward linkage analog of 6 are calculated in much the same way, but flipped. For the for- Í Í ward linkage case, Forward Linkages8 is equal to 9 98, and Forward HCI Linkages8 is equal to 9 HCI 98. ∈ Equation 6, however, captures only direct (one degree) connections—or spillovers—that propagate between HCI industries and others. Nevertheless, total (n-degree) backward linkage measures are calculated using a method similar to the direct effects above, except using coefficients from Leontief matrix (see Technical Ap- pendix) instead of the technical input-output matrix. Total linkages are calculated by

Õ Total Backward HCI Linkage8 = ℓ89. (7) 9 HCI ∈ where equation 7 adds industry 8’s Leontief coefficients for purchasing sectors, 9, but only for those targeted by the HCI drive.41 In other words, for an industry row 8, I add column-wise entries 9 for 9’s in the set of tar- geted industries. Thus, Total Backward HCI Linkage8 in equation 6 captures the total exposure of industry 8 through all direct and indirect linkages. The Total Forward HCI Linkage8 measure is calculated in a similar way, though the indices are reversed. Instead of summing across columns for each row, I sum across rows 9, for each column 8.

Figure D1 lists non-targeted sectors with the highest direct connections to targeted sectors—measured by 42 Backward HCI Linkages8 and Forward HCI Linkages8, equation (6). The left of figure D1, shows the top twenty (5-digit) manufacturing industries with the highest share of inputs sourced from targeted sectors. These sectors include Jewelry & related articles and Plastic products. Many sectors of these sectors tend to be more downstream industries. The right of Figure D1 lists the top 20 industries with the highest (direct) backward links to targeted sectors. In other words, the list of non-treated industries supplying a large share of output to HCI industry. Unsurprisingly, many of sectors supplying a large share of output to HCI industries are fairly upstream sectors, closer to the raw materials end of the supply chain.

40 For simplicity, I do not count 8’s sales to itself. Substantively, this means excluding diagonals 88 in the input-output matrix. 41See Technical Appendix for derivation of the Leontief inverse table used in the calculation. As with the direct linkage calculations, I do not count on-diagonal coefficients. 42Names of the sectors reflect both the harmonization of industry names through time, as well as the matching of I-O tables to 5-digit industry codes. Industry are meant to convey a general, qualitative pattern to the reader.

26 5.2 Network Spillovers: Empirical Strategy

I use linkage measures above (section. 5.1) to estimate the impact of the HCI industrial policy on industries downstream and upstream from treated industries. I do so by using a dynamic DID analysis in the spirit of equation (1). Intuitively, I estimate the spillovers of HCI by comparing outcomes across sectors with strong versus weak linkages, on either side of 1973. I consider the following specification,

Õ  9  . = C  Backward Linkage Year 8C 8 + + 9 · 8 × C + 9≠1972 (8) Õ  9  Õ 9  Forward Linkage Year -0 Year Ω & 9 · 8 × C + 8 × C 9 + 8C 9≠1972 9≠1972 where . is an outcome, 8 indexes each 5-digit (or 4-digit) industry. Subscript C denotes the years, which are 1967 1986 for the 4-digit panel and 1970 1986 for the 5-digit panel. The baseline equation (8) is a linear TWFE − − specification. Fixed effects and controls are the same as (1). Since these measures do not change through time, they are interacted with time effects, - Year, allowing their impact to vary through time. 80 × The coefficients of interest in (8) convey the dynamic impact of linkage exposure on upstream and down- stream industry. Importantly, (8) includes two types of linkage effects. The first set of coefficients, 9, conveys the impact of HCI policy through backward links. The second set, 9, convey the impact of HCI policy through forward links. Thus, the set of estimates, 9s (9s) conveys the differential development of sectors with high backward (forward) linkages with HCI industry, relative to those with fewer linkages.

Before 1972, the vector of coefficients ought to be 0, and should show no prior differences between linked in- dustries. Estimates after 1972 should increase until at least 1979, the start of HCI’s liberalization. Estimates for the post-liberalization period may indicate long-run effects of policy (if coefficients continue to be greater than or equal to earlier estimates) or temporary policy effects if coefficients decline significantly.

For this empirical exercise, I take the 1970 input-output network as fixed, determined by forces prior to the shock. The identifying assumption is that differences in industrial development between more-less backward (forward) linked industries would have evolved similarly in the absence of the HCI policy.

It is worth noting that the dynamic DID specification (8) uses a continuous treatment variable, whereas DID estimates in the first part of this paper, section 4, used a binary treatment variable. The continuous treatment precludes the use of the semiparametric DID methods used earlier. The following results section, thus, presents two-way fixed effects estimates and avoids binarization of linkage variables.

5.3 Network Results

I break my analysis into forward and backward linkage results. I start with, and focus on, forward linkages. Part 1 shows that sectors with a relatively strong forward link to HCI industry—downstream users dependent on HCI inputs—developed more over the HCI period. Similarly, I show evidence of dynamic comparative ad- vantage for downstream exports, for the periods after HCI. Part 2 turns to backward linkages, where I show the relatively limited, or even weakly negative, impacts of HCI policy on sectors upstream from HCI industry.

5.3.1 Forward Linkages and Downstream Development

I present three results for the impact of HCI on downstream industry. First A), I report downstream sectors industry with stronger forward linkages have higher relative output growth and industrial development over HCI. I then B) show longer-run effects of forward linkages on revealed comparative advantage for down-

27 stream exporters using trade data. Last C), I highlight the potential role of intermediate use in promoting these effects.

A) Downsteam Industial Expansion and Development Theoretically, expansion of supply from targeted sectors is beneficial to forward-linked sectors.43 Figure 7 shows the relationship between forward linkage strength and downstream output, plotting the dynamic DID estimates from equation (8).

Rows in Figure 7 show estimates for real value added (top) and output prices (bottom). This section focuses on value added measures of output, given the emphasis on the stages of production. Estimates with gross out- put tend to be larger, but the patterns are the same. Columns show estimates by industry panel (4 digit vs. 5 digit data), and by sample (full sample vs. non-HCI sample).

We are interested in how HCI impacts external sectors through forward linkages. Estimates in panels B and D of Figure 7 use only variation from the “Non-HCI sample,” excluding all HCI observations. This restriction, however, significantly reduces the size and power of the data. especially in more aggregate 4-digit data. Pan- els A and C, alternatively, show estimates using the full sample of industries, but controlling flexibly for HCI industry through time. These “Full-Sample” estimates include an additional control interaction, Targeted Year. × Estimates in Figure 7 show that industries with stronger forward linkages expanded output more over the HCI drive period. Before 1973, differences between HCI-reliant industries were negligible. Table E1 presents the full regressions from these plots, and provides joint tests for pre-trends. All tests reject pretends, except columns 3-4 panel B. Columns 3-4 show forward-linked sectors had relatively higher output in the 1960s, a lead which trended downwards and became insignificant before 1973.

Table 7 reports average estimates, or the pre-post version of equation (8). For simplicity, Table 7 shows DID estimates for both forward linkages and backward linkages; in dynamic differences-in-differences tables, they are shown separately due to size. This section discusses the analysis of forward linkages; I discuss backward effects in the following section.

For value added, average forward linkages effects in Table 7 (panel A col. 2) imply a 1 unit rise in the share of links to HCI translates into 2.18 percent more output (1.35 percent in 4-digit data), with estimates significant at the 5 percent level. Five-digit estimates in panel A are all positive and significant.

Similarly, Table E3 reports the average effects for total forward linkages, or the linkages accounting for n-degree (Leontief) linkages between downstream industry and HCI suppliers. Like direct links, Table E3 reports a robust relationship between total forward linkage exposure and downstream growth in relative value added. Notably, total forward linkages effects are strongest in the Non-HCI sample. Point estimates (panel A col. 4) imply a one unit rise in total forward linkage strength is associated with 3.48 percent higher value added after 1973 (significant at 10 percent level).44

Beyond output, positive supply shocks in targeted industries can decrease output prices in downstream industry. The bottom row of Figure 7 shows the impact of forward linkages on downstream prices. Down- stream industry with more connections to HCI have relatively lower output prices during and after the drive. Pre-1973, prices were higher in forward-linked sectors. After 1973, they decline markedly. This steep relative drop is shown across data sets and samples across panels in Fig. 7. After 1979, these differences between prices stop widening, though prices remain relatively lower in forward linked sectors through the 1980s.

43This result can be derived from many theoretical frameworks, though would result from one with. Refer to previous version of the paper for a basic theoretical model. 44Note that Leontief coefficients are different units than direct input-output measures, which are interpretable as the percent share of inputs between 0-100.

28 Figure 7: Impact of Direct Forward Linkages on Downstream Value Added and Output Prices

A) Entire Sample B) Non−HCI Only C) Entire Sample D) Non−HCI Only 4−Digit Panel 4−Digit Panel 5−Digit Panel 5−Digit Panel

0.050 0.04 0.050 0.04

0.025 0.02 0.025 0.02

0.000 Value Add. Value 0.00 0.00 0.000 −0.025 −0.025 −0.02

0.005 0.000 0.0000 0.000 −0.002 0.000 −0.0025 Prices −0.005 −0.004 −0.005 −0.006 −0.0050

−0.010 1967 1972 1979 1986 1967 1972 1979 1986 1967 1972 1979 1986 1967 1972 1979 1986 Notes: Figure plots dynamic differences−in−differences estimates for the relationship between direct forward linkage exposure to HCI and outcomes: real output (value shipped) (top) and value added per worker (bottom). Forward linkage measures corresponds to 1970 share of inputs sourced directly from HCI industry. See text for details. Estimates are relative to, 1972, the year before HCI. The year 1979 corresponds to collapse of Park regime. Years are on the x−axis. Estimates for the effect of direct forward (Linkage X Year) linkages are on y−axis. Panels (A) and (C) show estimates for the entire sample of industries, controlling the effect of direct targeting, HCI x Year. Panels (B) and (D) shows estimates for only non−targeted industry. Regressions include controls for direct backward linkage connections, interacted with time. Regression tables in Appendix. 95 percent confidence interveals are shown in gray.

Figure 8: Mechanisms: Direct Forward Linkages on Downstream Input Use and Investment

A) Entire Sample B) Non−HCI Only C) Entire Sample D) Non−HCI Only 4−Digit Panel 4−Digit Panel 5−Digit Panel 5−Digit Panel 0.06 0.04 0.04 0.050 0.03 0.04

0.02 0.02 0.025 0.02 0.01

Material Cost 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.000 −0.01 −0.02 −0.02

0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.03 0.03

0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02

0.01 0.01

Invest. Total 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

−0.02 −0.01 −0.01 1967 1972 1979 1986 1967 1972 1979 1986 1967 1972 1979 1986 1967 1972 1979 1986 Notes: Figure plots dynamic differences−in−differences estimates for the relationship between direct forward linkage exposure to HCI and outcomes: real total variable input costs (Material Cost, ihs), and real total gross capital formation (ihs) (Invest. Total, ihs). Estimates are relative to, 1972, the year before HCI. The year 1979 corresponds to collapse of Park regime. Years are on the x−axis. Estimates for the effect of direct forward (Linkage X Year) linkages are on y−axis. Panels (A) and (C) show estimates for the entire sample of industries, controlling the effect of direct targeting, HCI x Year. Panels (B) and (D) shows estimates for only non−targeted industry. Regressions include controls for direct backward linkage connections, interacted with time. Regression tables in Appendix. 95 percent confidence interveals are shown in gray.

29 Full regression estimates for prices are shown in Table E2. Like the direct impact of HCI on targeted sector prices, joint tests for significance in Table E2 show that pre-1973 prices were higher in more versus less linked industries. Point estimates also suggest they may have been trending downward prior to the policy. While the effects shown in Figure 7 suggest a substantial effect, it may be that these (differential) prices trends were in motion. However, if such trends were already occurring, it is notable that industrial policy did not buck this trend, much less raise prices in these sectors (see discussion for price results in section 4.2).

The overall, average relationship between forward linkages and output prices is significant, shown by DID es- timates in Table 8. DID estimates in panel A (col. 2) show a one unit rise in the share of total HCI links is asso- ciated with 0.26 percent lower output prices in forward-linked industry.

Table E4 shows correspond estimates for total, forward linkage exposure and prices. The impact of total for- ward linkages on prices is reliably negative for total forward linkage estimates.

Beyond output and prices, forward linkages positively impact downstream sectors across outcomes in Table 9. Estimates in 9 show a dynamic, positive relationship across employment (columns 1-2), average wage (3-4), number of establishments (5-6), and value added per worker (7-8). Estimates are most significant across the 1973-1979 push, precisely estimated in 5-digit data (panel A). In full and non-HCI industry samples, the num- ber of plants is significantly higher in forward-linked sectors, relative lesser-linked sectors, for all years past 1979. Labor productivity and wage estimates are noisier in non-HCI samples, and estimates for both outcomes dissipate after 1979.

Employment is also significantly higher in forward-linked sectors during the policy window. Before HCI, pan- els A and B in Table 9 show total employment was indistinguishable between high and low linkage industries (cols. 1-2). Across data, relative employment becomes significantly higher in the mid-1970s through the early 1980s, including in the non-HCI sample. Estimates become noisier in the 1980s, but remain positive.

Differences-in-differences estimates in Table E5 summarize the overall average impact of forward linkages on industrial development outcomes. Bolstering the dynamic estimates in Table 9, Table E5 shows a positive im- pact of forward linkages over the post-1973 period. Labor productivity estimates, due to its post-1979 fall, are noisiest. The average impact of forward linkages are also positive for total (Leontief) linkage effects, which are provided in Table E6. Thus, direct linkage effects also align with total linkage effects.

B) Forward Linkages and the Evolution of Downstream Comparative Advantage The impact of HCI on downstream exports is positive, and longer lasting. Above, I showed forward linkages were robustly related to downstream (external) industrial development during the 1973-1979 period, measures tended to become noisy in the post-1979 period compared to direct estimates in section 4.2.

Because the dynamics of comparative advantage are important here, I focus on event study differences-in- differences estimates, rather than average differences-in-differences estimates.

Figure 9 shows that improved export performance emerged during the HCI drive, and only ascended fully in the years after the end of HCI. Before 1973, forward-linked sectors had essentially no comparative advantage over other downstream sectors. If anything, their revealed comparative advantage may have trended downwards. Post-1973, the pattern shifts: Table E7 shows that across RCA measures, comparative advantage climbs in forward-linked industries. Estimates for export performance become larger and significant for the 1973-1979 period and into the 1980s.

Building on the direct effects in panel A, panel B of Table E7 shows total linkages effects. Relatedly, total link- age effects have a strong impact on dynamic comparative advantage. Estimates for total forward linkages be- come significant in around 1976, growing in magnitude through the end of the series. Thus, both direct and

30 total forward linkages with HCI industry correspond to the eventual comparative advantage of downstream industry.

The emergence of comparative advantage among users of HCI products is even stronger when we consider only domestic linkages. Above, Table E7 provided estimates using linkages measures from the general 1970 input-output tables, which did not yet distinguish between domestic and imported flows. Online Appendix Table 1 shows estimates using domestic-only input-output flows, which were introduced in the 1975 input-output accounts. Although these domestic-only tables come after the 1973 HCI announcement and are endogenous to the policy, they reify the impact of domestic forward linkage effects on downstream comparative advantage.

Taken together, HCI coincides with improved export performance and the emergence of comparative advan- tage in downstream industry; that is, for downstream exporters most connected to HCI suppliers. These ef- fects are robust across measures of RCA, as well as the types of forward linkages: direct, total, and domestic- only.

The positive evolution of downstream exporters is important for two reasons. First, these results show that HCI industrial policy may not only have promoted long-run development in (directly) targeted sectors, it may have a positive impact in external markets after the policy period. Though some external benefits of policy are contemporaneous, other external benefits, like those for downstream exporters, may take time to come to fruition.

Second, these results are consistent with the direct effects shown in section 4. Had HCI been unsuccessful in directly targeted sectors, it is likely that they would have harmed exporters—those sensitive to the competitive international market. This is particularly true where IP raises prices in targeted sectors, as in Blonigen (2016).

Figure 9: Impact of Direct Forward Linkages on the Evolution of Downstream Exports

A) Entire Sample B) Non−HCI Only

1.00

0.8 0.75

0.50 0.4

RCA (ihs) 0.25

0.0 0.00

0.6

0.4 0.4

0.2 0.2 I[RCA>1]

0.0 0.0

1967 1972 1979 1986 1967 1972 1979 1986 Notes: Figure plots dynamic differences−in−differences estimates for the relationship between direct forward linkage exposure to HCI and outcomes: revealed comparative advantage (RCA). Top row is RCA (ihs). The bottom row is the probability that RCA is greater than 1. Estimates are relative to, 1972, the year before HCI. The year 1979 corresponds to collapse of Park regime. Years are on the x−axis. Estimates for the effect of direct forward (Linkage X Year) linkages are on y−axis. Full sample regressions control for the main HCI x Year effect. All regressions include controls for direct backward linkage connections, interacted with time. Regression tables in Appendix. 95 percent confidence interveals are shown in gray.

31 C) Forward-Linkage Mechanisms, Investment, and HCI Intermediates If HCI policy positively impacted downstream industry, it likely did so through inputs. I consider this mechanism by focusing on the use of in- termediate goods and investment behavior in forward-linked industry.

To examine whether HCI benefited users of HCI inputs, I examine changes in the patterns of input use and investment in industries more versus less dependent on HCI goods. Figure 8 plots the differential evolution of input use and investment in downstream industry.

Before 1973, in Figure 8 differences in total materials and investment were converging between sectors with strong versus weak links. After 1973, this trend reverses. These differences jump for materials use (top row) and total gross fixed capital formation (bottom row) outcomes. This post-1973 divergence is seen in 4-digit data (panels A-B) and 5-digit data (panels C-D), and likewise is strong for the non-HCI sample.

Table E8 reports regression coefficients from Figure 8, and show the rise in materials use for the 1973-1979 pe- riod, with positive linkage effects after 1979. Post 1979, investment is particularly high in downstream sectors.

In addition total investment, Table E8 also presents investment in machinery. Equipment and machinery were particularly targeted by HCI industrial policy. Estimates in Table E8 show strong impacts of forward linkages on total fixed capital investment (3-4 and 11-12), and also for equipment investment. Investment for machines is particularly significant for the mid- to late-1970s.

Table 2 in the Online Appendix shows estimates using total forward linkages. If targeted HCI products were useful for downstream industry, then the cumulative impact of HCI inputs ought to similarly be useful. Esti- mates for total forward linkages in Table 2 in the Online Appendix show a positive impact for total forward linkages on materials and investments. All estimates are positive, and estimates are especially strong for mate- rials and investment for 4-digit data. Thus, the same pattern seen in direct linkages also emerges for measures of total forward linkages.

In sum, the patterns above show that over the HCI period, downstream users of HCI inputs—those industries reliant more on targeted intermediates—expanded outlays and output during the drive. More precisely, those sectors with higher HCI exposure (through forward links) increased their intermediate materials use and investment in fixed capital. For the latter, the effects were strong for the machinery—a sector specifically targeted by HCI.

5.3.2 Network Results - Backward Linkages and Impact on Upstream Industry

Since at least Hirschman (1958), proponents of industrial policy emphasized that interventions promote spillovers through backward linkages. I show that in the context of the HCI drive, the spillovers from HCI to upstream suppliers may have been limited. In exploring the impacts of HCI on upstream industry, I suggest that HCI likely had the strongest impact through forward-linkage, or supply-side effects, rather than by supporting upstream demand.

In the HCI environment, the expansion of targeted sectors can have ambiguous impacts on backward-linked sectors. On one hand, growth in targeted industries may increase demand for inputs, thus transmitting shocks to upstream suppliers through backward linkages.

On the other hand, features of HCI industrial policy may limit the scope of these effects. For example, if targeted sectors are compelled to import inputs. For HCI, targeted sectors were provided import exemptions. Similarly, financial incentives increased the use of intermediates (shown in section 4.3), which were potentially imported. Alternatively, because HCI sectors tended to be more upstream (shown by Liu (2019) with this IO data), the extent of backward linkages effects may also be limited.

32 Figure F1 illustrates the ambiguous or negative impact of HCI on upstream industry output, measured by real value added. Importantly, Figure F1 shows direct linkage estimates, which reflect the extent of direct ties be- tween suppliers and HCI sectors.

Before 1973, Figure F1 shows upstream industries with stronger direct links were already in decline relative to those with weaker direct links. Table F1 reports the full estimates from Fig. F1, alongside alternative specifica- tions. Results in panel B (Table F1 show that backward-linked sectors were significantly different, and trend- ing downward. Joint tests were strongest for the Non-HCI sample (column 4).

The downward trend among backward-linked sectors was not stopped by the ascent of downstream HCI in- dustry in 1973. Figure F1 reports noisy effects of direct backward linkages on output during the HCI period. Table F1 shows—across samples and data—estimates for 1973-1979 are uniformly weak and negative. After 1979, negative estimates in Table F1 are amplified, becoming stronger through the 1980s. This relative decline is seen across estimates in Figure F1 for the 1980s.

Table F2 goes beyond the impact of HCI on direct suppliers, and considers measures of total n-degree connections. Unlike the direct effects in Table F1, total linkage effects are weak and ambiguous: small and weakly negative in 5-digit data (panel A), and weakly negative in 4-digit data (panel B). Thus, the effect of total linkages on upstream suppliers seems more ambiguous than direct linkages.

The average, overall impact of backward linkages on output are report in Table 7 for direct links, and Table ?? for total links. Coefficients on backward linkage estimates are much smaller than forward effects, which are shown in both tables. The average backward linkage estimates (Table 7) are weakly negative, but anemic. The total backward effects linkage effects tend more toward zero (Table E3).

Figure F2 highlights a potential reason for the lackluster impact of HCI on backward linked industry. One rea- son may be that HCI allowed targeted industry to expand their use of imported inputs.

If this is the case, I should observe a rise in imported goods that are used in HCI production. Thus, I rerun the same regression shown in Figure F1, but using import values as the outcome of interest, instead of the value of domestic output.

Figure F2 plots the results from this regression, and shows a large, but noisy, rise in imports for goods with higher backward links to HCI versus lower links. Put differently, I show an increase in imports more inten- sively used by HCI industry. The left of F1 reports estimates for direct linkages, while the right reports esti- mates for total Leontief linkages. The estimates in Figure F2 show that import competition, by virtue of HCI policy, may have dampened or limited HCI’s benefit on upstream producers.

5.4 Networks: Discussion

Focusing on forward linkages—spillovers from targeted industry to downstream users of HCI products—and backward linkages—spillovers from targeted industry to suppliers of inputs to HCI production—the results above showed the power of downstream effects relative to upstream impacts. I show that HCI had positive im- pacts on the industrial development of downstream users. In other words, the benefits of HCI were passed on to users of HCI inputs, rather than through the power of building upstream demand.

This dovetails with work by Liu (2019), whose theoretical work shows that optimal targeting of industrial pol- icy in the network may correspond to influential, upstream sectors (specifically, those with high "distortion centrality). Using input-output tables from this study, Liu showed that Korean HCI sectors correspond to this sufficient statistic for targeting. The differences-in-differences estimates herein show upstream targeting may

33 propagate to downstream industries. Conversely, the potential of upstream sectors to transmit demand effects through backward linkages might be limited.45

That is, the development of key upstream, intermediate sectors may catalyze downstream users. I showed that these downstream users expanded outlays and outputs. Moreover, those with stronger forward linkages in- creased their use of inputs, like steel, and investment in intermediate capital goods targeted by HCI, like ma- chinery.

These results align with spillovers effects emphasized by scholars of foreign direct investment, which has long explored the potential positive spillovers of FDI through linkages (Javorcik 2004b; Harrison and Rodríguez-Clare 2010). For example, the forward linkage results in the above paper share commonalities with the welfare-enhancing effects of FDI studied by Blalock and Gertler (2008) in Indonesia. Here, FDI improved productivity for upstream input producers, who in turn passed benefits on to downstream—and external—users of output.

6 Conclusion

This paper shows that HCI promoted industrial development in manufacturing sectors targeted by the policy. In addition, I show the industrial intervention had wide ramifications. First, the drive created positive effects in treated industries long after major elements of the policy were retrenched. Moreover, the regime’s policy created both temporary and durable effects in sectors not directly targeted by policy. I show that in the case of export performance and comparative advantage, these effects were only fully realized after the policy had ended.

The role of industrial policy in the East Asian growth miracle has long been debated by economists (Rodrik, Grossman, and Norman 1995; Lal 1983; Krueger 1995). This study provides some of the first estimates on the impact of infant industry policy on industrial development. In doing so, I add to a nascent literature using his- torical, natural experiments to understand the foundations of industrial development (Juhasz 2018; Hanlon 2020; Giorcelli 2019; Mitrunen 2019).

I show real output in treated industries doubled, relative to non-targeted manufacturing industries during the policy period, while also fostering growth in export activity and significant drops in output prices. My study shows that, unlike IP in many places, realized HCI policies correspond to de jure industrial policy. In doing so, I hint that Korea IP relied on investment incentives and the availability of imported intermediates, rather than the overt protection of output markets. This is compatible with recent work importance of quality intermedi- ates in industrial development (Goldberg et al. 2010; Verhoogen 2020).

I use the HCI context to study two important justifications for industrial policy: dynamic comparative advantage and spillovers. Using the assassination of President Park, which liberalized trade and capital markets, I show that the direct impact of industrial policy persisted long after the de facto end date of the policy. Importantly, my study provides evidence that targeted industries impacted external industries through the input-output network. I show the development of HCI goods—their expansion and decline in prices—benefited downstream industries dependent on HCI intermediates. Downstream producers with stronger (forward) links to treated sectors grew relatively more—in terms of output, plant entry, and employment—than downstream industries with weaker links.

For industry downstream from HCI, I also show evidence that sectors with stronger forward-linkages invested more in capital, especially those goods targeted by HCI (e.g. equipment) and increased outlays for

45This does not rule out the potential of other forms of backward linkages effects, like the technological spillovers emphasized in the FDI literature Javorcik (2004a).

34 intermediates. After the end of the policy in 1979, I show forward-linked sectors also attained competitive advantage as exporters—trends that were sown during the active years of the HCI drive.

This study turns to a key industrial intervention: South Korea’s heavy industrial push. My findings corre- spond to aspects of qualitative arguments posed by Wade (1990) and Amsden (1992). The results in this study, however, emphasize rather conventional economic mechanisms and forces. The impacts of my study are nonetheless related to more conventional policy levers, such as investment incentives and the promotion of import intermediate inputs. These results update earlier work by Hirschman (1958) and others, indicating that the impacts of traditional policy prescriptions may be complex in a world with imported intermediate markets. Similarly, if upstream sectors are optimal nodes to target, this can limit the extent of demand effects through traditional backward linkages.

While my study highlights the impacts of industrial policy on industrial development outcomes, I have not delved into issues of total factor productivity and allocative efficiency, which I investigate deeper in an upcoming analysis. A next step for future research would be to fully account for the effects of industrial policy on the aggregate economy. Furthermore, the context of this study hints that successful IP depends on bureaucratic capacity (Johnson 1982; Evans 1995; Fukuyama 2014) and political incentive compatibility (Haggard 1990; Chibber 2002; Robinson 2010; Vu 2010). Such conditions may be rarely satisfied (Krueger 1990), indicating the importance of future work on the of IP.

35 7 References

Acemoglu, Daron, David Autor, David Dorn, Gordon H Hanson, and Brendan Price. 2015. “Import Competition and the Great US Employment Sag of the 2000s.” Journal of Labor Economics 34 (S1): S141–S198.

Adelman, Irma. 1969. Practical Approaches to Development Planning: Korea’s Second Five-Year Plan. Edited by Irma Adelman. Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins Press. http://books.google.com/books?id=Sem5AAAAIAAJ%7B/&%7Dpgis=1.

Aghion, Philippe, Jing Cai, Mathias Dewatripont, Luosha Du, Ann Harrison, and Patrick Legros. 2015. “Industrial policy and competition.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.20120103.

Aihounton, Ghislain B D, and Arne Henningsen. 2020. “Units of measurement and the inverse hyperbolic sine transforma- tion.” The Econometrics Journal, October. https://doi.org/10.1093/ectj/utaa032.

Amiti, Mary, and Jozef Konings. 2007. “Trade Liberalization, Intermediate Inputs, and Productivity: Evidence from Indone- sia.” 97 (5): 1611–38.

Amsden, AH. 1992. Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. Second. New York, New York: Oxford University Press.

Baldwin, Richard, and . 1988. “Market Access and International Competition: A Simulation Study of 16K Random Access Memories.” In Empirical Methods for International Trade, edited by Robert Feenstra, 1st ed., 171–97. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Baldwin, Robert E. 1969. “The Case against Infant Industry Tariff Protection.” Journal of Political Economy 77 (3): 295–305.

Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duflo. 2014. “Do Firms Want to Borrow More? Testing Credit Constraints Using a Directed Lending Program.” The Review of Economic Studies 81 (2): 572–607. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdt046.

Barwick, Panle Jia, Myrto Kalouptsidi, and Nahim Bin Zahur. 2019. “China’s industrial policy: An empirical evaluation.” National Bureau of Economic Research.

Beason, Richard, and David E Weinstein. 1996. “Growth, Economies of Scale, and Targeting in Japan (1955-1990).” The Re- view of Economics and Statistics 78 (2): 286–95.

Becker, SO, PH Egger, and M Von Ehrlich. 2010. “Going NUTS: The effect of EU Structural Funds on regional performance.” Journal of Public Economics. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S004727271000071X.

Bellemare, Marc F, and Casey J Wichman. 2020. “Elasticities and the Inverse Hyperbolic Sine Transformation.” Oxford Bul- letin of Economics and Statistics 82 (1): 50–61. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1111/obes.12325.

Besley, Timothy, and Torsten Persson. 2010. “State Capacity, Conflict, and Development.” Econometrica 78 (1): 1–34.

———. 2011. Pillars of Prosperity: The Political Economics of Development Clusters. The Yrjö Jahnsson Lectures. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

Blalock, Garrick, and Paul J Gertler. 2008. “Welfare gains from Foreign Direct Investment through technology transfer to lo- cal suppliers.” Journal of International Economics 74 (2): 402–21. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2007.05. 011.

Blonigen, Bruce A. 2016. “Industrial Policy and Downstream Export Performance.” The Economic Journal 126 (595): 1635–59. https://doi.org/doi:10.1111/ecoj.12223.

Callaway, Brantly, and Pedro H C Sant’Anna. 2020. “Difference-in-differences with multiple time periods.” Journal of Econo- metrics.

Carpenter, Robert E, Steven M Fazzari, Bruce C Petersen, Anil K Kashyap, and Benjamin M Friedman. 1994. “Inventory In- vestment, Internal-Finance Fluctuations, and the Business Cycle.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1994 (2): 75–138. https://doi.org/10.2307/2534655.

Castley, Robert. 1997. Korea’s Economic Miracle: The Crucial Role of Japan. First. London; Basingstoke, U.K.: Palgrave Macmil- lan UK.

Cerqua, Augusto, and Guido Pellegrini. 2017. “Industrial policy evaluation in the presence of spillovers.” Small Business Eco- nomics 49 (3): 671–86. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-017-9855-9.

Chang, Ha-Joon. 2003. Globalization, Economic Development and the Role of the State. London, UK; New York, NY: Zed Books.

Cheng, Tun-jen. 1990. “Political Regimes and Development Strategies.” In Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in and East Asia, edited by Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, 139–78. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

36 ———. 2001. “Transforming Taiwan’s Economic Structure in the 20th Century.” In Taiwan in the Twentieth Century: A Ret- rospective View, edited by Richard Louis Edmonds and Steven M. Goldstein, 19–36. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.

Chibber, Vivek. 2002. “Bureaucratic Rationality and the Developmental State.” American Journal of Sociology 107 (4): 951–89.

Cho, Yoon Je. 1989. “Finance and Development: The Korean Approach.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 5 (4): 88–102.

Cho, Yoon-Je, and David C Cole. 1986. The Role of the Financial Sector in Korea’s Structural Adjustment. Development Discus- sion Paper. Harvard Institute for International Development, .

Cho, Yoon-Je, and Joon-Kyung Kim. 1995. “Credit Policies and the Industrialization of Korea.” Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

Choi, Tae Young, and Su Gyo Lee. 1989. “Effect analysis of US military aid to the Republic of Korea.” Declassified, Naval Postgraduate School; Naval Postgraduate School Archive.

Criscuolo, Chiara, Ralf Martin, Henry Overman, John Van Reenen, and John Van Reenen. 2019. “Some Causal Effects of an Industrial Policy.” American Economic Review 109 (1): 48–85. https://doi.org/DOI:%2010.1257/aer.20160034.

Cushman, John H. 1979. “The Military Balance in Korea.” Asian Affairs: An American Review 6 (6): 359–69.

Dasgupta, Sudipto, Erica X N Li, and Dong Yan. 2019. “Inventory Behavior and Financial Constraints: Theory and Evidence.” The Review of Financial Studies 32 (3): 1188–1233. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhy064.

Dell, Melissa, Nathan Lane, and Pablo Querubin. 2018. “The Historical State, Local Collective Action, and Economic Devel- opment in Vietnam.” Econometrica 86 (6): 2083–2121. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA15122.

Dollar, David, and Kenneth Sokoloff. 1990. “Patterns of productivity growth in South Korean manufacturing industries, 1963–1979.” Journal of Development Economics 33 (2): 309–27.

Eberstadt, Nick. 1999. The End of North Korea. Washington, D.C.: The AEI Press.

El-Agraa, Ali M. 1997. “UK Competitiveness Policy vs. Japanese Industrial Policy.” The Economic Journal 107 (444): 1504–17. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.1997.tb00061.x.

Evans, Peter B. 1995. Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

Feenstra, Robert C, Robert Inklaar, and Marcel P Timmer. 2015. “The Next Generation of the Penn World Table.” American Economic Review 105 (10): 3150–82.

Flam, Harry, Torsten Persson, and Lars Svensson. 1983. “Optimal Subsidies to Declining Industries: Efficiency and Equity Considerations.” Journal of Public Economics 22: 327–45.

Fukuyama, Francis. 2014. Political Order and Political Decay, from the industrial revolution to the Globalization of Democracy. First. New York, New York: Farrar, Straus,; Giroux.

Giorcelli, Michela. 2019. “The Long-Term Effects of Management and Technology Transfers.” American Economic Review 109 (1): 1–33.

Goldberg, Pinelopi Koujianou, Amit Kumar Khandelwal, Nina Pavcnik, and Petia Topalova. 2010. “Imported intermediate inputs and domestic product growth: Evidence from India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (4): 1727–67. https://doi. org/10.1162/qjec.2010.125.4.1727.

Goldberg, P K, and N Pavcnik. 2016. “Chapter 3 - The Effects of Trade Policy.” In, edited by Kyle Bagwell and Robert W B T - Handbook of Commercial Policy Staiger, 1:161–206. North-Holland. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/bs.hesco p.2016.04.002.

Greenwald, Bruce, and Joseph E Stiglitz. 2006. “Helping Infant Economies Grow: Foundations of Trade Policies for Develop- ing Countries.” American Economic Review 96 (2): 141–46. http://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/00028280677721 2206.

Grossman, Gene M. 1990. “Promoting New Industrial Activities: A Survey of Recent Arguments and Evidence.” OECD Jour- nal: Economic Studies, no. 14: 87–125.

Grubel, Herbert G. 1966. “The Anatomy of Classical and Modern Infant Industry Arguments.” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 97: 325–44. http://www.jstor.org/stable/40436711.

Haggard, Stephan. 1990. The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries. First. Ithaca, New York; London, U.K.: Cornell University Press.

Hamm, Taik-young. 1999. Arming the Two Koreas: State, Capital and Military Power. Vol. 10. London, England; New York, New York: Routledge.

37 Han, Sungjoo. 1978. “South Korea 1977: Preparing for Self-Reliance.” Asian Survey 18 (1): 45–57.

Hanlon, W Walker. 2020. “The Persistent Effect of Temporary Input Cost Advantages in Shipbuilding, 1850 to 1911.” Journal of the European Economic Association 18 (6): 3173–3209. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeea/jvz067.

Harris, Richard, Ian Keay, and Frank Lewis. 2015. “Protecting infant industries: Canadian manufacturing and the national policy, 1870–1913.” Explorations in Economic History 56: 15–31. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eeh.2015.01.00 1.

Harrison, AE Ann E. 1994. “An Empirical Test of the Infant Industry Argument: Comment.” The American Economic Review 84 (4): 1090–5. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2118047.

Harrison, Ann E, and Andres Rodriguez-Clare. 2009. “Trade, Foreign Investment, and Industrial Policy for Developing Countries.” In Handbook of Development Economics, Volume 5, edited by Dani Rodrik and Mark Rosenzweig, 4039–4214. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier B.V.; North-Holland.

Harrison, Ann, and Andrés Rodríguez-Clare. 2010. “Trade, Foreign Investment, and Industrial Policy for Developing Coun- tries.” In Handbooks in Economics, edited by Dani Rodrik and Mark Rosenzweig, 5:4039–4214. Elsevier. https://doi.org/ https://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-444-52944-2.00001-X.

Head, Keith. 1994. “Infant Industry Protection in the Steel Rail Industry.” Journal of International Economics 37 (3): 141–65. ht tps://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(94 90043-4. ) Herrera, Ana María. 2018. “OIL PRICE SHOCKS, INVENTORIES, AND MACROECONOMIC DYNAMICS.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 22 (3): 620–39. https://doi.org/DOI:%2010.1017/S1365100516000225.

Hillman, Arye L. 1982. “Declining Industries and Political-Support Protectionist Motives.” American Economic Review 72 (5): 1180–7.

Hirschman, Albert O. 1958. The Strategy of Economic Development. Third. New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press.

Hong, Wontack. 1987. “Export-Oriented Growth and Trade Patterns of Korea.” In Trade and Structural Change in Pacific Asia, edited by Jr Colin I. Bradford and William H. Branson, 273–306. Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press.

Horikane, Yumi. 2005. “The Political Economy of Heavy Industrialisation: The Heavy and Chemical Industry (HCI) Push in South Korea in the 1970s.” Modern Asian Studies 39 (2): 369–97.

Inwood, Kris, and Ian Keay. 2013. “Trade policy and industrial development: iron and steel in a small open economy, 1870- 1913.” Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d’économique 46 (4): 1265–94. https://doi.org/10.1111/caje.120 48.

Irwin, Douglas A. 2000. “Did Late-Nineteenth-Century U.S. Tariffs Promote Infant Industries? Evidence from the Tinplate Industry.” The Journal of Economic History 60 (2): 335–60. https://doi.org/DOI:%2010.1017/S0022050700025122.

Javorcik, Beata Smarzynska. 2004a. “Does Foreign Direct Investment Increase the Productivity of Domestic Firms? In Search of Spillovers through Backward Linkages.” The American Economic Review 94 (3): 605–27. http://www.jstor.org/stable/3 592945.

———. 2004b. “Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domestic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages.” The American Economic Review 94 (3): 605–27.

Jaworski, Taylor, and Andrew Smyth. 2018. “Shakeout in the early commercial airframe industry.” The Economic History Re- view 71 (2): 617–38. https://doi.org/10.1111/ehr.12430.

Johnson, Chalmers. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy : 1925-1975. Stanford, California: Stan- ford University Press.

Jones, Christopher S, and Selale Tuzel. 2013. “Inventory investment and the cost of capital.” Journal of Financial Economics 107 (3): 557–79. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.09.001.

Juhasz, Reka. 2018. “Temporary Protection and Technology Adoption: Evidence from the Napoleonic Blockade.” American Economic Review 108 (11): 3339–76. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20151730.

Kalouptsidi, Myrto. 2018. “Detection and Impact of Industrial Subsidies: The Case of Chinese Shipbuilding.” The Review of Economic Studies 85 (2): 1111–58. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdx050.

Kamada, Tomihisa, and Satoru Kawai. 1989. “An Algorithm for Drawing General Undirected Graphs.” Information Process- ing Letters 31 (1): 7–15.

Kim, Byung-kook, and EF Vogel. 2011. “The leviathan: Economic bureaucracy under Park.” Edited by Byung-kook Kim and Ezra Vogel. The Park Chung Hee Era: The Transformation of South Korea, 200–233. http://scholar.google.se/scholar?hl=en %7B/&%7Dq=The Leviathan%7B/%%7D3A Economic Bureaucracy under Park Chung Hee%7B/&%7DbtnG=% 7B/&%7Das%7B/_%7Dsdt=1%7B/%%7D2C22%7B/&%7Das%7B/_%7Dsdtp=%7B/#%7D1.+ + + + + + +

38 Kim, Do Hoon DaHoon, Young Seok Oh, Kye Hwan Kim, Ma Joy V. Abrenca, Mauricio Canedo Pinheiro, and Chen Tsung Yun. 2013. “A Study on International Comparisons of Processes and Policies for Developing Heavy and Chemical Indus- tries.” Research Report. Seoul: Korea Institute for Industrial Economics; Trade.

Kim, Eun Mee. 1988. “From Dominance to Symbiosis: State and Chaebol in Korea.” Pacific Focus 3 (2): 105–21.

———. 1997. Big Business, Strong State: Collusion and Conflict in South Korean Development, 1960-1990. Albany, New York: State University of New York Press.

Kim, Hyung-A. 2011. “Heavy and Chemical Industrialization, 1973-1979: South Korea’s Homeland Security Measures.” Re- assessing the Park Chung Hee Era, 1961-1979; Development, Political Thought, Democracy, & Cultural Influence.

Kim, Ji Hong. 1990. “Korean Industrial Policy in the 1970’s: The Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive.” Seoul: Korea Devel- opment Institute.

Kim, Joon-Kyung, Sang Dal Shim, and Jun-Il Kim. 1995. “The Role of Government in Promoting Industrialization and Hu- man Capital Accumulation in Korea.” In Growth Theories in Light of the East Asian Experience, Nber-Ease Volume 4, edited by Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, 181–200. Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press.

Kim, Kihwan, and Danny M Leipziger. 1993. “Korea: a Case of Government-Led Development.” In The Lessons of East Asia, Third. Washington, D.C.: World Bank Publications.

Kim, Kwang-Doo. 2005. “Financing the Economic Development: The Role of Government, Banks, Capital Market.” In KIEP- University of Sao Paulo Joint Seminar. Sao Paulo, Brazil.

Kim, Kwang Suk. 1994. “Trade and Industrialization Policies in Korea: An overview.” In Trade Policy and Industrialization in Turbulent Times, edited by Gerald K. Helleiner, First, 317–63. New York, New York: Routledge.

Kim, Se Jin. 1970. “South Korea’s Involvement in Vietnam and Its Economic and Political Impact.” Asian Survey 10 (6): 519– 32.

Kim, Seung-Young. 2001. “Security, nationalism and the pursuit of nuclear weapons and missiles: The South Korean case, 1970–82.” Diplomacy and Statecraft 12 (4): 53–80.

Kohli, Atul. 2004. State-Directed Development: Political Power and Industrialization in the Global Periphery. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Kong, Tat Yan. 2000. The Politics of Economic Reform in South Korea: A Fragile Miracle. Routledge Advances in Korean Studies. London, England; New York, New York: Routledge; Taylor & Francis Group.

Koo, Bohn-Young. 1984. “The Role of the Government in Korea’s Industrial Development: A paper submitted to the U.S.I.T.C. for its Study on ’Industrial Targeting Practices in Korea’.” Seoul: Korea Development Institute.

Krueger, Anne O. 1979. The Developmental Role of the Foreign Sector and Aid. Cambridge, Massachusetts; London, England: Council on East Asian Studies, Harvard University; Harvard University Press.

———. 1990. “Government Failures in Development.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 4 (3): 9–23.

———. 1995. “East Asian Experience and Endogenous Growth Theory.” In Growth Theories in Light of the East Asian Experi- ence, Nber-Ease Volume 4, 9–36. Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press.

Krueger, Anne O., and Baran Tuncer. 1982. “An Empirical Test of the Infant Industry Argument.” American Economic Review 72 (5): 1142–52. http://www.jstor.org/stable/1812029.

Krugman, Paul R. 1993. “The Current Case for Industrial Policy.” In Protectionism and World Welfare, edited by Dominick Salvatore, 160–79. Cambridge, U.K; New York, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Kwack, Taewon. 1984. “Industrial Restructuring Experience and Policies in Korea in the 1970s.” KDI Working Paper Series. Seoul: Korean Development Institute.

———. 1985. “Depreciation and Taxation of Income from Capital.” Seoul, Korea: Korean Development Institute.

Kwack, Taewon, and Kye-Sik Lee. 1992. “Tax Reform in Korea.” In The Political Economy of Tax Reform, Nber-East Asia Seminar on Economics Volume 1, edited by Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, First, 117–36. Chicago, Illinois; London, England: University of Chicago Press.

Kwak, Tae Yang. 2003. “The Nixon Doctrine and the Yusin Reforms: American Foreign Policy, the Vietnam War, and the Rise of Authoritarianism in Korea, 1968–1973.” Journal of American-East Asian Relations 12 (1): 33–34.

Lal, Deepak. 1983. The Poverty of Development Economics. London, England: Institute of Economics Affairs.

Lall, Sanjaya. 1996. “‘The East Asian Miracle’ Study: Does the Bell Toll for Industrial Strategy?” In Learning from the Asian Tigers: Studies in Technology and Industrial Policy, edited by Sanjaya Lall, 107–23. London, England: Palgrave Macmillan UK.

39 ———. 1997. “Selective Policies for Export Promotion Lessons from Asian Tigers - Lall WP 1997.” Research for Action 43. Helsinki: UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research.

———. 1995. “Malaysia: Industrial success and the role of the government.” Journal of International Development 7 (5): 759–73.

Lane, Nathan. 2020. “The New Empirics of Industrial Policy.” Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 1 (2): 1–26. https:// doi.org/10.1007/s10842-019-00323-2.

Lawrence, Robert Z, and David E Weinstein. 1999. “Trade and growth: import-led or export-led? Evidence from Japan and Korea.” National bureau of economic research.

Lazzarini, Sergio G, Aldo Musacchio, Rodrigo Bandeira-de-Mello, and Rosilene Marcon. 2015. “What Do State-Owned De- velopment Banks Do? Evidence from BNDES, 2002–09.” World Development 66: 237–53. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.worlddev.2014.08.016.

Lee, Chong-Sik. 1980. “South Korea 1979: Confrontation, Assassination, and Transition.” Asian Survey 20 (1): 63–76. https: //doi.org/10.2307/2644008.

Lee, Jong-Wha. 1996. “Government Interventions and Productivity Growth.” Journal of Economic Growth 1 (3): 391–414.

Lee, Nae-young. 2011. “The Automobile Industry.” In The Park Chung Hee Era: The Transformation of South Korea, edited by Byung-Kook Kim and Ezra F. Vogel, 295–321. Cambridge, Massachusetts; London, England: Harvard University Press.

Lee, Suk-Chae. 1991. “The Heavy and Chemical Industries Promotion Plan (1973-1979).” In Economic Development in the Re- public of Korea: A Policy Perspective, edited by Lee-Jay Cho and Yoon Hyung Kim, 431–71. Honolulu, Hawaii: East-West Center, University of Hawaii Press.

Lin, Justin Yifu. 2012. New Structural Economics: A Framework for Rethinking Development and Policy. Vol. 26. 2. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

Lindbeck, Assar. 1981. “Industrial Policy as an Issue in the Economic Environment.” The World Economy 4 (4): 391–406.

Liu, Ernest. 2019. “Industrial Policies in Production Networks.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, no. Forthcoming.

Luedde-Neurath, Richard. 1986. Import controls and Export-Oriented Development: a Reassessment of the South Korean case. Boul- der, Colorado; Londong, England: Westview Press.

Manova, Kalina, Shang-Jin Wei, and Zhiwei Zhang. 2015. “Firm exports and multinational activity under credit constraints.” Review of Economics and Statistics 97 (3): 574–88.

Martin, Leslie A, Shanthi Nataraj, and Ann E Harrison. 2017. “In with the Big, Out with the Small: Removing Small-Scale Reservations in India.” American Economic Review 107 (2): 354–86. http://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/aer.2014 1335.

Mason, Edward Sagendorph. 1980. The Economic and Social Modernization of the Republic of Korea. Third. Council on East Asian Studies, Harvard University; Harvard University Press.

Melitz, Marc J. 2005. “When and how should infant industries be protected?” Journal of International Economics 66 (1): 177–96. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2004.07.001.

Meredith, H O. 1906. “Protection of Infant Industries.” The Economic Journal 16 (61): 1–11. https://doi.org/10.2307/2221136.

Mitrunen, Matti. 2019. “War Reparations, Structural Change, and Intergenerational Mobility.”

Moon, Chung-in, and Byung-joon Jun. 2011. “Modernization Strategy: Ideas and Influences.” In The Park Chung Hee Era: The Transformation of South Korea, edited by Byung-Kook Kim and Ezra F. Vogel, 115–39. Cambridge, Massachusetts; London, England: Harvard University Press.

Moon, Chung-in, and Sangkeun Lee. 2009. “Military Spending and the Arms Race on the Korean Peninsula.” Asian Perspec- tive 33 (4): 69–99.

Moreira, Mauricio Mesquita. 1994. “Industrialization, Trade and Market Failures: the Role of Government Intervention in Brazil.” Revista Brasileira de Economia 48 (3): 295–324.

Musacchio, Aldo, Sergio G Lazzarini, and Ruth V Aguilera. 2015. “New Varieties of State Capitalism: Strategic and Gov- ernance Implications.” Academy of Management Perspectives 29 (1): 115–31. https://doi.org/10.5465/amp.2013.009 4.

Nam, Chong-Hyun. 1980. “Trade and Industrial Policies, and the Structure of Protection in Korea.” Seoul: Korea Develop- ment Institute.

———. 1995. “The Role of Trade and Exchange Rate Policy in Korea’s Growth.” In Growth Theories in Light of the East Asian Experience, Nber-Ease Volume 4, edited by Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, 153–79. Chicago, Illinois: National Bureau of Economic Research; University of Chicago Press.

40 Nam, Sang-Woo. 1992. “Korea’s financial reform since the early 1980s.” In Financial Reform: Theory and Experience, edited by Gerard Caprio, Izak Atiyas, and James A. Hanson, 184–222. New York, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Nelson, Richard R, and Howard Pack. 1998. “The Asian Miracle and Modern Growth Theory.” The Economic Journal 109 (1881): 416–36.

Nixon, Richard M. 1969. Public Papers of the Presidents of the United States - Richard Nixon. Washington, D.C.: Office of the Fed- eral Register, Government Printing Office.

———. 1970. “Letter From President Nixon to Korean President Park.” In Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969-1976, edited by Edward C Keefer and Carolyn Yee, 2010th ed., XIX:152–54. Washington, D.C.: United States Government Printing Office.

Noland, Marcus. 2004. “Selective Intervention and Growth: The Case of Korea.” In Empirical Methods in International Trade: Essays in Honor of Mordechai Kreinin, edited by Michael G. Plummer, 229–46. August. Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

Noland, Marcus, and Howard Pack. 2003. Industrial Policy in an Era of Globalization: Lessons from Asia. Washington, D.C.: Insti- tute for International Economics.

Nunn, Nathan, and Daniel Trefler. 2010. “The Structure of Tariffs and Long-Term Growth.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (4): 158–94.

Nurkse, Ragnar. 1953. Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

Ostermann, Christian F., and James F. Person. 2011. “The rise and fall of Détente on the Korean Peninsula, 1970-1974.” In History and Public Policy Program Critical Oral History Conference Series, edited by Christian F Ostermann and James F Per- son. Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars.

Pack, Howard. 2000. “Industrial Policy: Growth Elixir or Poison?” The World Bank Research Observer 15 (1): 47–67.

Pack, Howard, and Kamal Saggi. 2006. “Is there a case for industrial policy? A critical survey.” The World Bank Research Ob- server 21 (2): 267–97.

Panchamukhi, Vadiraj R. 1978. Trade Policies of India: A Quantitative Analysis. Delhi: Concept Publishing.

Park, Tong-Ho. 1977. “A Study on the Industry Tariff System of Korea - with refer to Heavy & Chemical Industry Develop- ment” 4 (5): 173–214.

Perkins, Dwight H. 2013. East Asian Development: Foundations and Strategies (The Edwin O. Reischauer Lectures). Cambridge, Massachusetts; London, England: Harvard University Press.

Pons-Benaiges, Oriol. 2017. “Did Government Intervention Target Technological Externalities? Industrial Policy and Eco- nomic Growth in Postwar Japan, 1964-1983.”

Rasmussen, Poul Nørregaard. 1956. Studies in Inter-Sectoral Relations. First. (København) Copenhagen, Denmark: E. Harck.

Rhyu, Sang-young, and Seok-jin Lew. 2011. “Pohang Iron & Steel Company.” In The Park Chung Hee Era: The Transformation of South Korea, 322–44. Cambridge, Massachusetts; London, England: Harvard University Press.

Robinson, James A. 2010. “Industrial Policy and Development: A Political Economy Perspective.” In Annual World Bank Con- ference on Development Economics 2010 - Global: Lessons from East Asia and the Global Financial Crisis, edited by Justin Yifu Lin and Boris Pleskovic, 61–79. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

Rodriguez, Francisco, and Dani Rodrik. 2001. “Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross-National Evidence.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Volume 15, 15:261–338. January. University of Chicago Press. https: //doi.org/10.1086/654419.

Rodrik, Dani. 2004. “Industrial Policy for the Twenty-First Century.” John F. Kennedy School of Government.

———. 2005. “Growth Strategies.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf, 1:967– 1014. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier B.V.; North-Holland.

———. 2012. “Why We Learn Nothing from Regressing Economic Growth on Policies.” Seoul Journal of Economics 25 (2): 137–51.

Rodrik, Dani, Gene Grossman, and Victor Norman. 1995. “Getting Interventions Right: How South Korea and Taiwan Grew Rich.” Economic Policy 10 (20): 53–107. https://doi.org/10.2307/1344538.

Rogers, William P. 1970. “Telegram From the Department of State to the Embassy in Korea.” In Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969-1976, edited by Edward C Keefer and Carolyn Yee, 2010th ed., XIX:150–52. Washington, D.C.: United States Government Printing Office.

Rosenstein-Rodan, Paul N. 1943. “Problems of Industrialisation of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe.” The Economic Journal 53 (210/211): 202–11.

41 Rotemberg, Martin. 2017. “Equilibrium Effects of Firm Subsidies.”

Sant’Anna, Pedro H C, and Jun Zhao. 2020. “Doubly robust difference-in-differences estimators.” Journal of Econometrics 219 (1): 101–22.

Schmitz Jr, James A. 2001. “Government production of investment goods and aggregate labor productivity.” Journal of Mone- tary Economics 47 (1): 163–87.

Scitovsky, Tibor. 1954. “Two Concepts of External Economies.” Journal of Political Economy 62 (2): 143–51.

Scobell, Andrew, and John M. Sanford. 2007. “North Korea’s Military Threat: Pyongyang’s Conventional Forces, Weapons of Mass Destruction, and Ballistic Missiles.” Carlisle Barracks, Pennsylvania: U.S. Army War College Strategic Studies Institute.

Sloczynski, Tymon. 2018. “A General Weighted Average Representation of the Ordinary and Two-Stage Least Squares Esti- mands.” Working Papers. Brandeis University, Department of Economics; International Businesss School. https://doi.or g/DOI:

Stern, Joseph J, Ji-hong Kim, Dwight H Perkins, and Jung-ho Yoo. 1995. Industrialization and the State: The Korean Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard Institute for International Development.

Taylor, William J, Jennifer A Smith, and Michael J Mazarr. 1990. “US Troop Reductions from Korea, 1970–1990.” The Journal of East Asian Affairs 4 (2): 256–86.

Trager, Frank N. 1972. “The Nixon Doctrine and Asian Policy.” Southeast Asian Perspectives, no. 6: 1–34.

Trela, Irene, and John Whalley. 1990. “Taxes, outward orientation, and growth performance in Korea.” Policy, Research, and External Affairs Working Paper Series. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

Verhoogen, Eric. 2020. “Firm-Level Upgrading in Developing Countries.” CDEP-CGEG.

Vogel, Ezra. 1991. The Four Little Dragons: The Spread of Industrialization in East Asia. Cambridge, Massachusetts; London, England: Harvard University Press.

Vu, Tuong. 2010. Paths to Development in Asia South Korea, Vietnam, China, and Indonesia. New York, NY: Cambridge Univer- sity Press.

Wade, Robert H. 1990. Governing the market: Economic theory and the role of government in East Asian industrialization. Second. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

Weinstein, David E. 1995. “Evaluating administrative guidance and cartels in Japan (1957-1988).” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 9: 200–223.

Werlin, Herbert. 1991. “Ghana and South Korea: Lessons from World Bank case studies.” Public Administration and Develop- ment 11 (3): 245–55.

Westphal, Larry E. 1990. “Industrial Policy in an Export Propelled Economy: Lessons from South Korea’s Experience.” Jour- nal of Economic Perspectives 4 (3): 41–59.

Westphal, Larry E, and Kwang Suk Kim. 1982. “Fostering Technological Mastery by Means of Selective Infant Industry Protection.” In Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies, edited by Bela Balassa, 212–79. Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Woo, Jung-en. 1991. Race to the Swift: State and Finance in Korean Industrialization. New York, New York: Columbia University Press.

Woo-Cumings, Meredith Jung-En. 1998. “14 National security and the rise of the developmental state in South Korea and Taiwan.” Behind East Asian Growth: The Political and Social Foundations of Prosperity, 319.

World Bank. 1987. “Korea - Managing the industrial transition : The conduct of industrial policy.” Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

Yang, Ya-Hwei. 1993. “Government policy and strategic industries: the case of Taiwan.” In Trade and Protectionism, Nber-Ease Volume 2, 387–411. University of Chicago Press.

Yoo, Jung-ho. 1990. “The Industrial Policy of the 1970s and the Evolution of the Manufacturing Sector in Korea.” 9017. Seoul, Korea: Korea Development Institute; Korea Development Institute.

———. 1993. “The Political Economy of Protection Structure in Korea.” In Trade and Protectionism, Nber-Ease Volume 2, edited by Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, 361–85. Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press.

42 Table 1: Estimates for Average Impact (ATT) of HCI on Development Outcomes, Before and After 1973

Semiparametric DID Estimates Linear DID Estimates

No Controls With Controls No Controls With Controls

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A) 5-Digit Panel 1970-1986 Val. Ship 1.0238*** 0.9475*** 0.9625*** 0.8302*** [0.3254] [0.2214] (0.3047) (0.1701) Employment 0.6091** 0.5378*** 0.5861** 0.4538*** [0.2577] [0.1822] (0.2394) (0.134) Prices -0.1575*** -0.1311*** -0.1974*** -0.1708*** [0.0339] [0.0268] (0.0344) (0.0279) Labor Prod. 0.4829* 0.5118*** 0.3637 0.335*** [0.2578] [0.1888] (0.2285) (0.1263) Output Share 0.1124*** 0.1398*** 0.1225*** 0.1375*** [0.0291] [0.0389] (0.0309) (0.0336) Panel B) 4-Digit Panel 1967-1986 Val. Ship 0.8391** 0.9412** 0.8824*** 0.8174*** [0.3346] [0.4604] (0.3136) (0.305) Employment 0.3369 0.5079 0.322 0.3331 [0.2853] [0.3225] (0.2552) (0.2552) Prices -0.1681*** -0.14*** -0.2456*** -0.2132*** [0.0623] [0.0528] (0.0719) (0.0579) Labor Prod. 0.5203** 0.6298** 0.486** 0.4989** [0.2385] [0.2742] (0.1968) (0.1896) Output Share 0.2157*** 0.2383** 0.2544*** 0.2073*** [0.0796] [0.1181] (0.088) (0.0734) Export 1.4136*** 1.3513*** 1.4713*** 1.2817*** [0.3042] [0.3709] (0.3541) (0.3446) Export Share 0.3333*** 0.3282*** 0.4501*** 0.4359*** [0.0926] [0.0879] (0.1174) (0.1146) Note: Table reports many estimates of the average treatment effect on the treated (ATT). Each cell is a single DID estimate, from semiparametric DID (left column) estima- tor or analogous linear two-way fixed effect estimator (right column). Targeted is industry-level dummy variable (0 or 1 for HCI sectors). Panel A shows estimates using shorter, detailed 5-digit level industrial data (1970-1986). Panel B shows es- timates using longer, aggregate 4-digit level industrial data (1967-1986). Val. Ship is the real value of output shipped. Employment is the total number of indus- try employment. Prices output price indices. Labor Prod. is real value added per worker. Output Share is the real manufacturing share of industry output. Export is the real (won) value of exports and Export Share is the manufacturing share of industry exports. Specifications without additional controls use industry and year effects. Specifications with controls include pre-1973 averages for avg. real plant wage, total cost, labor productivity, and output prices. Bootstrapped stan- dard errors are in square brackets (10,000 iterations) and are adjusted to allow for within-industry correlation. Cluster robust standard errors (industry-level) are reported in brackets. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level.

43 Table 2: Estimates for Average Impact (ATT) of HCI on Export Development, Before and After 1973

Semiparametric DID Estimates Linear DID Estimates

No Controls With Controls No Controls With Controls

(1) (2) (3) (4)

4-Digit SITC Data 1965-1986 1.0697** 1.3187* 1.2963** 1.6365**Rca [0.4798] [0.7145] (0.5357) (0.7504) 0.2325*** 0.2558*** 0.2761*** 0.2975***Rca(IHS) [0.0675] [0.0688] (0.0728) (0.0738) 0.6719*** 0.7248*** 1.2562*** 1.3062***Rca(Ln) [0.2217] [0.2273] (0.2207) (0.2216) 0.1224*** 0.1296*** 0.1424*** 0.1463***I[Rca>1] [0.0393] [0.0398] (0.037) (0.0365) Note: Table reports many estimates of the average treatment effect on the treated (ATT). Each cell is a single DID estimate, from semiparametric DID (left col- umn) estimator or analogous linear two-way fixed effect estimator (right col- umn). Targeted is industry-level dummy variable (0 or 1 for HCI sectors). Panel is SITC Rev. 1 goods data over the period 1965-1986. RCA is revealed comparative advantage index. RCA also normalized ihs and natural ln for completenes. Indicator I[RCA>1] is dummy equal to 1 when RCA>1, 0 oth- erwise Specifications without additional controls use industry and year ef- fects. Specifications with controls include pre-1973 averages for avg. real plant wage, total cost, labor productivity, and output prices. Bootstrapped standard errors are in square brackets (10,000 iterations) and are adjusted to allow for within-industry correlation. Cluster robust standard errors (industry-level) are reported in brackets. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level.

44 Table 3: Estimates for Average Impact (ATT) of HCI on Export Development, Before and After 1973

Semiparametric DID Estimates Linear DID Estimates

No Controls With Controls No Controls With Controls

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A) 5-Digit Panel 1970-1986 Material Cost 0.9701*** 0.8092*** 0.8724*** 0.6585*** [0.3274] [0.2283] (0.3029) (0.171) Invest. Total 0.7699*** 0.6694*** 0.778*** 0.6538*** [0.2708] [0.2322] (0.2399) (0.2036) Panel B) 4-Digit Panel 1967-1986 Material Cost 0.7215** 0.8331* 0.5926* 0.5556* [0.3661] [0.4574] (0.2994) (0.3046) Invest. Total 0.1419 0.2256 0.308 0.3142 [0.2937] [0.2221] (0.2561) (0.213) Note: Table reports many estimates of the average treatment effect on the treated (ATT). Each cell is a single DID estimate, from semiparametric DID (left column) estima- tor or analogous linear two-way fixed effect estimator (right column). Targeted is industry-level dummy variable (0 or 1 for HCI sectors). Panel A shows estimates using shorter, detailed 5-digit level industrial data (1970-1986). Panel B shows es- timates using longer, aggregate 4-digit level industrial data (1967-1986). Material Cost is real input material costs. Invest. Total is real total gross capital formation. Specifications without additional controls use industry and year effects. Speci- fications with controls include pre-1973 averages for avg. real plant wage, total cost, labor productivity, and output prices. Bootstrapped standard errors are in square brackets (10,000 iterations) and are adjusted to allow for within-industry correlation. Cluster robust standard errors (industry-level) are reported in brack- ets. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level.

45 Table 4: Differences in Industry-Level Trade Performance, HCI vs. Non-HCI Industry

Outcomes - Trade flows (ihs)

Mfg. Share of Exports Value of Exports Mfg. Share of Imports Value of Imports

1 2 3 4

Targeted X 1967 -0.132 -0.007 0.020 0.252 (0.100) (0.309) (0.118) (0.259) Targeted X 1968 -0.179 0.030 -0.022 0.176 (0.098) (0.279) (0.095) (0.223) Targeted X 1969 -0.085 0.143 -0.072 -0.022 (0.078) (0.264) (0.073) (0.186) Targeted X 1970 -0.096 -0.010 -0.056 -0.064 (0.060) (0.177) (0.054) (0.132) Targeted X 1971 -0.121** -0.072 -0.005 -0.040 (0.043) (0.159) (0.032) (0.074) Targeted X 1972 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (.) (.) (.) (.) Targeted X 1973 -0.036 0.206 -0.178** -0.162 (0.041) (0.195) (0.058) (0.142) Targeted X 1974 0.066 0.627* -0.080 0.018 (0.066) (0.281) (0.067) (0.155) Targeted X 1975 0.003 0.465 -0.052 0.079 (0.071) (0.356) (0.078) (0.167) Targeted X 1976 0.082 0.845** -0.130 -0.048 (0.077) (0.305) (0.076) (0.174) Targeted X 1977 0.233* 1.125** -0.073 0.031 (0.100) (0.334) (0.082) (0.183) Targeted X 1978 0.269** 1.202*** 0.006 0.051 (0.095) (0.343) (0.082) (0.194) Targeted X 1979 0.348*** 1.315*** -0.011 0.091 (0.090) (0.340) (0.089) (0.208) Targeted X 1980 0.435*** 1.509*** -0.072 0.071 (0.098) (0.349) (0.095) (0.214) Targeted X 1981 0.437*** 1.457*** -0.094 0.113 (0.115) (0.345) (0.107) (0.219) Targeted X 1982 0.515*** 1.683*** -0.082 0.102 (0.128) (0.346) (0.110) (0.234) Targeted X 1983 0.560*** 1.766*** -0.071 0.066 (0.143) (0.354) (0.113) (0.240) Targeted X 1984 0.584*** 1.923*** -0.033 0.107 (0.144) (0.367) (0.111) (0.238) Targeted X 1985 0.606*** 1.996*** -0.055 0.008 (0.151) (0.384) (0.114) (0.241) Targeted X 1986 0.573*** 2.022*** -0.009 -0.004 (0.132) (0.362) (0.100) (0.235) Industry Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Baseline Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes R-Squared 0.869 0.871 0.895 0.925 Observations 1720 1720 1720 1720 Clusters 86 86 86 86 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 3.043 0.399 0.914 0.700 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.014 0.848 0.476 0.625

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between Heavy Chemical and Industry Drive (HCI) tar- geting and industrial trade performance. Mfg. Share of Exports is an industry’s manufacturing share of exports. Value of Exports is the real value of exports. Export Share is the industy share of manufacturing imports for each industry. Trade values are real won (2010 base).. Interactions correspond to interactions between Targeted dummy variable (0 or 1 for HCI sectors) and year effects (Tar- geted x Year). Estimates are relative to the baseline year, 1972, the year before HCI. Table shows estimates from linear two-way fixed effect estimates and include industry level and year effects. All specifications controls for pre-1973 averages for wages, firm size, total costs, and labor productivity (interacted with time effects). Panel is 4-digit industrial data (1967-1986).Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986, and UN-COMTRADE.

46 Table 5: Differences in Trade Policy, HCI vs. Non-HCI Industry, 1968-1982

Outcomes: Levels Outcomes: Differences

Tariff Rate QRs Coverage Tariffs Rate QR Coverage

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Panel A - Outcomes: Output Protection Targeted -0.511*** -0.272* -0.505*** -0.254 -0.269*** -0.182* -0.249** -0.173* 0.038 0.044 0.019 0.068 (0.114) (0.137) (0.113) (0.142) (0.078) (0.071) (0.080) (0.074) (0.028) (0.038) (0.018) (0.044) Year Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Controls X X X X X X X X X X X X Sample Full Full Post-1973 Post-1973 Full Full Post-1973 Post-1973 Full Full Full Full Weighted None Weighted None Weighted None Weighted None Weighted None Weighted None Weighted R-Squared 0.418 0.560 0.419 0.565 0.206 0.293 0.210 0.294 0.202 0.275 0.312 0.581 Observations 516 516 430 430 430 430 344 344 258 258 430 430 Clusters 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 Panel B - Outcomes: Exposure to Input Protection 47 Targeted -0.302* -0.359* -0.343** -0.390* -0.088** -0.096** -0.095*** -0.100** -0.051*** -0.060*** -0.020 -0.015 (0.116) (0.149) (0.120) (0.154) (0.028) (0.033) (0.027) (0.032) (0.014) (0.018) (0.010) (0.012) Year Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Controls X X X X X X X X X X X X Sample Full Full Post-1973 Post-1973 Full Full Post-1973 Post-1973 Full Full Full Full Weighted None Weighted None Weighted None Weighted None Weighted None Weighted None Weighted R-Squared 0.163 0.226 0.145 0.207 0.224 0.320 0.248 0.331 0.261 0.360 0.262 0.251 Observations 516 516 430 430 430 430 344 344 430 430 258 258 Clusters 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86

Note: This table shows the relationship between trade policy and HCI (Targeted industries), using nominal trade policy data for the years 1968-1982. All regressions are at the 4-digit industry level. The first set of columns report results for regressions in levels. The second set of columns reports differences outcomes. Columns (1-4) report estimates for tariffs. Columns 5-8 reports estimates for quantitative restriction coverage (QR). Columns (9-10) shows estimates for changes in tariff rates. Columns (11-12) shows estimates for changes in tariff rates QRs. Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. a Panel A groups estimates for tariff and QR outcomes related to industry-level output market protection–the average level (or change) in tariff or QR coverage of a given output mar- ket. Panel B examines the industry-level exposure to tariffs vis-a-vis their input bundle. Input exposure is calculated using the weighted sum of QRs or tariffs for industry’s input basket, with weights are taken from the 1970 input-output accounts. Sample refers to whether all five periods are used, or whether only post-HCI (1973) observations are used. * Source - Tariffs rates and QR coverages, Luedde-Neurath (1986). Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986. Table 6: Differences in Investment Responses to HCI, Across Asset and Inventory Class

Capital investment by asset class (ihs) Inventory investment (ihs), type

Machinery Transp.Equip. Structures Invent./Ship. Out.Invent. Input Invent.

1 2 3 4 5 6

Targeted X 1970 -0.240 -0.340 -0.404 -0.001 0.107 -0.542 (0.296) (0.257) (0.290) (0.011) (0.309) (0.283) Targeted X 1971 0.039 -0.066 -0.269 -0.019 -0.132 -0.118 (0.275) (0.227) (0.320) (0.012) (0.298) (0.298) Targeted X 1972 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) Targeted X 1973 0.277 0.346 -0.046 0.006 1.231* 1.210* (0.252) (0.234) (0.295) (0.016) (0.475) (0.468) Targeted X 1974 0.423 0.284 -0.014 -0.004 0.686* 0.364 (0.252) (0.261) (0.267) (0.011) (0.280) (0.270) Targeted X 1975 0.185 0.144 0.049 -0.003 0.358 -0.167 (0.272) (0.252) (0.275) (0.010) (0.306) (0.308) Targeted X 1976 0.015 0.185 0.108 -0.002 0.434 0.022 (0.307) (0.286) (0.307) (0.010) (0.326) (0.320) Targeted X 1977 0.582* 0.409 0.390 0.005 0.820** 0.252 (0.275) (0.266) (0.295) (0.011) (0.312) (0.296) Targeted X 1978 0.863** 0.413 0.508 0.010 1.164* 0.336 (0.308) (0.273) (0.296) (0.014) (0.494) (0.633) Targeted X 1979 0.776* 0.548* 0.537 0.001 1.515** 0.226 (0.314) (0.278) (0.348) (0.012) (0.475) (0.663) Targeted X 1980 0.828** 0.304 0.605 0.005 -0.485 1.134 (0.288) (0.281) (0.317) (0.013) (0.796) (0.715) Targeted X 1981 0.398 0.280 0.374 -0.002 1.031 0.979 (0.293) (0.269) (0.322) (0.012) (0.762) (0.792) Targeted X 1982 0.601 0.269 0.294 0.008 1.924 -2.069* (0.324) (0.290) (0.349) (0.011) (0.987) (0.994) Year Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Industry Effect X X X X X X Controls X X X X X X R-Squared 0.766 0.767 0.730 0.191 0.400 0.385 Observations 3094 3094 3094 3040 3107 3107 Clusters 238 238 238 239 239 239 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 0.502 1.044 0.991 2.091 0.262 1.886 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.606 0.354 0.373 0.126 0.770 0.154

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between Heavy Chemical and Industry Drive (HCI) targeting and across investment asset class and type of inventory investment. Machinery Equip. is value (real gross) investment in equipment and machin- ery. Transportation Equip. is value (real gross) investment in vehicle and transportation equipment. Structures are value (real gross) investment in building and structures. Invent./Ship. are changes in the real value of product inventories divided by value of shipments. Output Inventory is the change in real value of product inventories. Input Inventory is the change in real value of intermediate inventories.. Interactions corre- spond to interactions between Targeted dummy variable (0 or 1 for HCI sectors) and year effects (Targeted x Year). Estimates are relative to the baseline year, 1972, the year before HCI. Table shows estimates from linear two-way fixed effect estimates and include industry level and year effects. All specifications controls for pre-1973 averages for wages, firm size, total costs, and labor productivity (interacted with time effects). Panel is 4-digit industrial data (1967-1986).Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986.

48 Table 7: Average Impact of Linkages on Output, Before and After 1973

Outcome - Real value added (ihs)

Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Full Sample Non-HCI Sample Full Sample Non-HCI Sample

1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4

Post X Forward Link 0.0216** 0.0235** 0.0214* 0.0229* 0.0134 0.0166* 0.0114 0.0134 (0.00699) (0.00759) (0.00975) (0.0103) (0.00698) (0.00642) (0.0100) (0.00918) Post X Backward Link -0.0169* -0.0163* -0.0204* -0.0192* -0.0115 -0.0117 -0.0249*** -0.0251*** (0.00695) (0.00697) (0.00885) (0.00879) (0.00718) (0.00758) (0.00716) (0.00696) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Network Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.765 0.766 0.766 0.769 0.827 0.831 0.809 0.815 Observations 4726 4726 3111 3111 1760 1760 1180 1180 Clusters 278 278 183 183 88 88 59 59

Note: Average differences-in-differences estimates, before and after 1973. Regressions interact linkage measure with Post 1973 indicator. For these estimates, both linkage interactions are shown (forward and backward); whereas, dynamic estimates presented only linkages for the interaction of interest (forward or backward). Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986.

Table 8: Average Impact of Linkages on Output Prices, Before and After 1973

Outcome - Output prices (ihs)

Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Full Sample Non-HCI Sample Full Sample Non-HCI Sample

1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4

Post X Forward Link -0.00264** -0.00339*** -0.00252* -0.00334*** -0.00331* -0.00429** -0.00242 -0.00324* (0.00100) (0.000983) (0.00104) (0.000994) (0.00144) (0.00145) (0.00145) (0.00140) Post X Backward Link 0.00353*** 0.00333*** 0.00370*** 0.00353*** 0.00591** 0.00561** 0.00878** 0.00854** (0.000529) (0.000519) (0.000476) (0.000463) (0.00210) (0.00204) (0.00288) (0.00268) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Network Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.951 0.953 0.941 0.943 0.955 0.956 0.948 0.951 Observations 4722 4722 3107 3107 1751 1751 1177 1177 Clusters 278 278 183 183 88 88 59 59

Note: Average differences-in-differences estimates, before and after 1973. Regressions interact linkage measure with Post 1973 indicator. For these estimates, both linkage interactions are shown (forward and backward); whereas, dynamic estimates presented only linkages for the interaction of interest (forward or back- ward). Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. All specifications are unweighted. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986.

49 Table 9: Impact of Direct Forward Linkages on Downstream Industrial Development Outcomes

A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Employment Avg. Wage. Num. Plants Labor Prod. Employment Avg. Wage. Num. Plants Labor Prod.

Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI

1234567812345678

1967 X Forward Link 0.00215 -0.000481 0.00273 0.0113 0.00371 0.00172 0.00504 0.0108 (0.00526) (0.00772) (0.00726) (0.00981) (0.00411) (0.00481) (0.00567) (0.00798) 1968 X Forward Link 0.00536 0.00389 0.00452 0.0146 0.00560 0.00395 0.00803 0.0157* (0.00494) (0.00765) (0.00672) (0.00887) (0.00370) (0.00461) (0.00519) (0.00755) 1969 X Forward Link 0.00611 0.00564 0.00204 0.0141 0.00389 0.000784 0.00851 0.0188 (0.00471) (0.00756) (0.00649) (0.00839) (0.00438) (0.00577) (0.00715) (0.0109) 1970 X Forward Link -0.00244 0.000379 0.00378 0.00383 -0.00234 -0.00211 -0.00246 -0.00880 -0.00488 -0.00465 0.00135 0.00152 -0.00240 -0.00394* 0.00499 0.00501 (0.00380) (0.00419) (0.00345) (0.00414) (0.00157) (0.00183) (0.00664) (0.00923) (0.00370) (0.00293) (0.00156) (0.00200) (0.00195) (0.00168) (0.00283) (0.00407) 1971 X Forward Link -0.00540 -0.00383 -0.00269 -0.00312 -0.00349* -0.00330 -0.00371 -0.00358 -0.00124 -0.00236 0.00117 0.00260 -0.00213 -0.00271 0.00224 0.00346 (0.00370) (0.00492) (0.00418) (0.00596) (0.00152) (0.00199) (0.00483) (0.00718) (0.00304) (0.00332) (0.00338) (0.00576) (0.00154) (0.00167) (0.00241) (0.00326) 1972 X Forward Link 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) 1973 X Forward Link -0.00167 -0.000518 -0.000170 -0.00106 -0.000140 0.000724 -0.00214 -0.00450 -0.000286 -0.00202 0.00254 0.00283 0.00141 0.00143 -0.00230 -0.00343 (0.00330) (0.00385) (0.00279) (0.00292) (0.00115) (0.00153) (0.00414) (0.00497) (0.00181) (0.00216) (0.00159) (0.00214) (0.00116) (0.00156) (0.00250) (0.00378) 1974 X Forward Link -0.000306 0.00330 0.00265 0.00287 0.00202 0.00348 0.00261 0.00277 0.00244 0.00172 0.00556 0.00788 0.00267 0.00251 0.00538 0.00658 (0.00320) (0.00363) (0.00343) (0.00433) (0.00156) (0.00217) (0.00417) (0.00515) (0.00203) (0.00320) (0.00408) (0.00706) (0.00158) (0.00228) (0.00361) (0.00597) 1975 X Forward Link 0.0122* 0.0131 0.0106 0.00397 0.00940** 0.0118** 0.0114 0.00315 0.0127* 0.0180* 0.00653 0.00737 0.0118*** 0.0156*** 0.00164 0.000451 (0.00566) (0.00789) (0.00660) (0.00655) (0.00311) (0.00437) (0.00778) (0.00790) (0.00495) (0.00736) (0.00561) (0.00939) (0.00317) (0.00439) (0.00521) (0.00856) 1976 X Forward Link 0.0214** 0.0262** 0.0178* 0.0146 0.0130*** 0.0182*** 0.0200* 0.0168 0.0168* 0.0204 0.00934 0.00937 0.0174*** 0.0235*** 0.00438 0.00306 (0.00659) (0.00913) (0.00760) (0.00885) (0.00331) (0.00438) (0.00891) (0.0106) (0.00694) (0.0103) (0.00641) (0.00942) (0.00461) (0.00600) (0.00609) (0.00885) 50 1977 X Forward Link 0.0257*** 0.0309** 0.0214** 0.0192* 0.0139*** 0.0187*** 0.0255** 0.0226* 0.0209** 0.0264* 0.0148 0.0179 0.0191*** 0.0260*** 0.0102 0.0119 (0.00695) (0.0100) (0.00793) (0.00946) (0.00345) (0.00459) (0.00934) (0.0113) (0.00768) (0.0120) (0.00851) (0.0139) (0.00487) (0.00653) (0.00772) (0.0125) 1978 X Forward Link 0.0176** 0.0192* 0.0151* 0.00894 0.0124*** 0.0162*** 0.0176* 0.0103 0.0197* 0.0250* 0.0177* 0.0205 0.0197*** 0.0272*** 0.0118 0.0135 (0.00626) (0.00871) (0.00734) (0.00794) (0.00359) (0.00472) (0.00865) (0.00952) (0.00771) (0.0116) (0.00872) (0.0142) (0.00501) (0.00684) (0.00785) (0.0127) 1979 X Forward Link 0.0208** 0.0204* 0.0191* 0.0120 0.0139*** 0.0163*** 0.0215* 0.0147 0.0202** 0.0243* 0.0184* 0.0207 0.0201*** 0.0274*** 0.0146 0.0171 (0.00672) (0.00865) (0.00802) (0.00876) (0.00352) (0.00460) (0.00923) (0.0102) (0.00724) (0.0109) (0.00890) (0.0145) (0.00487) (0.00644) (0.00804) (0.0132) 1980 X Forward Link 0.0223** 0.0247* 0.0187* 0.0117 0.0147*** 0.0186*** 0.0209* 0.0146 0.0203* 0.0274* 0.0188* 0.0207 0.0204*** 0.0282*** 0.0129 0.0152 (0.00702) (0.00993) (0.00798) (0.00924) (0.00365) (0.00471) (0.00930) (0.0111) (0.00805) (0.0125) (0.00910) (0.0146) (0.00509) (0.00654) (0.00820) (0.0135) 1981 X Forward Link 0.0209** 0.0210* 0.0188* 0.0121 0.0157*** 0.0177*** 0.0204* 0.0129 0.0190* 0.0246* 0.0197* 0.0225 0.0199*** 0.0267*** 0.0131 0.0157 (0.00657) (0.00917) (0.00803) (0.00950) (0.00382) (0.00499) (0.00942) (0.0114) (0.00757) (0.0110) (0.00942) (0.0149) (0.00516) (0.00657) (0.00843) (0.0138) 1982 X Forward Link 0.0242*** 0.0281** 0.0234** 0.0198 0.0170*** 0.0208*** 0.0258** 0.0222 0.0219* 0.0287* 0.0213* 0.0245 0.0222*** 0.0296*** 0.0143 0.0174 (0.00703) (0.0102) (0.00820) (0.0102) (0.00390) (0.00505) (0.00963) (0.0123) (0.00838) (0.0126) (0.00947) (0.0152) (0.00536) (0.00703) (0.00897) (0.0148) 1983 X Forward Link 0.00754 0.0128 0.00240 0.000508 0.0117** 0.0167** 0.00214 -0.000575 0.0125* 0.0101 0.0110* 0.00746 0.0188*** 0.0217*** 0.00346 -0.000187 (0.00716) (0.00903) (0.00623) (0.00821) (0.00440) (0.00542) (0.00735) (0.00981) (0.00522) (0.00727) (0.00465) (0.00550) (0.00451) (0.00513) (0.00343) (0.00434) 1984 X Forward Link 0.0103 0.0153 0.00517 0.000447 0.0126** 0.0178** 0.00420 -0.00119 0.0137** 0.0110 0.0109* 0.00807 0.0194*** 0.0228*** 0.00332 -0.000349 (0.00801) (0.00978) (0.00616) (0.00811) (0.00470) (0.00585) (0.00730) (0.00977) (0.00510) (0.00700) (0.00473) (0.00548) (0.00481) (0.00534) (0.00354) (0.00435) 1985 X Forward Link 0.00633 0.0128 0.00128 -0.00169 0.0119* 0.0178** 0.000500 -0.00298 0.0138* 0.0125 0.0119* 0.0104 0.0204*** 0.0239*** 0.00480 0.00319 (0.00827) (0.00994) (0.00641) (0.00823) (0.00489) (0.00596) (0.00758) (0.0101) (0.00538) (0.00696) (0.00560) (0.00740) (0.00494) (0.00553) (0.00418) (0.00599) 1986 X Forward Link 0.0124 0.0201 0.00590 0.00222 0.0139** 0.0197** 0.00554 0.00242 0.0152** 0.0145* 0.0120* 0.0111 0.0210*** 0.0239*** 0.00495 0.00335 (0.00848) (0.0106) (0.00650) (0.00873) (0.00505) (0.00605) (0.00764) (0.0106) (0.00574) (0.00722) (0.00549) (0.00724) (0.00519) (0.00577) (0.00415) (0.00586) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No R-Squared 0.788 0.808 0.640 0.625 0.857 0.870 0.635 0.621 0.848 0.854 0.732 0.675 0.888 0.898 0.753 0.710 Observations 4726 3111 4726 3111 4726 3111 4726 3111 1760 1180 1760 1180 1760 1180 1760 1180 Clusters 278 183 278 183 278 183 278 183 88 59 88 59 88 59 88 59 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 1.496 1.254 1.892 1.252 2.608 4.180 0.403 0.876 2.169 3.734 1.633 5.968 1.370 5.109 1.581 1.983 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.204 0.290 0.112 0.291 0.036 0.003 0.807 0.479 0.027 0.001 0.110 0.000 0.208 0.000 0.126 0.052

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between forward direct linkage exposure to HCI and industrial development outcomes. (Real) Shipments are an altenative, gross measure of output. Num. Plants are the number of plants op- erating in an an industry. Value Exports are real (Won) value of exports. Labor Productivity is value added per worker. Estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. 1979 corresponds to collapse of Park regime. Panel A reports estimates from detailed 5-digit in- dustrial data (1970-1986). Panel B reports estimates from longer 4-digit level industrial data (1967-1986). Specificiations are two-way fixed effect OLS estimates, and include year and industry effects. All regressions include controls for backward direct interacted with time. Network controls are 1970 eigenvalue centrality and total network degrees (1970) interacted with time. Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986. Appendix

51 Table A1: Pre-HCI Drive Statistics Across Manufacturing Industry - By Panel and Treatment

A) 4-Digit Panel 1967-1972 B) 5-Digit Panel 1970-1972 HCI Variable Mean Stdev. Obs. Mean Stdev. Obs. i. Industrial Statistics Non-HCI Average Size 2.81 3.73 1180 2.81 2.86 3111 HCI Average Size 2.34 2.00 580 2.46 2.27 1615 Non-HCI Costs 486380.67 782366.73 1180 139507.36 313009.85 3111 HCI Costs 1006636.14 2092000.36 580 267638.53 766298.73 1615 Non-HCI Establishments 442.92 635.98 1180 126.74 261.93 3111 HCI Establishments 284.28 371.22 580 92.83 137.15 1615 Non-HCI Gross Output 696712.59 1072556.26 1180 256926.77 579862.85 3111 HCI Gross Output 1144931.83 2761979.92 580 400072.62 1260235.61 1615 Non-HCI Investment 18283.96 32977.69 1180 9262.60 23177.12 3111 HCI Investment 43713.76 113854.10 580 19606.86 58862.08 1615 Non-HCI Labor Productivity 1735.10 3177.95 1180 1538.47 2368.45 3111 HCI Labor Productivity 2412.79 5364.54 580 1982.37 3150.12 1615 Non-HCI Prices 28.03 23.63 1180 32.56 26.15 3111 HCI Prices 46.70 49.91 580 48.04 48.68 1615 Non-HCI Shipments 687847.08 1059938.88 1180 253653.63 572877.84 3111 HCI Shipments 1128595.62 2746062.60 580 394791.54 1255021.14 1615 Non-HCI Value Added 291781.53 477598.90 1180 106916.59 270509.06 3111 HCI Value Added 346778.71 769766.77 580 126333.87 322466.70 1615 Non-HCI Workers 21003.36 33129.56 1180 6882.79 15659.36 3111 HCI Workers 18681.43 29562.49 580 6755.78 15743.39 1615 ii. Direct Linkage Measures Non-HCI Backward, Upstream From Targeted 8.35 15.04 1180 12.47 24.11 3111 HCI Backward, Upstream From Targeted 15.20 20.87 580 17.51 20.04 1615 Non-HCI Forward, Downstream From Targeted 20.81 17.43 1180 19.70 15.95 3111 HCI Forward, Downstream From Targeted 46.85 19.48 580 51.24 18.28 1615 iii. Trade Statistics Non-HCI Trade Value Imports (Log) 3.21 2.68 1180 HCI Trade Value Imports (Log) 5.39 2.22 580 Non-HCI Trade Value Exports (Log) 2.79 3.76 1180 HCI Trade Value Exports (Log) 3.85 2.94 580 Non-HCI Tariff 50.90 28.19 1180 HCI Tariff 31.04 13.59 580 Non-HCI Quantitative Restrictions 0.94 0.61 1180 HCI Quantitative Restrictions 0.59 0.41 580 Note: Table reports pre-1973 statistics for a selection of core industrial variables. Panel A shows statistics for aggregated (’long’) 4-digit industrial panel, 1967 to 1972. Panel B shows statistics for disaggregated (’short’) 5-digit industrial panel, 1970 to 1972. Raw (non-normalized) values are shown. Part i) of table reports Mining and Manufacturing Sur- vey/Census outcomes. With the exception of prices, which come from the Bank of Korea publications. Part ii) shows data from the 1970 input-output tables published by the Bank of Korea (1970), harmonized and matched to industry- level data. Part iii) shows trade (UN-COMTRADE) variables, harmonized and matched to 4-digit industry-level data. Trade policy variables are also shown: tariffs and quantitative restrictions (QRs). Tariffs are reported as ad velorum rates. QRs, are coverage scores of industry restrictions: lowest (0) to highest (3) (Luedde-Neurath 1986). All values, including trade values, have been converted to real Won (base year = 2010).

52 Table A2: Normalized Names for Treated Industries - Harmonized 5-Digit Level Industries

Chemical fibres Metal working machinery Hydrochloric acid Petroleum synthetic resins Food products machinery Other sodium products Polyvinyl chlorides Mining and construction machinery Soda ash Thermosetting resins Other special industry machinery Sulfuric acid Paints and allied products Textile machinery Anhydrous ammonia

Pigments Office and service industry machines Other industrial compressed gases Soap and surface active agents Household electric appliances Other inorganic chemicals Miscellaneous chemical products Refrigerators and other household appliances Miscellaneous organic chemicals Processed edible oil products and fats Generators and motors Processed oils and fats products Briquettes Other electric transmission and distribution equipmnet Nitrogenous fertilizers Dry distillated coal products Other electrical industrial apparatus Phosphatic fertilizers Other petroleum products Transformers Calcium cyanamide Ferroalloys Communications equipment Other chemical fertilizers Pig iron Electronic components Soap and active agents Raw steel Radio and television sets Adhesives Copper Electric lamps Explosives and products Gold and silver ingots Insulated wire and cable Matches Other non-ferrous metal ingots Other electrical equipment and supplies Photochemical and sensitized materials Household metal products Storage and primary batteries Miscellaneous metal products Tools Railroad transportation equipment General industrial machinery

Metal furniture Automobile repair General machinery parts Structural metal products Motor vehicle parts Sewing machines Wire products Motor vehicles Steel ships Boilers Measuring and scientific instruments Ships, NEC Prime movers Medical, surgical and dental instruments Cosmetics and tooth paste and powder

Farm machinery Calcium carbide Synthetic dyestuffs Machine tools for working metals Caustic soda

Source notes: Sample list of Korean industry names under HCI. Industry names are based on the 1970 Bank of Korea industry labels, as they are most consistent through time. Names are not exact, due to harmonization of codes through times, and represent best representative strings from crosswalked industrial codes. Heuristically, the term ’Heavy and Chemical Industry’ (as well as HCI) is also used to define a specific set of sectors in Korea statistical publications. This more general nomeclature, however, does not encompass the electronics industry. Hence, there is a distinction between the term ’heavy industry’ as it is used in statistical publications and its specific use in HCI policy plans. As Suk- Chae Lee explains, the electronics industry ’was one of the core industries slated for promotion in Korea’s HCI Plan [May, 1973]; therefore any analysis of the HCI plan should include the electronics industry’ [Lee 1992; p.432].

53 Figure A1: Example of State Lending and Subsidies During HCI Period, by Industry Value of NIF Loans from Korean Development Bank Tax Rates on Marginal Returns to Capital, 1970−1983

50

90

60 54

Real Value (Bil. Won) Real Value 25 30 Effective Tax Rate (percentage) Effective Tax

0 10 1971 1972 1973 1977 1970 1972 1979 1982 Year Year

Industry Type Non−HCI Manufacturing HCI Manufacturing

Notes: Left − Plots the value of loans provided by the Korea Development Bank during the HCI period, the primary lender of NIF funds. Gray lines correspond to non−targeted sectors and red lines correspond to targeted sectors. NIF provided discounted financing for equipment investment and factory construction, and loans were provided through commercial banks. Right − Plots estimates of the average effective tax rate (percentage) on the returns of capital, accounting for changes in industry−specific subsidies. Average rates were calculated for aggregate 2−digit manufacturing industries (thin lines). Thick lines show the average rates by treated and non−treated industries. Table B1: Differences in Industrial Output Growth, HCI vs. Non-HCI, Relative to 1972

Outcomes: Measures of real output, gross and value added (ihs) Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986 Val. Ship Val. Ship Gross Out. Gross Out. Value Add. Value Add. Val. Ship Val. Ship Gross Out. Gross Out. Value Add. Value Add. 123456123456 Targeted X 1967 -0.141 -0.075 -0.157 -0.093 -0.184 -0.117 (0.301) (0.296) (0.301) (0.296) (0.296) (0.295) Targeted X 1968 -0.039 -0.001 -0.038 -0.002 -0.085 -0.027 (0.287) (0.280) (0.288) (0.281) (0.282) (0.278) Targeted X 1969 -0.025 -0.035 -0.015 -0.028 0.248 0.261 (0.279) (0.268) (0.279) (0.268) (0.376) (0.387) Targeted X 1970 0.091 0.137 0.238 0.264 0.206 0.239 -0.041 -0.055 0.163 0.112 0.221 0.189 (0.175) (0.198) (0.219) (0.252) (0.198) (0.228) (0.267) (0.244) (0.245) (0.243) (0.215) (0.217) Targeted X 1971 0.093 0.060 0.274 0.256 0.221 0.194 -0.014 -0.017 0.199 0.131 0.200 0.144 (0.184) (0.213) (0.193) (0.224) (0.169) (0.196) (0.238) (0.244) (0.245) (0.239) (0.208) (0.201) Targeted X 1972 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) Targeted X 1973 0.556** 0.614** 0.608** 0.673** 0.662*** 0.747*** 0.297 0.191 0.255 0.142 0.413* 0.283 (0.188) (0.213) (0.189) (0.215) (0.189) (0.205) (0.208) (0.193) (0.213) (0.199) (0.192) (0.175) Targeted X 1974 0.561** 0.673*** 0.510** 0.610** 0.468** 0.574** 0.195 0.095 0.272 0.167 0.136 0.054 (0.173) (0.197) (0.167) (0.188) (0.158) (0.178) (0.167) (0.145) (0.196) (0.180) (0.167) (0.149) Targeted X 1975 0.616 0.449 0.650 0.483 0.585 0.447 0.268 0.232 0.264 0.227 0.154 0.121

55 (0.362) (0.258) (0.366) (0.263) (0.333) (0.244) (0.269) (0.234) (0.269) (0.234) (0.254) (0.224) Targeted X 1976 0.751 0.504 0.754 0.502 0.720 0.505 0.708 0.609 0.709 0.609 0.619 0.538 (0.410) (0.294) (0.411) (0.294) (0.371) (0.268) (0.398) (0.423) (0.396) (0.422) (0.360) (0.380) Targeted X 1977 1.024* 0.810** 1.030* 0.817** 0.938* 0.751** 0.723 0.762 0.724 0.765 0.651 0.704* (0.414) (0.272) (0.414) (0.271) (0.376) (0.245) (0.391) (0.389) (0.390) (0.389) (0.356) (0.346) Targeted X 1978 1.097** 0.933*** 1.120** 0.951*** 1.007** 0.867*** 0.871* 0.893* 0.882* 0.905* 0.763* 0.795* (0.408) (0.272) (0.410) (0.272) (0.378) (0.253) (0.408) (0.408) (0.408) (0.408) (0.378) (0.371) Targeted X 1979 1.455*** 1.207*** 1.456*** 1.209*** 1.310** 1.121*** 0.980* 0.992* 0.982* 0.994* 0.856* 0.901* (0.434) (0.298) (0.435) (0.297) (0.400) (0.279) (0.410) (0.411) (0.411) (0.411) (0.381) (0.368) Targeted X 1980 0.974* 0.946*** 0.984* 0.970*** 0.919* 0.933*** 0.884* 0.887* 0.914* 0.931* 0.849* 0.903* (0.413) (0.255) (0.413) (0.255) (0.379) (0.237) (0.394) (0.390) (0.394) (0.388) (0.362) (0.345) Targeted X 1981 1.059* 1.040*** 1.060* 1.040*** 1.000** 1.016*** 0.989* 0.993* 0.989* 0.993* 0.900* 0.921* (0.412) (0.258) (0.412) (0.258) (0.376) (0.240) (0.423) (0.425) (0.424) (0.425) (0.394) (0.388) Targeted X 1982 0.924* 0.985*** 0.932* 0.998*** 0.841* 0.937*** 1.018* 1.075* 1.019* 1.077* 0.934* 1.033* (0.421) (0.277) (0.422) (0.280) (0.388) (0.259) (0.454) (0.436) (0.454) (0.436) (0.431) (0.400) Targeted X 1983 1.294** 1.049*** 1.294** 1.049*** 1.163** 0.983** 1.212** 1.032* 1.211** 1.030* 1.153** 1.022** (0.421) (0.309) (0.423) (0.310) (0.392) (0.296) (0.427) (0.398) (0.427) (0.398) (0.411) (0.373) Targeted X 1984 1.332** 1.006*** 1.335** 1.008*** 1.255** 0.969*** 1.300** 1.121** 1.310** 1.130** 1.264** 1.131** (0.421) (0.297) (0.422) (0.298) (0.394) (0.283) (0.438) (0.408) (0.438) (0.409) (0.419) (0.380) Targeted X 1985 1.361** 1.100** 1.355** 1.095** 1.262** 1.059** 1.142* 1.060* 1.133* 1.053* 1.060* 1.019* (0.454) (0.360) (0.455) (0.361) (0.425) (0.343) (0.439) (0.427) (0.439) (0.426) (0.422) (0.400) Targeted X 1986 1.330** 1.231*** 1.327** 1.223*** 1.267** 1.186*** 1.160* 1.076* 1.158* 1.076* 1.088* 1.038* (0.448) (0.335) (0.449) (0.335) (0.420) (0.320) (0.456) (0.439) (0.457) (0.440) (0.443) (0.416) Industry Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Baseline Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.763 0.745 0.761 0.740 0.762 0.745 0.830 0.806 0.831 0.806 0.825 0.803 Observations 4726 4063 4726 4063 4726 4063 1760 1720 1760 1720 1760 1720 Clusters 278 239 278 239 278 239 88 86 88 86 88 86 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 0.162 0.270 1.077 0.798 0.948 0.706 0.242 0.135 0.537 0.276 0.828 0.579 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.851 0.763 0.342 0.452 0.389 0.495 0.943 0.984 0.748 0.925 0.533 0.716

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive (HCI) industrial policy and industrial output–for gross and value added measures. Three different measures of output are reported: real value shipped, real gross output, and real value added, and are deflated using industrial price indices.. Targeted x Year correspond to the interaction between treat- ment indicator (0 or 1 for HCI industry) and year effects; coefficient estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. Estimates are from a linear two-way fixed effect regression, and with industry and year ef- fects. Specifications with controls include pre-1973 averages for wagebill, firm size, material costs, and labor productivity, interacted with time.Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986. Table B2: Differences in Industrial Development Outcomes

Outcomes: Measures of industrial development (ihs) Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986 Output Share Prices Labor Prod. Avg. Size Num. Plants Avg. Wages Employment Labor Share Output Share Prices Labor Prod. Num. Plants Avg. Size Avg. Wages Employment Labor Share 1234567812345678 Targeted X 1967 -0.028 0.076 -0.141 0.027 -0.004 -0.372 0.044 -0.031 (0.065) (0.044) (0.251) (0.156) (0.106) (0.360) (0.214) (0.064) Targeted X 1968 0.027 0.088* -0.093 0.027 -0.060 -0.339 0.085 -0.016 (0.052) (0.039) (0.237) (0.143) (0.107) (0.344) (0.201) (0.059) Targeted X 1969 0.027 0.073* 0.202 0.053 0.059 -0.351 -0.004 -0.024 (0.047) (0.033) (0.296) (0.138) (0.097) (0.335) (0.196) (0.048) Targeted X 1970 -0.012 0.087*** 0.257 0.167 0.103 0.050 0.087 0.011 -0.095 0.080*** 0.256 0.127 0.170 -0.062 0.116 0.018 (0.020) (0.012) (0.225) (0.091) (0.077) (0.158) (0.183) (0.023) (0.056) (0.021) (0.217) (0.106) (0.137) (0.153) (0.207) (0.049) Targeted X 1971 -0.012 0.037*** 0.166 0.054 0.030 -0.020 0.047 -0.008 -0.024 0.051* 0.119 0.041 0.021 -0.032 0.207 0.006 (0.016) (0.010) (0.189) (0.088) (0.068) (0.157) (0.177) (0.023) (0.033) (0.019) (0.175) (0.087) (0.084) (0.120) (0.223) (0.042) Targeted X 1972 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) Targeted X 1973 0.024 0.007 0.586** 0.062 0.087 0.301 0.394** 0.029 0.043 -0.022 0.299 0.063 0.108 0.122 0.166 0.047 (0.015) (0.011) (0.204) (0.090) (0.056) (0.158) (0.138) (0.015) (0.029) (0.018) (0.188) (0.079) (0.106) (0.153) (0.172) (0.026) Targeted X 1974 0.045* 0.003 0.286 0.032 0.245*** 0.195 0.403** 0.055** 0.091* -0.020 -0.034 0.083 -0.028 -0.115 0.004 0.068* (0.019) (0.020) (0.185) (0.083) (0.064) (0.152) (0.133) (0.018) (0.042) (0.028) (0.158) (0.056) (0.076) (0.186) (0.085) (0.033) Targeted X 1975 0.039 -0.007 0.213 0.087 0.263* 0.139 0.343 0.057 0.013 -0.011 0.134 0.241 0.191 0.075 0.169 0.036 (0.024) (0.022) (0.234) (0.096) (0.107) (0.195) (0.199) (0.031) (0.057) (0.034) (0.176) (0.167) (0.135) (0.167) (0.226) (0.049) Targeted X 1976 0.072* -0.034 0.226 0.007 0.198 0.101 0.292 0.075* 0.074 -0.045 0.501 0.255 0.179 0.421 0.326 0.070 (0.028) (0.025) (0.233) (0.089) (0.126) (0.188) (0.218) (0.033) (0.069) (0.037) (0.288) (0.203) (0.135) (0.264) (0.299) (0.059) Targeted X 1977 0.090** -0.090** 0.468* 0.068 0.245 0.338 0.470* 0.088** 0.110 -0.096* 0.565* 0.306 0.138 0.488 0.428 0.085 (0.032) (0.027) (0.225) (0.101) (0.125) (0.179) (0.202) (0.034) (0.074) (0.041) (0.258) (0.212) (0.138) (0.259) (0.288) (0.060)

56 Targeted X 1978 0.127*** -0.094** 0.519* 0.003 0.242 0.379* 0.502* 0.113** 0.163* -0.109* 0.612* 0.320 0.107 0.561* 0.471 0.138* (0.035) (0.028) (0.220) (0.088) (0.131) (0.171) (0.196) (0.037) (0.076) (0.048) (0.267) (0.226) (0.126) (0.273) (0.312) (0.069) Targeted X 1979 0.147*** -0.138*** 0.636** -0.028 0.349** 0.432* 0.680** 0.125** 0.200* -0.158** 0.677* 0.401 0.118 0.615* 0.513 0.156* (0.036) (0.031) (0.238) (0.093) (0.132) (0.195) (0.210) (0.038) (0.077) (0.055) (0.267) (0.223) (0.136) (0.278) (0.308) (0.074) Targeted X 1980 0.139*** -0.203*** 0.474* -0.003 0.363** 0.330 0.536** 0.120** 0.201* -0.216** 0.714** 0.385 0.148 0.695* 0.477 0.152* (0.036) (0.036) (0.205) (0.096) (0.137) (0.174) (0.206) (0.038) (0.078) (0.066) (0.245) (0.223) (0.139) (0.276) (0.294) (0.068) Targeted X 1981 0.165*** -0.227*** 0.542* -0.006 0.398** 0.375* 0.557** 0.121** 0.258** -0.238** 0.716* 0.406 0.131 0.756* 0.493 0.156* (0.040) (0.040) (0.209) (0.094) (0.139) (0.170) (0.204) (0.038) (0.091) (0.071) (0.281) (0.226) (0.124) (0.293) (0.308) (0.073) Targeted X 1982 0.171*** -0.194*** 0.485* 0.039 0.407** 0.326 0.541* 0.124** 0.275** -0.223** 0.787** 0.441 0.123 0.700* 0.535 0.160* (0.043) (0.037) (0.217) (0.092) (0.146) (0.175) (0.220) (0.039) (0.098) (0.069) (0.276) (0.242) (0.122) (0.290) (0.338) (0.077) Targeted X 1983 0.182*** -0.180*** 0.581* 0.089 0.443** 0.375* 0.510* 0.135*** 0.287** -0.221** 0.728** 0.393 0.036 0.590* 0.476 0.195* (0.046) (0.037) (0.236) (0.085) (0.166) (0.189) (0.250) (0.040) (0.099) (0.070) (0.226) (0.255) (0.100) (0.233) (0.350) (0.077) Targeted X 1984 0.193*** -0.203*** 0.486* 0.003 0.428* 0.298 0.500* 0.146*** 0.304** -0.245*** 0.764** 0.414 0.001 0.647** 0.550 0.221** (0.047) (0.038) (0.217) (0.083) (0.171) (0.181) (0.242) (0.042) (0.102) (0.070) (0.226) (0.267) (0.105) (0.237) (0.356) (0.080) Targeted X 1985 0.205*** -0.216*** 0.534* -0.014 0.420* 0.331 0.575* 0.157*** 0.323** -0.253*** 0.674** 0.449 0.057 0.620* 0.528 0.238** (0.050) (0.039) (0.264) (0.089) (0.183) (0.215) (0.275) (0.042) (0.104) (0.071) (0.228) (0.273) (0.097) (0.236) (0.364) (0.080) Targeted X 1986 0.212*** -0.238*** 0.628** 0.022 0.501** 0.415* 0.676* 0.168*** 0.343** -0.279*** 0.648** 0.511 0.073 0.658** 0.572 0.255** (0.051) (0.039) (0.236) (0.085) (0.182) (0.199) (0.264) (0.044) (0.109) (0.070) (0.224) (0.280) (0.102) (0.229) (0.379) (0.082) Industry Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Baseline Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-Squared 0.900 0.971 0.583 0.761 0.866 0.595 0.789 0.899 0.904 0.972 0.743 0.867 0.824 0.745 0.807 0.925 Observations 4063 4059 4063 4063 4063 4063 4063 4063 1720 1711 1720 1720 1720 1720 1720 1720 Clusters 239 239 239 239 239 239 239 239 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 0.313 28.302 0.672 1.717 0.998 0.170 0.120 0.655 1.000 4.164 1.180 0.736 1.766 0.292 0.771 0.400 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.732 0.000 0.512 0.182 0.370 0.843 0.887 0.520 0.423 0.002 0.326 0.599 0.129 0.916 0.574 0.848

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive (HCI) industrial policy and industrial outcomes. Output share is the industry share of manufacturing output. Prices are output prices. Labor Productivity is value added per worker. Average Size is the average establishment size. Number of Plants is the count of establishments. Employment is total number of industry workers. Labor Share is the industry’s share of manufacturing employment. Variables are ihs normalized.. Targeted x Year corre- spond to the interaction between treatment indicator (0 or 1 for HCI industry) and year effects; coefficient estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. Estimates are from a linear two-way fixed effect regression, and with industry and year effects. Specifications with controls in- clude pre-1973 averages for wagebill, firm size, material costs, and labor productivity, interacted with time.Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986. Figure B1: Differences in Value Added Per Worker and Output Prices, Relative to 1972 57 Table B3: Differences in the Evolution of Comparative Advantage

Outcomes - Revealed comparative advantage

RCA (ihs) RCA (ln) RCA I[RCA>1] (dummy)

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Targeted X 1965 -1.182*** -1.149*** -0.085 -0.103 -0.243 -0.426 -0.041 -0.044 (0.319) (0.324) (0.059) (0.061) (0.227) (0.266) (0.043) (0.044) Targeted X 1966 -0.682* -0.652* -0.061 -0.067 -0.319 -0.447 -0.024 -0.023 (0.315) (0.310) (0.059) (0.060) (0.300) (0.362) (0.044) (0.045) Targeted X 1967 -0.610* -0.531 -0.063 -0.062 -0.314 -0.420 -0.048 -0.051 (0.310) (0.307) (0.060) (0.060) (0.282) (0.339) (0.042) (0.043) Targeted X 1968 -0.672* -0.647* -0.013 -0.004 -0.105 -0.084 0.002 0.008 (0.312) (0.313) (0.064) (0.066) (0.185) (0.207) (0.042) (0.043) Targeted X 1969 -0.830** -0.865** -0.059 -0.057 -0.208 -0.254 -0.019 -0.015 (0.270) (0.276) (0.049) (0.050) (0.190) (0.223) (0.039) (0.039) Targeted X 1970 -0.600* -0.647** -0.036 -0.034 -0.218 -0.250 0.003 0.003 (0.241) (0.247) (0.046) (0.047) (0.187) (0.214) (0.037) (0.039) Targeted X 1971 -0.098 -0.129 -0.032 -0.040 -0.406* -0.480 -0.033 -0.037 (0.215) (0.212) (0.037) (0.038) (0.207) (0.253) (0.032) (0.033) Targeted X 1972 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) Targeted X 1973 0.221 0.189 0.039 0.038 0.204 0.152 0.015 0.012 (0.191) (0.195) (0.041) (0.041) (0.218) (0.273) (0.033) (0.032) Targeted X 1974 0.481* 0.510* 0.172* 0.166* 0.403 0.269 0.123* 0.111* (0.237) (0.240) (0.074) (0.076) (0.299) (0.339) (0.049) (0.049) Targeted X 1975 0.369 0.446 0.120 0.132 0.304 0.195 0.069 0.074 (0.236) (0.237) (0.071) (0.073) (0.397) (0.480) (0.043) (0.044) Targeted X 1976 0.381 0.403 0.100 0.094 0.358 0.216 0.036 0.028 (0.244) (0.245) (0.059) (0.061) (0.347) (0.403) (0.038) (0.038) Targeted X 1977 0.616* 0.688* 0.179* 0.192* 0.639 0.571 0.082 0.088 (0.277) (0.276) (0.077) (0.076) (0.348) (0.382) (0.049) (0.049) Targeted X 1978 0.618* 0.665** 0.171* 0.186* 0.808* 0.759 0.069 0.086 (0.248) (0.248) (0.074) (0.074) (0.380) (0.419) (0.047) (0.048) Targeted X 1979 0.711* 0.767** 0.201* 0.208** 0.859* 0.818 0.107* 0.111* (0.278) (0.272) (0.078) (0.077) (0.413) (0.455) (0.049) (0.050) Targeted X 1980 0.745** 0.716** 0.212* 0.197* 0.963* 0.877 0.132* 0.123* (0.274) (0.274) (0.084) (0.083) (0.463) (0.501) (0.052) (0.052) Targeted X 1981 0.723* 0.691* 0.238** 0.223** 1.370* 1.250 0.124* 0.115* (0.280) (0.276) (0.088) (0.086) (0.578) (0.642) (0.052) (0.052) Targeted X 1982 0.810** 0.737* 0.316*** 0.297** 1.666** 1.517* 0.149** 0.140* (0.297) (0.294) (0.094) (0.092) (0.587) (0.632) (0.054) (0.055) Targeted X 1983 0.820** 0.773** 0.370*** 0.347*** 1.864** 1.694* 0.198*** 0.198*** (0.286) (0.285) (0.097) (0.095) (0.604) (0.655) (0.057) (0.057) Targeted X 1984 0.872** 0.813** 0.368*** 0.343*** 1.915** 1.737* 0.198*** 0.192** (0.288) (0.286) (0.095) (0.094) (0.662) (0.723) (0.057) (0.058) Targeted X 1985 0.949** 0.924** 0.376*** 0.356*** 1.928** 1.761* 0.198*** 0.189*** (0.288) (0.281) (0.091) (0.088) (0.659) (0.718) (0.054) (0.055) Targeted X 1986 1.090*** 1.072*** 0.391*** 0.375*** 1.695** 1.547* 0.215*** 0.216*** (0.278) (0.273) (0.088) (0.086) (0.560) (0.629) (0.055) (0.055) Industry Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Baseline Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.703 0.717 0.702 0.723 0.613 0.647 0.561 0.573 Observations 10758 10670 10758 10670 10758 10670 10758 10670 Clusters 489 485 489 485 489 485 489 485 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 2.771 2.705 0.929 1.225 0.911 1.441 0.681 0.804 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.008 0.009 0.483 0.287 0.497 0.187 0.689 0.584

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive (HCI) indus- trial policy and trade development outcomes. RCA (ihs) and RCA (ln) are normalized revealed comparative advantage; RCA is raw index. ’Dummy’ is an indicator equal to one if an industry has realized RCA (RCA>1). Panel is at the SITC Rev. 1, 4-digit level. Trade values reflect real values (won, 2010 base).. Targeted x Year correspond to the interaction between treatment indicator (0 or 1 for HCI industry) and year ef- fects; coefficient estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. Estimates are from a linear two-way fixed effect regression, and with indus- try and year effects. Specifications with controls include pre-1973 averages for wagebill, firm size, material costs, and labor productivity, inter- acted with time.Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * UN COMTRADE database. Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986.

58 Figure B2: Semiparametric Doubly-Robust Estimates Across Industrial Development Outcomes, 4 Digit Industry Panel 59 Figure B3: Semiparametric Doubly-Robust Estimates Across Industrial Development Outcomes, 5 Digit Industry Panel

60 Figure B4: Semiparametric Doubly-Robust Estimates Across Industrial Development Outcomes, Trade Data Panel

61 Table C1: Impact of HCI on Input Use and Investment, HCI vs. Non-HCI Industry

Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Material Costs Capital Formation Inventory Investment Material Costs Capital Formation Inventory Investment

ihs levels ihs levels ihs levels ihs levels ihs levels ihs levels

12 345612 3456

Targeted X 1967 0.114 2670.793 0.028 -7948.374* 0.971 -772.964 (0.243) (18136.663) (0.320) (3618.044) (0.847) (1521.902) Targeted X 1968 0.193 7182.233 0.090 -8480.625* 0.219 884.032 (0.222) (17534.330) (0.319) (3927.243) (1.055) (1723.160) Targeted X 1969 0.146 14223.480 0.009 -7611.858 -0.716 98.866 (0.225) (18742.024) (0.274) (3999.817) (0.964) (1129.185) Targeted X 1970 0.212 3060.532 -0.390 -2136.138* 0.024 -515.440 0.109 9316.475 -0.520 -7151.245* -0.169 2114.482 (0.221) (4209.806) (0.271) (981.253) (0.264) (1195.656) (0.313) (15828.646) (0.267) (3493.715) (0.255) (2032.223) Targeted X 1971 0.106 1156.358 0.148 -1300.148 -0.083 -571.502 0.239 4924.348 0.082 -6484.134* 0.044 3010.923 (0.233) (4300.608) (0.279) (701.585) (0.239) (1186.912) (0.309) (12362.932) (0.362) (3004.511) (0.300) (2461.391) Targeted X 1972 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) Targeted X 1973 0.641** -2013.964 0.455 -616.195 1.426*** 1290.239 0.208 17601.905 -0.130 -1448.558 0.317 13023.835 (0.211) (8048.115) (0.237) (1326.956) (0.417) (1561.157) (0.249) (27319.841) (0.199) (2910.677) (0.246) (8389.741) Targeted X 1974 0.566** 33425.275* 0.427 777.710 0.646** 3039.417 0.112 119940.435* 0.079 -3154.041 0.380 19144.270 (0.183) (13140.184) (0.240) (1910.172) (0.238) (3309.007) (0.135) (50661.977) (0.236) (5326.923) (0.302) (13568.681) Targeted X 1975 0.427 30397.193* 0.260 1307.606 0.366 -584.700 0.327 94629.095 -0.042 2182.543 0.074 -729.773

62 (0.255) (14934.173) (0.273) (2085.499) (0.276) (2457.259) (0.268) (62447.037) (0.312) (7298.379) (0.349) (7353.068) Targeted X 1976 0.487 64222.799* 0.075 1061.996 0.364 313.402 0.611 169077.675 -0.064 3807.311 0.313 1227.783 (0.297) (28010.532) (0.285) (1807.537) (0.288) (2470.217) (0.449) (98852.651) (0.296) (4028.178) (0.336) (8851.431) Targeted X 1977 0.751** 67989.230** 0.454 2925.354 0.722** 2295.473 0.729 221003.059* -0.075 3883.313 0.434 9070.462 (0.273) (25853.254) (0.292) (2157.916) (0.254) (2217.594) (0.407) (108573.924) (0.261) (4175.132) (0.278) (8485.915) Targeted X 1978 0.893*** 136834.169*** 0.649* 10060.489** 0.754 7465.061 0.896* 415637.433** 0.287 17543.181* 1.334 14756.709 (0.267) (38851.138) (0.303) (3822.153) (0.565) (4325.488) (0.420) (149523.453) (0.308) (7536.365) (1.246) (8895.524) Targeted X 1979 1.085*** 155959.595*** 0.732* 9673.047 1.035* 8824.968 0.899* 490591.786** 0.150 37053.047 -0.684 28640.932 (0.289) (44687.921) (0.296) (5056.196) (0.496) (4641.718) (0.428) (174708.812) (0.330) (27108.602) (1.063) (18428.570) Targeted X 1980 0.765** 146078.260** 0.798** 16658.507** 0.701 7211.787 0.724 514659.757** 0.274 36864.066 1.098 36733.947 (0.249) (45343.587) (0.270) (6014.037) (0.742) (4823.090) (0.398) (192610.694) (0.280) (18810.047) (0.589) (23280.719) Targeted X 1981 0.798** 171670.189*** 0.458 16656.200** 1.044 6454.589 0.801 660494.347** 0.232 42943.073* 1.517 25575.583 (0.256) (49548.800) (0.293) (6402.512) (0.773) (5638.788) (0.430) (227301.922) (0.253) (19345.070) (1.185) (25132.513) Targeted X 1982 0.791** 199705.840*** 0.558 18157.476** 1.221 -1240.609 0.870 708792.033** 0.368 60031.408 -0.210 648.359 (0.278) (54470.951) (0.316) (6799.063) (0.990) (2019.608) (0.440) (235361.889) (0.275) (33607.838) (1.816) (8450.278) Targeted X 1983 0.870** 253047.054*** 0.710* 14420.245** 0.843 891837.642** 0.630 24244.829* (0.301) (68183.330) (0.316) (5330.113) (0.427) (284769.230) (0.356) (10523.862) Targeted X 1984 0.798** 311497.774*** 0.767* 22135.006** 0.905* 1083323.583** 0.632 39424.549 (0.293) (88474.028) (0.295) (8354.287) (0.437) (358180.091) (0.365) (22251.208) Targeted X 1985 0.859* 339798.813*** 0.784* 20483.801** 0.858 1191670.380** 0.581 37754.227* (0.347) (91676.273) (0.333) (7018.181) (0.449) (371811.393) (0.382) (18929.359) Targeted X 1986 0.971** 441636.267*** 0.924** 50542.976** 0.864 1414448.727** 0.737 87965.454* (0.324) (120307.655) (0.333) (16178.994) (0.461) (473524.134) (0.402) (37292.324) Year Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Industry Effect X X X X X X X X X X X X Controls X X X X X X X X X X X X R-Squared 0.763 0.836 0.770 0.615 0.407 0.722 0.813 0.858 0.850 0.599 0.428 0.718 Observations 4063 4063 4034 4034 3107 3107 1720 1720 1716 1716 1376 1376 Clusters 239 239 238 238 239 239 86 86 86 86 86 86 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 0.486 0.363 1.984 2.377 0.102 0.116 0.525 0.395 1.265 1.466 0.715 0.944 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.616 0.696 0.140 0.095 0.903 0.890 0.757 0.851 0.287 0.209 0.614 0.457

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive (HCI) industrial policy and outcomes related to input use, capital investment, and inventory investment. Ma- terial Costs are real total input material costs. Total Investment is real total gross fixed capital investment. Inventory Investment is annual real change in total inventories. Both levels and ihs-normalized outcomes are reported, to ac- commodate 0s in investment and negative changes in inventories. Targeted x Year correspond to the interaction between treatment indicator (0 or 1 for HCI industry) and year effects; coefficient estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. Estimates are from a linear two-way fixed effect regression, and with industry level and year effects. Specifications with controls include pre-1973 averages for wagebill, firm size, material costs, and labor productivity, in- teracted with time. Panel A shows estimates using shorter, detailed 5-digit level industrial data (1970-1986). Panel B shows estimates using longer, aggregate 4-digit level industrial data (1967-1986). Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986. Figure C1: Changes in Distribution of Trade Policies, HCI vs. Non-HCI, 1968-1982

63 Figure D1: Top 20 Non-HCI Sectors with Highest Forward and Backward (Direct) Linkages to Targeted Industry

Jewelry & related articles Zinc ores Plastic products Miscellaneous non−ferrous metal ores Synthetic fibre fabrics Tungsten ores Synthetic fibre yarn Copper ores Dyeing & finishing Moribuden mining Abrasive products Gold & silver ores Miscellaneous manufactured articles Manganese ores Limestone Silica sand Manganese ores Rubble collected industries, NEC Flat glass Miscellaneous non−metallic minerals 2 Miscellaneous non−metallic minerals 1 Worked hair & postiches 2 Animal & vegetable oils & fats Worked hair & postiches 1 Talc Bicycles & cycle carts Graphite Rope & fishing nets 2 Crude salt Industry Name Rope & fishing nets 1 Stone products String & processed string goods, NEC Abrasive products Rubber footwear Other leather products 1 Other transportation equipment 2 Other leather products 2 Other transportation equipment 1 Paper containers & other products 1 Other fibre yarn 1 Pulp, NEC, species & cardboard manufacturing Other fibre yarn 2 Paper containers & other products 2 Weaving & spinning industry, NEC Packaging container & related products 0.00 0.25 0.50 0.75 0.0 0.3 0.6 0.9

Share Forward Linkages Share Backward Linkages Notes: Figure shows the top−ranked manufacturing industries in terms of backward linkages and forward linkages to targeted industries. Both forward and backward linkages are oriented in terms of the treated sector. Share Backward Linkage measures the weighted share of output from a non−HCI industry being sold to an HCI industry. Whereas, Share Forward Linkage measures the weighted share inputs a non−HCI industry sources from HCI industry. See text for definitions of weights. Both measures are direct I−0 flows, and are calculated from the 1970 Bank of Korea input− output tables.

64 Figure D2: Targeted Sectors and Non-Targeted Sectors in the 1970 Korean Industrial Network, Weighted by Number of Outward Connections (Forward Linkages) to Downstream Sectors

65 Table E1: Impact of Direct Forward Linkages on Downstream Output

Outcome - Real value added (ihs) Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Full Sample Non-HCI Sample Full Sample Non-HCI Sample

1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4

1967 X Forward Link 0.00250 0.000382 0.00257 0.000777 (0.00711) (0.00663) (0.0109) (0.0114) 1968 X Forward Link 0.00870 0.00585 0.0118 0.00958 (0.00647) (0.00612) (0.0102) (0.0107) 1969 X Forward Link 0.0122 0.00909 0.0200 0.0177 (0.00992) (0.00924) (0.0157) (0.0157) 1970 X Forward Link -0.00664 -0.00596 -0.0104 -0.0100 -0.00174 -0.00216 -0.00188 -0.00230 (0.00694) (0.00710) (0.00892) (0.00892) (0.00435) (0.00456) (0.00535) (0.00545) 1971 X Forward Link -0.00656 -0.00871* -0.00439 -0.00699 -0.00191 -0.00194 -0.00300 -0.00304 (0.00451) (0.00431) (0.00582) (0.00547) (0.00291) (0.00286) (0.00363) (0.00336) 1972 X Forward Link 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) 1973 X Forward Link -0.00479 -0.00305 -0.00477 -0.00251 -0.00443 -0.00280 -0.00769 -0.00652 (0.00574) (0.00592) (0.00756) (0.00763) (0.00322) (0.00284) (0.00543) (0.00492) 1974 X Forward Link 0.0000774 0.00263 0.00305 0.00618 0.00486 0.00617 0.00308 0.00370 (0.00444) (0.00450) (0.00568) (0.00559) (0.00389) (0.00325) (0.00620) (0.00546) 1975 X Forward Link 0.0146 0.0172 0.0113 0.0135 0.00885 0.0125* 0.00977 0.0121 (0.00825) (0.00909) (0.0107) (0.0116) (0.00642) (0.00621) (0.0101) (0.00841) 1976 X Forward Link 0.0265** 0.0257** 0.0290* 0.0270* 0.0162 0.0174* 0.0166 0.0173 (0.00908) (0.00958) (0.0121) (0.0123) (0.00940) (0.00826) (0.0141) (0.0130) 1977 X Forward Link 0.0323*** 0.0343*** 0.0335* 0.0346* 0.0225* 0.0238* 0.0250 0.0253 (0.00958) (0.0101) (0.0130) (0.0135) (0.0103) (0.00931) (0.0159) (0.0149) 1978 X Forward Link 0.0237* 0.0248* 0.0198 0.0201 0.0229* 0.0244* 0.0252 0.0257 (0.00939) (0.0102) (0.0122) (0.0130) (0.0103) (0.00937) (0.0155) (0.0145) 1979 X Forward Link 0.0278** 0.0289** 0.0222 0.0219 0.0262* 0.0274** 0.0280 0.0283 (0.00986) (0.0106) (0.0120) (0.0127) (0.0101) (0.00920) (0.0153) (0.0143) 1980 X Forward Link 0.0281** 0.0291** 0.0257* 0.0253 0.0246* 0.0266* 0.0293 0.0302 (0.00977) (0.0105) (0.0129) (0.0134) (0.0107) (0.0101) (0.0168) (0.0161) 1981 X Forward Link 0.0265** 0.0286** 0.0211 0.0220 0.0235* 0.0250* 0.0270 0.0275 (0.00953) (0.0103) (0.0124) (0.0131) (0.0107) (0.00964) (0.0160) (0.0149) 1982 X Forward Link 0.0317** 0.0335** 0.0313* 0.0320* 0.0276* 0.0296** 0.0329 0.0336 (0.00993) (0.0107) (0.0135) (0.0141) (0.0118) (0.0112) (0.0183) (0.0175) 1983 X Forward Link 0.00703 0.00854 0.00752 0.00824 0.0141* 0.0165* 0.00771 0.00900 (0.00875) (0.00929) (0.0119) (0.0126) (0.00682) (0.00651) (0.00973) (0.00876) 1984 X Forward Link 0.00994 0.0114 0.00957 0.0104 0.0152* 0.0174** 0.00839 0.00972 (0.00947) (0.00998) (0.0124) (0.0131) (0.00658) (0.00642) (0.00896) (0.00838) 1985 X Forward Link 0.00459 0.00547 0.00585 0.00626 0.0150* 0.0163* 0.0105 0.0111 (0.00973) (0.0103) (0.0125) (0.0132) (0.00670) (0.00681) (0.00824) (0.00827) 1986 X Forward Link 0.0126 0.0134 0.0160 0.0165 0.0166* 0.0179* 0.0126 0.0133 (0.0101) (0.0108) (0.0133) (0.0140) (0.00768) (0.00786) (0.00965) (0.00971) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Network Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.770 0.771 0.773 0.775 0.831 0.834 0.815 0.820 Observations 4726 4726 3111 3111 1760 1760 1180 1180 Clusters 278 278 183 183 88 88 59 59 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 0.734 1.145 1.676 1.799 1.899 1.501 4.047 4.317 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.569 0.336 0.157 0.131 0.056 0.153 0.000 0.000

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between direct forward linkage exposure to Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive sec- tors and output, measured as real value added (ihs) . Estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. All specifications include industry and year effects. Panel A shows estimates using detailed 5-digit level industrial data (1970-1986). Panel B shows estimates using longer, aggregate 4-digit level industrial data (1967-1986). ’Full sample’ refers to estimates for full sample of manufacturing industries (columns 1-2); full-sample regressions include controls for HCI sectors (Targeted x Year). ’Non-HCI Sample’ refers to sample excluding treated industry. Controls refer to pre-1973 averages for wagebill, firm size, total costs, and labor productivity (inter- acted with time effects). Network Controls refer to 1970 eigenvalue centrality and total network degrees interacted with time. All regressions include controls for direct backward interacted with time. Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986.

66 Table E2: Impact of Direct Forward Linkages on Downstream Output Prices

Outcome - Output prices (ihs) Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Full Sample Non-HCI Sample Full Sample Non-HCI Sample

1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4

1970 X Forward Link 0.000508 0.000461 0.000688 0.000701 0.000508 0.000461 0.000688 0.000701 (0.000332) (0.000339) (0.000476) (0.000488) (0.000332) (0.000339) (0.000476) (0.000488) 1971 X Forward Link 0.000413 0.000388 0.000533 0.000550 0.000413 0.000388 0.000533 0.000550 (0.000237) (0.000234) (0.000333) (0.000335) (0.000237) (0.000234) (0.000333) (0.000335) 1972 X Forward Link 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) 1973 X Forward Link 0.000183 0.000111 -0.000316 -0.000381 0.000183 0.000111 -0.000316 -0.000381 (0.000302) (0.000306) (0.000405) (0.000406) (0.000302) (0.000306) (0.000405) (0.000406) 1974 X Forward Link -0.000459 -0.00111* -0.000960 -0.00162* -0.000459 -0.00111* -0.000960 -0.00162* (0.000549) (0.000546) (0.000738) (0.000733) (0.000549) (0.000546) (0.000738) (0.000733) 1975 X Forward Link -0.00105 -0.00176** -0.00165 -0.00250** -0.00105 -0.00176** -0.00165 -0.00250** (0.000683) (0.000670) (0.000908) (0.000899) (0.000683) (0.000670) (0.000908) (0.000899) 1976 X Forward Link -0.00189* -0.00250*** -0.00249** -0.00328*** -0.00189* -0.00250*** -0.00249** -0.00328*** (0.000745) (0.000727) (0.000927) (0.000929) (0.000745) (0.000727) (0.000927) (0.000929) 1977 X Forward Link -0.00255** -0.00317*** -0.00319** -0.00401*** -0.00255** -0.00317*** -0.00319** -0.00401*** (0.000783) (0.000758) (0.000985) (0.000982) (0.000783) (0.000758) (0.000985) (0.000982) 1978 X Forward Link -0.00340*** -0.00407*** -0.00378*** -0.00456*** -0.00340*** -0.00407*** -0.00378*** -0.00456*** (0.000893) (0.000878) (0.000951) (0.000952) (0.000893) (0.000878) (0.000951) (0.000952) 1979 X Forward Link -0.00259** -0.00337*** -0.00259** -0.00343*** -0.00259** -0.00337*** -0.00259** -0.00343*** (0.000967) (0.000944) (0.000941) (0.000916) (0.000967) (0.000944) (0.000941) (0.000916) 1980 X Forward Link -0.00260* -0.00359** -0.00209 -0.00308* -0.00260* -0.00359** -0.00209 -0.00308* (0.00125) (0.00123) (0.00133) (0.00128) (0.00125) (0.00123) (0.00133) (0.00128) 1981 X Forward Link -0.00294* -0.00390** -0.00211 -0.00304 -0.00294* -0.00390** -0.00211 -0.00304 (0.00147) (0.00146) (0.00161) (0.00157) (0.00147) (0.00146) (0.00161) (0.00157) 1982 X Forward Link -0.00341* -0.00436** -0.00233 -0.00324* -0.00341* -0.00436** -0.00233 -0.00324* (0.00149) (0.00148) (0.00150) (0.00142) (0.00149) (0.00148) (0.00150) (0.00142) 1983 X Forward Link -0.00355* -0.00449** -0.00263 -0.00351** -0.00355* -0.00449** -0.00263 -0.00351** (0.00147) (0.00145) (0.00143) (0.00134) (0.00147) (0.00145) (0.00143) (0.00134) 1984 X Forward Link -0.00311* -0.00408** -0.00227 -0.00317* -0.00311* -0.00408** -0.00227 -0.00317* (0.00148) (0.00146) (0.00146) (0.00137) (0.00148) (0.00146) (0.00146) (0.00137) 1985 X Forward Link -0.00269 -0.00368* -0.00158 -0.00251 -0.00269 -0.00368* -0.00158 -0.00251 (0.00152) (0.00150) (0.00152) (0.00144) (0.00152) (0.00150) (0.00152) (0.00144) 1986 X Forward Link -0.00260 -0.00356* -0.00166 -0.00256 -0.00260 -0.00356* -0.00166 -0.00256 (0.00154) (0.00153) (0.00151) (0.00144) (0.00154) (0.00153) (0.00151) (0.00144) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Network Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.957 0.958 0.951 0.952 0.957 0.958 0.951 0.952 Observations 4722 4722 3107 3107 4722 4722 3107 3107 Clusters 278 278 183 183 278 278 183 183 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 18.293 17.950 59.307 60.914 18.293 17.950 59.307 60.914 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between direct forward linkage exposure to Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive sectors and output prices (ihs) . Estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. All specifications include industry and year effects. Panel A shows estimates using detailed 5-digit level indus- trial data (1970-1986). Panel B shows estimates using longer, aggregate 4-digit level industrial data (1967-1986). ’Full sample’ refers to estimates for full sample of manufacturing industries (columns 1-2); full-sample regressions include controls for HCI sectors (Targeted x Year). ’Non-HCI Sample’ refers to sample excluding treated industry. Controls refer to pre-1973 averages for wagebill, firm size, total costs, and labor productivity (interacted with time effects). Network Controls refer to 1970 eigenvalue centrality and total net- work degrees interacted with time. All regressions include controls for direct backward interacted with time. Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986.

67 Table E3: Average Impact of Total (Leontief ) Linkages on Output, Before and After 1973

Outcome - Real value added (ihs)

Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Full Sample Non-HCI Sample Full Sample Non-HCI Sample

1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4

Post X Forward Link 0.0119** 0.0119* 0.0352* 0.0331* 0.0178** 0.0195*** 0.0220 0.0287* (0.00441) (0.00460) (0.0150) (0.0147) (0.00548) (0.00570) (0.0131) (0.0125) Post X Backward Link -0.000351 -0.0000801 0.00137 0.00155 -0.00952 -0.00982 -0.0251 -0.0216 (0.00325) (0.00326) (0.00373) (0.00371) (0.00584) (0.00541) (0.0166) (0.0146) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Network Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.763 0.764 0.765 0.768 0.829 0.832 0.813 0.818 Observations 4726 4726 3111 3111 1760 1760 1180 1180 Clusters 278 278 183 183 88 88 59 59

Note: Average differences-in-differences estimates, before and after 1973. Regressions interact linkage measure with Post 1973 indicator. For these estimates, both linkage interactions are shown (forward and backward); whereas, dynamic estimates presented only linkages for the interaction of interest (for- ward or backward). Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986.

Table E4: Average Impact of Leontief Linkages on Output Prices, Before and After 1973

Outcome - Output prices (ihs)

Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Full Sample Non-HCI Sample Full Sample Non-HCI Sample

1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4

Post X Forward Link -0.00217** -0.00227** -0.00399* -0.00387 -0.00450** -0.00469** -0.00660** -0.00677** (0.000771) (0.000765) (0.00198) (0.00196) (0.00164) (0.00162) (0.00232) (0.00225) Post X Backward Link 0.00111*** 0.00101*** 0.000993*** 0.000909** 0.00333* 0.00322* 0.00757** 0.00716** (0.000243) (0.000237) (0.000290) (0.000280) (0.00164) (0.00158) (0.00274) (0.00266) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Network Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.951 0.952 0.941 0.943 0.954 0.956 0.952 0.954 Observations 4722 4722 3107 3107 1751 1751 1177 1177 Clusters 278 278 183 183 88 88 59 59

Note: Average differences-in-differences estimates, before and after 1973. Regressions interact linkage measure with Post 1973 indicator. For these estimates, both link- age interactions are shown (forward and backward); whereas, dynamic estimates presented only linkages for the interaction of interest (forward or backward). Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986.

68 Table E5: Average Impact of Direct Linkages on Industrial Development Outcomes, Before and After 1973

A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Employment Avg. Wage. Num. Plants Labor Prod. Employment Avg. Wage. Num. Plants Labor Prod.

Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI

1234567812345678

Post X Forward Link 0.0169** 0.0188* 0.0112* 0.00730 0.0135*** 0.0171*** 0.0146* 0.0122 0.0137* 0.0170* 0.0109 0.00632 0.0153*** 0.0215*** 0.00251 -0.00155 (0.00521) (0.00738) (0.00515) (0.00614) (0.00318) (0.00417) (0.00627) (0.00808) (0.00589) (0.00822) (0.00593) (0.00771) (0.00445) (0.00502) (0.00488) (0.00671) Post X Backward Link -0.0120* -0.0138* -0.00972 -0.00923 -0.00387 -0.00617 -0.00871 -0.00824 -0.00475 -0.0146** -0.0160** -0.0213* 0.00154 -0.00709 -0.00799 -0.0112 (0.00534) (0.00663) (0.00520) (0.00679) (0.00285) (0.00337) (0.00570) (0.00743) (0.00526) (0.00465) (0.00567) (0.00874) (0.00515) (0.00465) (0.00406) (0.00569) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No R-Squared 0.784 0.803 0.632 0.615 0.855 0.866 0.628 0.611 0.846 0.850 0.725 0.665 0.885 0.893 0.748 0.704 Observations 4726 3111 4726 3111 4726 3111 4726 3111 1760 1180 1760 1180 1760 1180 1760 1180 Clusters 278 183 278 183 278 183 278 183 88 59 88 59 88 59 88 59

Note: Average differences-in-differences estimates, before and after 1973. Regressions interact linkage measure with Post 1973 indicator. For these estimates, both linkage interactions are shown (forward and backward); whereas, dynamic estimates pre- sented only linkages for the interaction of interest (forward or backward). Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986. 69

Table E6: Average Impact of Total (Leontief ) Linkages on Industrial Development , Before and After 1973

A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Employment Avg. Wage. Num. Plants Labor Prod. Employment Avg. Wage. Num. Plants Labor Prod.

Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI

1234567812345678

Post X Forward Link 0.00976** 0.0269* 0.00336 0.0134 0.00750*** 0.0219** 0.00298 0.0149 0.0148** 0.0229 0.0120* 0.00689 0.0118*** 0.0295*** 0.00528 -0.00389 (0.00366) (0.0108) (0.00318) (0.00987) (0.00222) (0.00661) (0.00365) (0.0119) (0.00435) (0.0121) (0.00501) (0.0118) (0.00344) (0.00806) (0.00377) (0.0100) Post X Backward Link -0.000657 0.00102 0.000875 0.00195 0.000527 0.00158 0.00275 0.00388 -0.00663 -0.0139 -0.00930* -0.0230 -0.00247 -0.00202 -0.00416 -0.0142 (0.00255) (0.00279) (0.00268) (0.00304) (0.00114) (0.00130) (0.00290) (0.00330) (0.00366) (0.0104) (0.00451) (0.0118) (0.00230) (0.00579) (0.00343) (0.0103) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No R-Squared 0.783 0.802 0.630 0.614 0.854 0.867 0.627 0.612 0.848 0.852 0.724 0.670 0.885 0.892 0.748 0.706 Observations 4726 3111 4726 3111 4726 3111 4726 3111 1760 1180 1760 1180 1760 1180 1760 1180 Clusters 278 183 278 183 278 183 278 183 88 59 88 59 88 59 88 59

Note: Average differences-in-differences estimates, before and after 1973. Regressions interact linkage measure with Post 1973 indicator. For these estimates, both linkage interactions are shown (forward and backward); whereas, dynamic estimates presented only linkages for the interaction of interest (forward or backward). Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986. Table E7: Impact of Direct vs.Total Forward Linkages on Downstream Exports

Panel A) Dependent variable - Direct forward linkages Panel B) Dependent variable - Total (Leontief) forward linkages

RCA (ihs) RCA (ln) RCA I[RCA>1] Export Value RCA (ihs) RCA (ln) RCA I[RCA>1] Export Value

Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

1965 X Forward Link 0.289* 0.349* 0.141 0.322 0.985 1.171 0.249** 0.291** 1.100 1.322 0.117 0.135 0.0217 0.0435 0.245 0.282 0.122** 0.127** -0.00559 0.00921 (0.143) (0.165) (0.596) (0.641) (0.674) (0.792) (0.0876) (0.0979) (1.832) (1.876) (0.0956) (0.101) (0.281) (0.297) (0.475) (0.502) (0.0453) (0.0483) (0.904) (0.927) 1966 X Forward Link 0.166 0.207 -0.326 -0.224 0.816 0.979 0.109 0.123 -0.140 -0.0438 0.0768 0.0918 -0.298 -0.245 0.159 0.162 0.0742 0.0709 -1.117 -1.064 (0.135) (0.154) (0.553) (0.599) (0.565) (0.666) (0.0797) (0.0885) (1.674) (1.697) (0.0905) (0.0953) (0.278) (0.289) (0.362) (0.390) (0.0481) (0.0503) (0.871) (0.892) 1967 X Forward Link 0.128 0.145 -0.254 -0.171 0.563 0.657 0.106 0.126 -0.283 -0.0821 0.0683 0.0812 -0.0552 -0.0102 -0.111 -0.122 0.0776 0.0852 -0.366 -0.102 (0.126) (0.143) (0.519) (0.543) (0.523) (0.616) (0.0770) (0.0862) (1.581) (1.661) (0.0778) (0.0818) (0.253) (0.259) (0.285) (0.310) (0.0470) (0.0498) (0.823) (0.845) 1968 X Forward Link 0.135 0.150 0.0705 0.0567 0.0435 0.00851 0.157* 0.178* 1.016 1.382 0.0671 0.0730 -0.149 -0.112 -0.112 -0.140 0.0877* 0.0933* -0.760 -0.387 (0.115) (0.120) (0.515) (0.541) (0.464) (0.530) (0.0695) (0.0759) (1.580) (1.596) (0.0689) (0.0691) (0.246) (0.249) (0.214) (0.222) (0.0395) (0.0407) (0.859) (0.859) 1969 X Forward Link 0.0700 0.0960 -0.313 -0.115 0.172 0.224 0.0756 0.103 -0.591 0.381 0.0301 0.0436 -0.204 -0.129 -0.0609 -0.0598 0.0309 0.0377 -0.458 0.0633 (0.0934) (0.104) (0.434) (0.466) (0.380) (0.448) (0.0616) (0.0685) (1.464) (1.562) (0.0583) (0.0605) (0.236) (0.243) (0.173) (0.189) (0.0414) (0.0429) (0.704) (0.731) 1970 X Forward Link -0.00503 0.0112 -0.280 -0.322 -0.127 -0.116 0.00474 0.0260 0.431 1.093 -0.0210 -0.00751 -0.373 -0.339 -0.121 -0.107 0.00797 0.00920 -0.474 -0.164 (0.0913) (0.101) (0.432) (0.469) (0.463) (0.547) (0.0588) (0.0600) (1.303) (1.457) (0.0614) (0.0642) (0.230) (0.241) (0.189) (0.204) (0.0381) (0.0392) (0.788) (0.830) 1971 X Forward Link 0.0462 0.0379 0.0808 0.0274 0.00647 -0.0198 0.0366 0.0405 2.117 2.014 -0.00480 -0.00130 -0.108 -0.138 0.0414 -0.00230 -0.00809 -0.00882 0.740 0.629 (0.0834) (0.0946) (0.456) (0.485) (0.321) (0.379) (0.0589) (0.0639) (1.396) (1.496) (0.0371) (0.0400) (0.201) (0.212) (0.199) (0.215) (0.0297) (0.0318) (0.775) (0.814) 1972 X Forward Link 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) 1973 X Forward Link 0.0723 0.0440 -0.118 -0.0519 0.358 0.360 0.0569 0.0455 -0.122 0.318 0.00779 0.00138 0.0170 0.0649 0.227 0.248 -0.0142 -0.0230 0.242 0.397 (0.0698) (0.0810) (0.338) (0.367) (0.240) (0.285) (0.0616) (0.0719) (1.129) (1.277) (0.0470) (0.0505) (0.175) (0.186) (0.214) (0.235) (0.0350) (0.0378) (0.635) (0.670) 1974 X Forward Link 0.265* 0.268* 0.740 0.920* 0.457 0.609 0.208** 0.193* 1.642 2.436 0.0745 0.0754 0.411 0.490* 0.0902 0.151 0.0782* 0.0695 0.720 0.983 (0.117) (0.120) (0.411) (0.458) (0.501) (0.519) (0.0786) (0.0860) (1.107) (1.246) (0.0656) (0.0669) (0.215) (0.228) (0.380) (0.390) (0.0369) (0.0388) (0.663) (0.693) 1975 X Forward Link 0.0434 0.0548 -0.464 -0.270 -0.116 0.0687 0.0439 0.0377 0.133 0.427 -0.00322 0.00697 -0.132 -0.0178 -0.182 -0.125 0.0152 0.0132 -0.114 0.136 (0.110) (0.107) (0.395) (0.438) (0.547) (0.536) (0.0755) (0.0805) (1.058) (1.181) (0.0584) (0.0572) (0.204) (0.217) (0.475) (0.479) (0.0347) (0.0358) (0.699) (0.723) 1976 X Forward Link 0.272* 0.215 0.425 0.446 0.723 0.591 0.157 0.125 0.781 1.746 0.162* 0.148* 0.413 0.506* 0.438 0.422 0.0955** 0.0813* 1.472* 1.991**

70 (0.119) (0.131) (0.423) (0.460) (0.549) (0.637) (0.0804) (0.0915) (1.079) (1.147) (0.0680) (0.0715) (0.234) (0.248) (0.473) (0.495) (0.0347) (0.0372) (0.677) (0.701) 1977 X Forward Link 0.323* 0.165 0.102 -0.194 0.875 0.547 0.139 0.0630 -1.169 -1.054 0.120 0.103 0.223 0.279 0.427 0.411 0.0418 0.0319 0.271 0.634 (0.136) (0.145) (0.457) (0.485) (0.605) (0.696) (0.0846) (0.0880) (1.296) (1.404) (0.0650) (0.0668) (0.218) (0.230) (0.470) (0.486) (0.0339) (0.0356) (0.721) (0.754) 1978 X Forward Link 0.355** 0.254 0.598 0.541 0.951 0.707 0.136 0.109 0.436 1.016 0.177** 0.169* 0.590** 0.651** 0.599 0.612 0.0575 0.0541 0.912 1.304* (0.131) (0.142) (0.442) (0.483) (0.600) (0.683) (0.0857) (0.0908) (1.331) (1.456) (0.0658) (0.0681) (0.208) (0.220) (0.468) (0.487) (0.0413) (0.0428) (0.626) (0.655) 1979 X Forward Link 0.437** 0.348* 0.981* 0.822 0.998 0.814 0.263** 0.204* 1.890 2.236 0.245*** 0.242** 0.690*** 0.783*** 0.702 0.746 0.154*** 0.143** 1.514* 1.993** (0.139) (0.156) (0.468) (0.505) (0.639) (0.739) (0.0893) (0.0956) (1.307) (1.419) (0.0737) (0.0773) (0.206) (0.221) (0.488) (0.510) (0.0435) (0.0460) (0.685) (0.729) 1980 X Forward Link 0.429** 0.357* 0.907* 1.032* 1.003 0.829 0.266** 0.209* 1.241 2.547 0.282*** 0.277*** 0.851*** 0.970*** 0.853 0.911 0.151** 0.137** 2.119** 2.689*** (0.147) (0.163) (0.457) (0.494) (0.714) (0.830) (0.0876) (0.0934) (1.281) (1.385) (0.0780) (0.0821) (0.231) (0.243) (0.512) (0.538) (0.0476) (0.0498) (0.762) (0.789) 1981 X Forward Link 0.503** 0.439* 0.951 1.086* 1.400* 1.266 0.336*** 0.306** 2.259 3.492* 0.307*** 0.303*** 0.823*** 0.965*** 0.964 1.045 0.187*** 0.181*** 2.056** 2.680*** (0.155) (0.172) (0.486) (0.537) (0.678) (0.780) (0.0942) (0.102) (1.401) (1.548) (0.0828) (0.0863) (0.230) (0.246) (0.534) (0.569) (0.0498) (0.0529) (0.689) (0.723) 1982 X Forward Link 0.589*** 0.504** 1.449** 1.522** 1.695* 1.530 0.333*** 0.290** 3.693** 5.087*** 0.303*** 0.292** 0.992*** 1.096*** 1.004 1.071 0.179*** 0.168** 2.729*** 3.383*** (0.165) (0.184) (0.499) (0.555) (0.720) (0.837) (0.0931) (0.0996) (1.334) (1.459) (0.0904) (0.0938) (0.246) (0.261) (0.533) (0.565) (0.0519) (0.0542) (0.740) (0.775) 1983 X Forward Link 0.682*** 0.571** 1.527** 1.463** 2.059** 1.769* 0.367*** 0.313** 2.482* 3.196* 0.336*** 0.326*** 1.108*** 1.178*** 1.208* 1.265* 0.180*** 0.162** 2.827*** 3.199*** (0.161) (0.175) (0.495) (0.547) (0.728) (0.831) (0.0958) (0.102) (1.247) (1.373) (0.0879) (0.0908) (0.261) (0.277) (0.529) (0.563) (0.0491) (0.0514) (0.716) (0.751) 1984 X Forward Link 0.711*** 0.614*** 1.658*** 1.621** 2.188** 2.025* 0.342*** 0.268** 3.028* 3.813** 0.356*** 0.347*** 0.955*** 1.039*** 1.359** 1.427* 0.155** 0.137* 2.304** 2.711** (0.161) (0.179) (0.466) (0.509) (0.743) (0.859) (0.0911) (0.0957) (1.234) (1.310) (0.0867) (0.0899) (0.270) (0.284) (0.522) (0.562) (0.0519) (0.0539) (0.877) (0.903) 1985 X Forward Link 0.761*** 0.657*** 1.868*** 1.819*** 2.348** 2.215* 0.425*** 0.359*** 3.002* 3.347* 0.373*** 0.362*** 1.073*** 1.150*** 1.396** 1.466** 0.204*** 0.183*** 2.293** 2.590*** (0.160) (0.176) (0.477) (0.523) (0.748) (0.868) (0.0950) (0.102) (1.269) (1.362) (0.0874) (0.0899) (0.252) (0.265) (0.511) (0.553) (0.0492) (0.0518) (0.699) (0.726) 1986 X Forward Link 0.733*** 0.645*** 1.858*** 1.901*** 2.173** 2.104* 0.355*** 0.279** 3.684** 4.944** 0.357*** 0.356*** 1.216*** 1.322*** 1.305* 1.447** 0.169*** 0.143** 3.072*** 3.678*** (0.154) (0.171) (0.499) (0.558) (0.704) (0.822) (0.0924) (0.0981) (1.376) (1.508) (0.0888) (0.0918) (0.292) (0.307) (0.513) (0.557) (0.0477) (0.0497) (0.888) (0.918) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No R-Squared 0.708 0.725 0.708 0.715 0.614 0.616 0.569 0.590 0.701 0.705 0.706 0.722 0.708 0.716 0.614 0.616 0.567 0.588 0.702 0.706 Observations 10736 8822 10736 8822 10736 8822 10736 8822 10676 8787 10736 8822 10736 8822 10736 8822 10736 8822 10676 8787 Clusters 488 401 488 401 488 401 488 401 488 401 488 401 488 401 488 401 488 401 488 401 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 1.747 1.751 1.045 1.039 1.066 1.022 1.597 1.409 1.144 0.677 0.697 0.596 1.045 0.678 0.897 0.881 1.372 1.300 1.588 0.737 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.044 0.044 0.407 0.413 0.386 0.430 0.076 0.145 0.316 0.797 0.778 0.869 0.407 0.796 0.562 0.580 0.162 0.204 0.078 0.737

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between forward linkage exposure to HCI and export development. RCA is revealed comparative advantage index. RCA also normalized ihs and natural ln for completenes. Indicator I[RCA>1] is dummy equal to 1 when RCA>1, 0 otherwise. Export values are ihs normalized to accomodate 0s. Estimates are relative to, 1972, the year before HCI. The year 1979 corresponds to collapse of Park regime. Panel A reports ’Year X Forward Linkage’ estimates for direct links. Panel B reports ’Year X Forward Linkage’ estimates for total forward or Leontief linkages.. Specificiations are two-way fixed effect OLS estimates, and include year and industry effects. All regressions include controls for backward interacted with time. Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * SITC Trade data - UN-COMTRADE † Direct and Total Linkaes Linkages - Calculated from the 1970 domestic I-O accounts. Bank of Korea. Table E8: Impact of Direct Forward Linkages on Downstream Input Use

Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Material Cost Total Investment Equipment Investment Materials Cost Total Investment Equipment Investment

Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI Full Non-HCI

123456123456

1967 X Forward Link 0.00906 0.00841 0.0204* 0.0206 (0.00590) (0.00908) (0.00837) (0.0118) 1968 X Forward Link 0.0131* 0.0164 0.0123 0.00875 0.0193* 0.0198 (0.00518) (0.00827) (0.0107) (0.0159) (0.00908) (0.0123) 1969 X Forward Link 0.00866 0.0109 0.0125 0.0140 0.0152 0.0180 (0.00489) (0.00796) (0.00844) (0.0126) (0.00942) (0.0141) 1970 X Forward Link 0.000401 0.00187 0.00588 0.000511 0.0104 0.00237 -0.00229 -0.000814 0.00649 0.00835 0.00611 0.00627 (0.00551) (0.00501) (0.00776) (0.00735) (0.00793) (0.00841) (0.00473) (0.00375) (0.00664) (0.00609) (0.00883) (0.00999) 1971 X Forward Link -0.00768 -0.00671 0.00145 0.00512 0.00596 0.00645 0.00180 0.00257 0.00574 0.00494 0.00942 0.00956 (0.00550) (0.00741) (0.00620) (0.00781) (0.00683) (0.00767) (0.00263) (0.00228) (0.00785) (0.0110) (0.00675) (0.00849) 1972 X Forward Link 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) 1973 X Forward Link -0.000944 -0.00197 0.00338 -0.0000880 0.0149* 0.00852 0.00111 -0.00328 0.00636 0.00465 0.0158* 0.0139 (0.00479) (0.00597) (0.00675) (0.00805) (0.00678) (0.00843) (0.00280) (0.00398) (0.00470) (0.00602) (0.00686) (0.00888) 1974 X Forward Link -0.00166 -0.00135 0.00183 0.000193 0.00589 0.00640 0.00591 0.00591 0.0120 0.00469 0.0142* 0.00782 (0.00544) (0.00789) (0.00593) (0.00725) (0.00546) (0.00721) (0.00554) (0.00876) (0.00741) (0.00804) (0.00682) (0.00639) 1975 X Forward Link 0.0130 0.0101 0.0168* 0.0197 0.0140 0.0207* 0.0114 0.0154 0.0224** 0.0231 0.0226** 0.0238*

71 (0.00781) (0.0103) (0.00723) (0.0108) (0.00734) (0.0104) (0.00628) (0.00965) (0.00831) (0.0116) (0.00830) (0.0105) 1976 X Forward Link 0.0247** 0.0265* 0.0202** 0.0226* 0.0208** 0.0225* 0.0161 0.0194 0.0241** 0.0256* 0.0247* 0.0273* (0.00918) (0.0122) (0.00686) (0.00907) (0.00763) (0.00937) (0.00988) (0.0146) (0.00913) (0.0112) (0.0110) (0.0135) 1977 X Forward Link 0.0313** 0.0332* 0.0275*** 0.0279** 0.0240** 0.0255* 0.0217* 0.0274 0.0222** 0.0227* 0.0269** 0.0257* (0.00972) (0.0135) (0.00728) (0.0107) (0.00793) (0.0113) (0.0109) (0.0171) (0.00719) (0.00920) (0.00854) (0.0115) 1978 X Forward Link 0.0192* 0.0172 0.0244*** 0.0218* 0.0250** 0.0252* 0.0196 0.0264 0.0246** 0.0216* 0.0250* 0.0245 (0.00889) (0.0118) (0.00724) (0.00973) (0.00761) (0.0101) (0.0108) (0.0170) (0.00864) (0.00961) (0.0103) (0.0125) 1979 X Forward Link 0.0242* 0.0208 0.0219** 0.00926 0.0147 0.0000331 0.0221* 0.0281 0.0194* 0.00849 0.0123 -0.00206 (0.00990) (0.0123) (0.00771) (0.0103) (0.00832) (0.0112) (0.0107) (0.0167) (0.00883) (0.00940) (0.0124) (0.0158) 1980 X Forward Link 0.0262** 0.0259 0.0238** 0.0228* 0.0137 0.0120 0.0201 0.0293 0.0204* 0.0243 0.00864 0.00829 (0.00974) (0.0133) (0.00734) (0.0104) (0.00737) (0.00997) (0.0113) (0.0177) (0.00937) (0.0136) (0.00931) (0.0122) 1981 X Forward Link 0.0236* 0.0209 0.0170* 0.0108 0.0152* 0.0110 0.0217 0.0306 0.0170* 0.0131 0.0156 0.0145 (0.00933) (0.0125) (0.00716) (0.0102) (0.00738) (0.0105) (0.0114) (0.0172) (0.00711) (0.00942) (0.00808) (0.0103) 1982 X Forward Link 0.0263** 0.0276* 0.0249** 0.0234* 0.0165* 0.0121 0.0210 0.0296 0.0235** 0.0179 0.0207* 0.0116 (0.00963) (0.0133) (0.00765) (0.0107) (0.00783) (0.0106) (0.0115) (0.0178) (0.00889) (0.0107) (0.00984) (0.0116) 1983 X Forward Link 0.00102 0.00620 0.00887 0.00743 0.00754 0.00510 0.0232** 0.0171 (0.00851) (0.0109) (0.00930) (0.0115) (0.00591) (0.00916) (0.00756) (0.00872) 1984 X Forward Link 0.00727 0.0116 0.0125 0.00838 0.00903 0.00571 0.0256** 0.0148 (0.00928) (0.0119) (0.00955) (0.0117) (0.00570) (0.00877) (0.00847) (0.00980) 1985 X Forward Link 0.00107 0.00784 0.00999 0.0139 0.00943 0.00859 0.0201* 0.0156 (0.00950) (0.0117) (0.00975) (0.0117) (0.00607) (0.00853) (0.00796) (0.0102) 1986 X Forward Link 0.00996 0.0174 0.0125 0.0126 0.0111 0.00965 0.0218* 0.0163 (0.0100) (0.0131) (0.00998) (0.0123) (0.00666) (0.00930) (0.00840) (0.00979) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No R-Squared 0.777 0.789 0.782 0.787 0.781 0.782 0.846 0.838 0.848 0.843 0.844 0.832 Observations 4726 3111 4663 3073 3551 2341 1760 1180 1752 1175 1316 883 Clusters 278 183 275 181 275 181 88 59 88 59 88 59 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 1.194 1.656 0.478 0.169 0.720 0.391 1.552 2.622 0.979 0.957 1.066 1.053 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.314 0.162 0.752 0.954 0.579 0.815 0.135 0.011 0.467 0.490 0.395 0.408

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between direct forward linkages linkage exposure to HCI and input use, capital investment, and inventory investment.Material Costs are real total in- put material costs. Total Investment is real gross fixed capital investment. Equipment Investment is investment in equipment and machinery assets. All are ihs normalized for lumpy investment. Estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. The year 1979 corresponds to the collapse of Park regime. Panel A shows estimates using shorter 5-digit industrial data (1970-1986). Panel B shows estimates using longer, aggregate 4-digit industrial data (1967- 1986). Specificiations are two-way fixed effect OLS estimates, and include year and industry effects. All regressions control for direct backward linkages interacted with time.Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986. Table F1: Impact of Direct Backward Linkages on Upstream Output

Outcome - Real value added (ihs) Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Full Sample Non-HCI Sample Full Sample Non-HCI Sample

1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4

1967 X Backward Link 0.00946* 0.00926* 0.0185* 0.0184* (0.00410) (0.00430) (0.00793) (0.00708) 1968 X Backward Link 0.00939* 0.00939* 0.0167* 0.0167* (0.00388) (0.00398) (0.00806) (0.00687) 1969 X Backward Link 0.0116 0.0122 0.0201 0.0205 (0.00644) (0.00695) (0.0115) (0.0104) 1970 X Backward Link 0.00434 0.00370 0.0126* 0.0118* 0.00278 0.00261 0.0114*** 0.0112** (0.00509) (0.00508) (0.00513) (0.00508) (0.00423) (0.00436) (0.00314) (0.00327) 1971 X Backward Link -0.00431 -0.00455 -0.00297 -0.00303 0.000467 0.000393 0.00414* 0.00404 (0.00479) (0.00477) (0.00601) (0.00590) (0.00268) (0.00275) (0.00207) (0.00220) 1972 X Backward Link 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) 1973 X Backward Link -0.00765 -0.00700 -0.00849 -0.00784 -0.000393 -0.000433 -0.00417 -0.00417 (0.00542) (0.00541) (0.00691) (0.00690) (0.00332) (0.00348) (0.00379) (0.00383) 1974 X Backward Link -0.000873 -0.000245 -0.000609 0.0000776 0.00512* 0.00502 0.00364 0.00360 (0.00416) (0.00419) (0.00533) (0.00536) (0.00250) (0.00254) (0.00341) (0.00353) 1975 X Backward Link -0.0132 -0.0125 -0.0139 -0.0128 -0.00386 -0.00440 -0.00701 -0.00731 (0.00863) (0.00865) (0.0113) (0.0112) (0.00362) (0.00355) (0.00617) (0.00541) 1976 X Backward Link -0.00841 -0.00854 -0.00224 -0.00165 0.00245 0.00248 0.00332 0.00334 (0.00626) (0.00634) (0.00706) (0.00699) (0.00572) (0.00596) (0.00799) (0.00851) 1977 X Backward Link -0.0149* -0.0145* -0.0129 -0.0117 -0.000555 -0.00105 -0.00370 -0.00414 (0.00686) (0.00694) (0.00862) (0.00864) (0.00623) (0.00659) (0.00935) (0.0101) 1978 X Backward Link -0.00990 -0.00922 -0.00823 -0.00703 -0.00336 -0.00386 -0.00914 -0.00963 (0.0100) (0.0100) (0.0131) (0.0130) (0.00685) (0.00718) (0.00920) (0.00992) 1979 X Backward Link -0.0136 -0.0136 -0.0103 -0.00952 -0.00177 -0.00218 -0.00962 -0.0101 (0.0116) (0.0117) (0.0153) (0.0152) (0.00729) (0.00766) (0.00919) (0.00994) 1980 X Backward Link -0.0154 -0.0154 -0.0142 -0.0136 -0.00475 -0.00525 -0.0142 -0.0147 (0.0107) (0.0108) (0.0142) (0.0142) (0.00751) (0.00794) (0.0103) (0.0109) 1981 X Backward Link -0.0158 -0.0155 -0.0165 -0.0158 -0.00721 -0.00747 -0.0180 -0.0183 (0.0100) (0.0100) (0.0132) (0.0132) (0.00845) (0.00878) (0.00967) (0.0102) 1982 X Backward Link -0.0162 -0.0162 -0.0170 -0.0165 -0.00971 -0.0103 -0.0235* -0.0240* (0.00930) (0.00937) (0.0122) (0.0122) (0.00954) (0.0100) (0.0111) (0.0118) 1983 X Backward Link -0.0293** -0.0290** -0.0326** -0.0318** -0.0132 -0.0134 -0.0211** -0.0212** (0.00931) (0.00937) (0.0120) (0.0120) (0.00740) (0.00770) (0.00632) (0.00686) 1984 X Backward Link -0.0243** -0.0238** -0.0257** -0.0246** -0.0136 -0.0135 -0.0222** -0.0222** (0.00777) (0.00782) (0.00957) (0.00944) (0.00769) (0.00797) (0.00691) (0.00722) 1985 X Backward Link -0.0331** -0.0325** -0.0367* -0.0356* -0.0151 -0.0150 -0.0270*** -0.0269*** (0.0120) (0.0120) (0.0158) (0.0157) (0.00849) (0.00871) (0.00646) (0.00664) 1986 X Backward Link -0.0345** -0.0339** -0.0408* -0.0399* -0.0160 -0.0158 -0.0303*** -0.0302*** (0.0124) (0.0124) (0.0162) (0.0161) (0.00924) (0.00948) (0.00647) (0.00671) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Network Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.770 0.771 0.773 0.775 0.831 0.834 0.815 0.820 Observations 4726 4726 3111 3111 1760 1760 1180 1180 Clusters 278 278 183 183 88 88 59 59 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 0.734 1.145 1.676 1.799 1.899 1.501 4.047 4.317 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.569 0.336 0.157 0.131 0.056 0.153 0.000 0.000

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between direct backward linkage exposure to Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive sectors and output, real value added per worker (ihs) . Estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. All specifications include industry and year effects. Panel A shows estimates using detailed 5-digit level industrial data (1970-1986). Panel B shows estimates using longer, aggregate 4-digit level industrial data (1967-1986). ’Full sample’ refers to estimates for full sample of manufacturing industries (columns 1-2); full-sample regressions include controls for HCI sectors (Targeted x Year). ’Non-HCI Sam- ple’ refers to sample excluding treated industry. Controls refer to pre-1973 averages for wagebill, firm size, total costs, and labor productivity (interacted with time ef- fects). Network Controls refer to 1970 eigenvalue centrality and total network degrees interacted with time. All regressions include controls for direct forward interacted with time. Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986.

72 Table F2: Impact of Total (Leontief ) Backward Linkages on Upstream Output

Outcome - Real value added (ihs) Panel A) 5-Digit Panel, 1970 - 1986 Panel B) 4-Digit Panel, 1967 - 1986

Full Sample Non-HCI Sample Full Sample Non-HCI Sample

1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4

1967 X Backward Link 0.00778 0.00771 0.0212 0.0187 (0.00683) (0.00679) (0.0216) (0.0199) 1968 X Backward Link 0.00690 0.00691 0.0224 0.0190 (0.00675) (0.00662) (0.0213) (0.0193) 1969 X Backward Link 0.00571 0.00598 0.0229 0.0180 (0.00696) (0.00676) (0.0221) (0.0196) 1970 X Backward Link 0.00456* 0.00455* 0.00472* 0.00475* -0.000883 -0.000958 0.000161 0.0000222 (0.00185) (0.00188) (0.00200) (0.00202) (0.00270) (0.00276) (0.00707) (0.00692) 1971 X Backward Link -0.00199 -0.00217 -0.00189 -0.00213 -0.00146 -0.00149 -0.00281 -0.00262 (0.00268) (0.00271) (0.00302) (0.00305) (0.00255) (0.00261) (0.00751) (0.00728) 1972 X Backward Link 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) 1973 X Backward Link -0.00316 -0.00280 -0.00394 -0.00363 -0.00289 -0.00293 -0.0138 -0.0119 (0.00294) (0.00297) (0.00331) (0.00334) (0.00382) (0.00357) (0.0112) (0.0102) 1974 X Backward Link -0.00112 -0.000760 -0.00195 -0.00162 0.00383 0.00371 0.00191 0.00330 (0.00305) (0.00308) (0.00339) (0.00343) (0.00357) (0.00367) (0.0107) (0.0100) 1975 X Backward Link 0.00308 0.00347 0.00473 0.00507 -0.00493 -0.00538 -0.0148 -0.0103 (0.00337) (0.00338) (0.00373) (0.00372) (0.00347) (0.00300) (0.0116) (0.00971) 1976 X Backward Link 0.00306 0.00288 0.00601 0.00571 -0.00550 -0.00567 -0.00618 -0.00502 (0.00301) (0.00305) (0.00340) (0.00337) (0.00397) (0.00391) (0.0122) (0.0106) 1977 X Backward Link 0.00102 0.00118 0.00411 0.00418 -0.00583 -0.00632 -0.0122 -0.0108 (0.00363) (0.00365) (0.00401) (0.00398) (0.00415) (0.00402) (0.0153) (0.0137) 1978 X Backward Link 0.00385 0.00404 0.00667 0.00675 -0.00642 -0.00691 -0.0132 -0.0114 (0.00402) (0.00404) (0.00451) (0.00449) (0.00459) (0.00445) (0.0164) (0.0146) 1979 X Backward Link 0.00210 0.00212 0.00537 0.00533 -0.00585 -0.00630 -0.0128 -0.0114 (0.00438) (0.00440) (0.00473) (0.00473) (0.00447) (0.00441) (0.0162) (0.0146) 1980 X Backward Link 0.00100 0.00100 0.00369 0.00361 -0.00736 -0.00787 -0.0174 -0.0153 (0.00437) (0.00440) (0.00486) (0.00486) (0.00464) (0.00441) (0.0163) (0.0144) 1981 X Backward Link 0.00128 0.00146 0.00401 0.00410 -0.00828 -0.00865 -0.0197 -0.0186 (0.00434) (0.00436) (0.00492) (0.00493) (0.00520) (0.00508) (0.0154) (0.0139) 1982 X Backward Link 0.00101 0.00107 0.00349 0.00348 -0.00806 -0.00861 -0.0209 -0.0190 (0.00401) (0.00404) (0.00453) (0.00455) (0.00541) (0.00521) (0.0179) (0.0161) 1983 X Backward Link -0.000511 -0.000172 0.00166 0.00188 -0.0110 -0.0113 -0.0223 -0.0200 (0.00394) (0.00395) (0.00434) (0.00432) (0.00611) (0.00583) (0.0156) (0.0146) 1984 X Backward Link 0.000545 0.000893 0.00137 0.00159 -0.0107 -0.0108 -0.0205 -0.0186 (0.00291) (0.00292) (0.00318) (0.00315) (0.00609) (0.00591) (0.0158) (0.0151) 1985 X Backward Link -0.00303 -0.00266 -0.00181 -0.00159 -0.00860 -0.00863 -0.0141 -0.0134 (0.00430) (0.00429) (0.00467) (0.00465) (0.00466) (0.00462) (0.00791) (0.00805) 1986 X Backward Link -0.00207 -0.00174 -0.00104 -0.000861 -0.00955 -0.00958 -0.0169 -0.0162 (0.00467) (0.00467) (0.00525) (0.00524) (0.00493) (0.00489) (0.00919) (0.00934) Industry Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fe Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Targeted X Year Yes Yes No No Yes Yes No No Network Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes R-Squared 0.765 0.766 0.769 0.771 0.831 0.834 0.817 0.821 Observations 4726 4726 3111 3111 1760 1760 1180 1180 Clusters 278 278 183 183 88 88 59 59 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (F-Test) 2.712 2.418 4.224 3.664 0.957 0.716 1.489 1.519 Joint Test of Pre-Trend (P-Values) 0.030 0.049 0.003 0.007 0.487 0.707 0.167 0.156

Note: Table shows dynamic differences-in-differences estimates for the relationship between total (Leontief) backward linkage exposure to Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive sectors and output, real value added per worker (ihs) . Estimates are relative to 1972, the year before HCI. All specifications include industry and year effects. Panel A shows estimates using detailed 5-digit level industrial data (1970-1986). Panel B shows estimates using longer, aggregate 4-digit level industrial data (1967- 1986). ’Full sample’ refers to estimates for full sample of manufacturing industries (columns 1-2); full-sample regressions include controls for HCI sectors (Targeted x Year). ’Non-HCI Sample’ refers to sample excluding treated industry. Controls refer to pre-1973 averages for wagebill, firm size, total costs, and labor productivity (in- teracted with time effects). Network Controls refer to 1970 eigenvalue centrality and total network degrees interacted with time. All regressions include controls for to- tal (Leontief) forward interacted with time. Standard errors are clustered at the industry-level and corrected for heteroskedasticity. * Significant at the 10 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. * Source for Panel A - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1970-1986. † Source for Panel B - Mining and Manufacturing Survey and Mining and Manufacturing Census: 1967-1986.

73 Figure F1: Relationship Between Direct Backward Linkages on Upstream Output

A) Entire Sample B) Non−HCI Only C) Entire Sample D) Non−HCI Only 4−Digit Panel 4−Digit Panel 5−Digit Panel 5−Digit Panel 0.025

0.02

0.025 0.00 0.000

0.00 0.000 −0.02 −0.025 Value Add. Value

−0.025 −0.04 −0.02 −0.050

−0.050 −0.06 −0.075

Notes: Figure plots dynamic differences−in−differences estimates for the relationship between direct backward linkage exposure to HCI and outcomes: real value added. Estimates are relative to, 1972, the year before HCI. The year 1979 corresponds to collapse of Park regime. Years are on the x−axis. Estimates for the effect of direct backward (Linkage X Year) linkages are on y−axis. Full sample regressions control for the main HCI x Year effect. All regressions include controls for direct forward linkage connections, interacted with time. Regression tables in Appendix. 95 percent confidence interveals are shown in gray.

74 Figure F2: Impact of Backward Linkages (Direct vs. Total) on Imported Goods

A) Backward Direct Linkages B) Backward Leontief Linkages Entire Sample Non−HCI Only Entire Sample Non−HCI Only 0.015

0.02 0.04 0.02 0.010

0.01 0.02 0.005 0.01

0.00 0.000 0.00 0.00

−0.01 −0.005

−0.02 −0.01

−0.02 −0.010

Notes: Figure plots dynamic differences−in−differences estimates for the relationship between (direct or total) backward linkage exposure to HCI and outcomes: real value of imports (ihs) Estimates are relative to, 1972, the year before HCI. The year 1979 corresponds to collapse of Park regime. Years are on the x−axis. Estimates for the effect of (direct or total) backward (Linkage X Year) linkages are on y−axis. Full sample regressions control for the main HCI x Year effect. All regressions include controls for (direct or total) forward linkage connections, interacted with time. 95 percent confidence interveals are shown in gray.

75