Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, 29,2(December 1997):419–435 O 1997 Southern Agricultural Economics Association

Price Expectations and Supply Response in the Yearling Market

J. Shannon Neibergs and Richard Thalheimer

ABSTRACT

Limited information is available concerning price determination in the thoroughbred year- ling market. A recursive model incorporating price expectations and biological constraints is useit to estimate supply and demand functions for thoroughbred . Empirical results characterize a market with inelastic supply and elastic demand that converges to equilib- rium under static conditions, Purses were identified as the most influential variable im- pacting price. Comparative statics illustrate the effectiveness of purses as a policy instru- ment for the thoroughbred industry. Federal tax policy also was found to have a significant impact on the decisions to breed or invest in thoroughbred yearlings.

Key Words: elasticity, parimutuel racing, price determination, price flexibility, purs- es, thoroughbred, yearling.

The thoroughbred race horse industry has a The thoroughbred industry can be roughly rich history as a form of recreation, and as a divided into five sectors. In the breeding sec- source of legalized gaming. In the United tor, the primary focus is producing that States, over $14 billion was wagered on pari- are predominantly sold as yearlings.2 This sec- mutuel horse racing in 1995 (Christiansen and tor’s investment in the industry includes the Cummings). Predominant states involved in breeding stock of and mares, and ex- the thoroughbred industry ranked by crop tensive fixed capital assets from which to con- include Kentucky, California, Florida, Texas, duct breeding operations. The second sector and Oklahoma (The Jockey Club). Currently, includes owners of yearlings and horses-in- the thoroughbred industry is undergoing struc- training, They are investors who create the tural change in response to speculative invest- market demand for the breeding sector’s pro- ment and disinvestment that has occurred in duction. Participants in this sector view horses the breeding industry, an expansion in simul- as capital assets whose values reflect expected casting races, 1and increased competition from after-tax earnings from racing and breeding, a proliferation of alternative gaming options, plus the additional utility gained from directly

The authors are assistant professor and associate pro- off-track wagering sites. Simulcasting has had signifi- fessor, respectively, with the Equine Industry Program, cant effects on the geographical distribution of gross College of Business and Public Administration, Uni- amount wagered and on-track attendance, and has versity of Louisville, Louisville, Kentucky. changed a race track’s market from a regionat to a na- The helpful comments of Robert G. Lawrence and tional and internationalbasis. two anonymous reviewers are gratefully acknowl- 2All become yearlings on the first edged. January 1 after they are foaled. Therefore, each thor- 1Simulcasting is where a track conducts a live race oughbred has January 1 as its official birthday. The and simultaneously transmits the race via satellite to primary market for thoroughbreds is yearling auctions. 420 Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, December 1997

Thousands

60

I o I I I 1960 1963 1966 1969 1972 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 Year

Source: The Blood-Horse, Annual Auction Review.

Figure 1. Average North America yearling sale price (deflated 1994 = 100) and supply, 1960–94

participating in a professional sport. The third yearling market research. The next two sec- sector includes racetracks who conduct pari- tions specify the empirical model and present mutuel racing. The fourth sector is comprised the results. Comparative dynamics are then an- of state governments which set regulations and alyzed with a specific emphasis on analyzing tax requirements guiding the industry. Horse purse and federal tax policy impacts on the race bettors, who make up the fifth sector, pro- market. Potential impacts to breeders and vide (directly or indirectly) the source of funds yearling buyers from an evolving thorough- for breeders, owners, race tracks, and govern- bred market are summarized and highlighted ments. Demand for thoroughbred yearlings is in the conclusions. a derived demand initiated by horse racing . bettors investing in parimutuel wagering pools History of Thoroughbred Industry and that fund the purses for which race horse own- Review of Literature ers compete.3 The principal objective of this study is to History present a dynamic econometric model of the thoroughbred yearling market. The model is Impacts to the thoroughbred industry manifest used to analyze (a) the effect of purses on the their effects in the yearling market where the demand for yearlings, (b) the dynamic supply greatest number of horses are sold. The year- response to changes in the price of yearlings, ling market is the most significant source of (c) the importance of the export market as a revenue to breeders and depends on buyers’ determinant of demand, and (d) the impact of expectations of economic conditions in thor- taxes on the yearling market. oughbred racing. Over the past 30 years, the A brief historical review of the thorough- thoroughbred yearling market has exhibited bred industry is presented first to highlight im- trend and cyclical behavior reflecting changes portant changes in the yearling market relative in the industry, as shown in figure 1. to specifying an econometric model. This is The supply of yearlings in North America followed by a review of existing thoroughbred grew steadily from 1960 to 1975, rose rapidly from 1976 to peakat51,293 yearlings in 1987,

s State statutesgenerally specify the minimum re- and declined to 37,108 by 1994. Average distribution of gross parimutuel wagers to winning bet- yearling prices were steady from 1960 to tors, state taxes, race tracks, and purses. 1972, then grew rapidly from 1975 to a peak Neibergs and Thalheimer: Thoroughbred Yearling Supply and Demand 421 of $65,015 in 1984.4 The rapid rise in price Alternative gaming affects the thorough- was fueled by massive foreign purchases and bred yearling market through purses. The neg- domestic speculative investment (Hollings- ative substitution of alternative gaming for worth). Many yearling buyers were willing to parimutuel wagering decreases purses in areas pay a premium above any realistic racing earn- where there is direct competition between ings on the theory that they would eventually parimutuel and alternative gaming. Alterna- recapture their investment through tax savings tively, some states (e.g., Delaware, Iowa, and and the yearling’s residual breeding value. West Virginia) use alternative gaming revenue This amounted to unsustainable speculation to subsidize purses. In either case, purses are and, combined with federal tax reform, over- the active agent exerting influence on the thor- supply, economic recession, and decreased oughbred market. foreign expenditures, caused the market to de- cline rapidly from 1985 to 1992. The recent market recovery is the result of renewed for- Review of Literature eign interest and increased potential race earn- ings due to larger purses funded primarily by Although the thoroughbred industry represents the growth in simulcasting. a large economic sector, its market and factors By the close of the 1980s, parimutuel wa- affecting price determination remain largely gering had been legalized in 36 states. But the unexplored. Lawrence (1968) developed eco- 1980s and early 1990s also saw increased le- nomic models analyzing price determination galization of state lotteries and alternative for the quarter horse and thoroughbred indus- gaming. Widespread state lottery expansion tries, and was the first to specify a recursive changed the public’s perception of gaming model for this industry. Several alternative from morally corrupting, dishonestly operated, specifications of single and simultaneous mod- and the source of negative social externalities, els were estimated. Results indicated that sup- to a state-regulated source of funding, eco- ply, quality, national income, and potential nomic growth, and entertainment (Christian- earnings had the greatest impact on average son and Cummings). This growth reflects an thoroughbred yearling price. acceptance by the public of gaming as a lei- Karungu, Reed, and Tvedt tested the hy- sure time activity. The change in gaming’s im- pothesis that macroeconomic conditions affect age and two developments in the late 1980s thoroughbred yearling prices. Specifically, a and early 1990s have created the potential for trade weighted exchange rate, an intermediate a wide proliferation of gaming. First was the term interest rate, a binary variable represent- 1987 U.S. Supreme Court decision (Cah~ornia ing the 1986 Tax Reform Act, and purses were v. Cabazon Band of Mission Indians) that found to affect the median price of thorough- opened the door for gaming on Indian reser- bred yearlings auctioned at the Keeneland vations, as set forth in the subsequent Indian (Kentucky) and Saratoga (New York) select Gaming Regulatory Act of 1988 (Marfels). sales.5 Buzby and Jessup expanded on the Second was the surge in riverboat gaming work of Kanmgu, Reed, and Tvedt to include along the Mississippi River—authorized in 11- both macroeconomic variables and yearling- linois, Indiana, Iowa, Louisiana, Mississippi, specific variables (sex, month foaled, Ken- and Missouri. The negative substitution effect tucky bred, stud fees, and past racing perfor- on thoroughbred wagering and attendance mance of the sire and dam) in a hedonic model from lotteries (Thalheimer and Ali 1995a, c; that estimated individual yearling prices from Gulley and Scott; Simmons and Sharp) and casinos (Ali and Thalheimer; Thalheimer and SA select sate is a public auction in which the en- Ali 1995b) has been well established. trants have been nominated and chosen based on cri- teria for pedigree and conformation. Select sales rep- resent the highest quality yearlings in the market. Only ~All prices in this study are deflated by the CPI, a small portion of the yearling population qualifies for where 1994 = 100. a select sale. 422 Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, December 1997 a time series of Keeneland select sales. The agricultural production. Ezekiel’s 1938 work is data for the Buzby and Jessup study consisted a classic reference in the application of differ- of 3,027 yearlings auctioned from 1980 to ence equations in specifying a cobweb model 1990. A binary variable representing the 1986 (sometimes referred to as a recursive model). Tax Reform Act, the sire’s stud fee, gross for- More recently, progress has been made in an- eign purchases, month foaled, and the dam’s alyzing managed animal populations under al- past racing performance were found to signif- ternative dynamic and price expectation spec- icantly impact the price of individual year- ifications. Chavas and Klemme specified an lings. aggregate supply response model where pop- The results from both the Karungu, Reed, ulation dynamics were characterized by dif- and Tvedt, and Buzby and Jessup studies sup- ference equations defining the age distribution port the conclusion that macroeconomic con- of breeding stock, and optimal control meth- ditions affect the yearling market, because ods were used to derive efficient production they reflect the economic climate that encour- conditions in a dynamic setting, The investi- ages or discourages investors. However, re- gations of Rosen; Whipple and Menkhaus; and sults from these studies have limited applica- Foster and Burt are examples of subsequent tion to industrywide analysis due to their focus managed animal population models specified on select sales. From 1980 to 1994, the num- under the basis of difference equations. Stein ber of yearlings sold at the Keeneland and Sar- examined the presence of cobweb cycles in atoga select sales represented on average only commodities without futures markets. Rosen, 5,1 % of the total number of yearlings auc- Murphy, and Scheinkman specified a structur- tioned in North America, and their average al model to examine cattle cycles, and con- price was 16 times greater than the average cluded that a recursive structural model with price of all yearlings auctioned. Consequently, long-run constant returns to scale is a good the use of data limited to the select sales re- working approximation of the cattle market. sults in a small and biased representation of Irwin and Thraen provide a review of agri- the true population. A second limitation of the cultural commodity modeling under alterna- two studies is that neither model addressed the tive price expectations specifications. impact of yearling supply. And third, the use Economic analysis of the thoroughbred of a binary variable to represent the 1986 Tax yearling market is different, in part, because Reform Act allowed the regression models to thoroughbred horses are capital goods in com- incorporate a number of structural changes in parison to livestock commodities which are the yearling market during this time period typically modeled as consumption goods. Fur- into one variable. In addition to tax reform, thermore, a thoroughbred mare has a potential the effects of development and expansion in breeding life of over 20 years. The long breed- simulcasting, a decline in the number of live ing life and the lack of data classifying thor- racing opportunities, variation in gross purse oughbred breeding stock precludes the devel- structure, and the dramatic increase in com- opment of a model specification based on age petition from alternative gaming could mani- and quality distributions of thoroughbred fest their impacts in a binary variable repre- breeding stock. senting this time period. From an industry The thoroughbred breeding decision is be- perspective, these are the factors that must be tween breeding the mare, or not breeding the addressed, and the potential range of their im- mare and maintaining the mare on the farm. pacts must be determined to develop efficient Rarely are thoroughbred mares culled and sent policy recommendations. to slaughter. Therefore, a mare not bred one year can return to the breeding population in Model and Econometric Specification subsequent years depending on market con- ditions. The economic decision is dependent Economists have long recognized the impor- on the marginal costs of breeding a mare and tance of dynamics and price expectations in producing a yearling versus the expected price Neibergs and Thalheimer: Thoroughbred Yearling Supply and Demand 423 of selling the yearling. Because thoroughbred Table 1. Variable Definitions mares are constrained to produce one foal per Variable Definition year, and there is little that can be done to RFOAL, The number of registered foals in increase productivity, the supply response North America originates from changes in breeding inten- P, The average price of thoroughbred tions. yearlings auctioned in North The underlying model hypothesis is that America breeders act in accordance with the informa- MTB, The present value of tax benefits tion available to them when breeding deci- from a capital investment in a sions are made in a way represented by the thoroughbred mare interaction of a supply and demand model of FCI, A farm production cost index thoroughbred yearlings. Breeding decisions SFEE, The average advertised stud fee in are dependent on the expected price of year- North America lings. The expected price would result from YRL, The supply of yearlings in North the solution of the supply and demand model America YTB, The present value of tax benefits for price on the basis of information available from a capital investment in a when breeding decisions are made. By utiliz- yearling ing the expected price to explain breeding de- PRSE, The average purse per race in North cisions, all information in the supply and de- America mand model is brought to bear in determining GFP, The gross amount of foreign purchas- breeding decisions. es of thoroughbred yearlings auc- The empirical specification is based on a tioned simple model of intertemporal equilibrium EXR, The exchange rate of United King- with price expectations. Because there are bio- dom pounds for U.S. dollars logically determined time lags between price GGDP, The growth in gross domestic prod- discovery and the decisions to breed a mare, uct The number of live races in North register the foal, and sell the produced off- NR, America spring as a yearling, there is a natural dynamic model structure. The decision to breed a mare Note: All variablesare annualdata.Lagged variablesare noted as t– 1 or r – 2 when appropriate. is made early in year t,which is followed by an 11-month gestation period, to produce and register a foal in year t + 1.6 The foal matures for a year and is sold as a yearling in year t equation system (with variable definitions pro- + 2. Therefore, supply decisions are based in vided in table 1): part on breeders’ price expectations two years in the future. (1) Supply of Registered Foals: Demand for thoroughbred yearlings can RFOAL, = CXO+ a, RFOALt. , + wZP,-2 best be represented as a capital investment function. Profit maximization compels inves- + L@4TB,_z -k cidFCI,-z tors to be aware of factors affecting the earn- -t W5SFEE,-Z + p,; ing potential of yearlings. Previous studies on thoroughbred yearlings (Karungu, Reed, and (2) Foal-to-Yearling Transfer: Tvedt; Buzby and Jessup) have established the YRL, = RFOALt- ,; importance of purses, taxes, and foreign pur- and chases as demand determinants. The structural (3) Inverse Demand for Yearlings: model is specified by the following three- P, = PO + ($ YRL, + ~2YTB, + ~3PRSEt

6Thoroughbreds can be registered in years beyond -I- ~bGFP, + ~5EXR, + &jGGDp, t + 1, but would still be counted in the foal crop of yeart + 1. + fi7NR, + V,. 424 Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, December 1997

The Supply Model By modeling tax reform through i14TB,_z, the net effect on the marginal cost of breeding de- Equation (1) represents a supply model of reg- cisions from changes in marginal tax rates, de- istered thoroughbred foals, RFOAL,. Supply preciation schedules, and capital gains can be response to price is modeled where RFOALt determined directly. responds to national average price for thor- Costs of production are represented oughbred yearlings lagged two years (P,_2) to through the remaining two variables in the represent price expectations and reproductive supply model. A farm cost index (FCZ,_2) rep- constraints associated with breeding decisions, resents input costs of production, and SFEE1_z as previously discussed. Due to the high asset represents the national average stud fee paid fixity associated with thoroughbred breeding to breed a mare. A stochastic error term is rep- investments and the long length of time as- resented by p,. sociated with breeding decisions, the supply of thoroughbred yearlings changes gradually Foal-to-Yearling Transfer over time, This can be observed in the smooth supply response curve (as seen in figure 1). Thoroughbred foals are registered with the The stickiness in supply response is in part Jockey Club as weanlings shortly after they attributable to the large fixed capital invest- are born, and become yearlings on the first ment associated with horse production that is January 1 after they are foaled. Equation (2) not easily liquidated, the small difference in is an identity that transfers RFOAL, to the sup- marginal cost between a bred mare versus a ply of marketable yearlings, YRL,. Once a foal nonproductive barren mare, and the biological is registered, only death prevents it from be- constraints of reproduction. Also, many breed- coming a yearling. Since death loss rates for ers may not be price responsive due to their thoroughbreds are unavailable, and presumed willingness to subsidize their thoroughbred in- negligible and invariant over time, an identity vestment through periods of nonprofitability, is used to transfer foals to yearlings. A partial adjustment process is represented by a one-period lag of the endogenous variable, The Demand Model RFOAL,. Because tax benefits are a primary consid- Equation (3) represents an inverse demand eration in thoroughbred investment decisions, function where the national average price of changes in federal tax policy affect the thor- yearlings (F’,) is a function of the predeter- oughbred yearling market. Tax benefits are a mined supply of yearlings (YRLJ and a set of better indication than tax costs of federal tax current exogenous variables. The price of a policy impacts on the yearling market, since capital asset, a thoroughbred yearling being no tax benefits apply equally to profitable and exception, is related to its earnings potential. nonprofitable thoroughbred investment deci- sions. The effects of changes in federal tax year tax recovery period required for a broodmare in- policy can be captured through an index that vestment as follows: measures the present value of tax benefits N T,,ZD,,, C,N from a capital investment in a thoroughbred MTBt=~— — ,,=, (1 + r)” + (1 + r)N’ broodmare (Hall and Jorgenson). The mare tax benefit index (AA%?.z) represents the present for t = 1960, . . . . 1994, value of tax benefits generated from a fixed where n is an annual index relative to year t, and N is capital investment in a thoroughbred mare.7 the tax recovery period of a mare (which is seven years). T,l is the highest personal marginal tax rate; D,, is annual depreciation expense; C~ is the capital gains 7 MTB, is calculated for each year tin the time se- tax benefit when allowed, and O otherwise; and the ries 1960–94 as the present value of expected maxi- discount rate r is fixed at 8%. Each tax policy variable mum tax benefits from a fixed capital investment in a is projected over the seven-year tax planning horizon thoroughbred breeding mare, projected over a seven- as expected in year t. Neibergs and Thalheimer: Thoroughbred Yearling Supply and Demand 425

For a thoroughbred yearling, those earnings the industry. The breeding sector supplies are the purses for which it competes. The na- horses to race, owners need to run their horses tional average purse per race (PZWE,) repre- in races in order to earn purses, and race tracks sents yearling earning potential. need live racing as a source of on-track reve- The yearling tax benefit YTB, represents the nues and as a product to sell in the simulcast present value of the tax benefits generated market. The number of live thoroughbred from a capital investment in a thoroughbred races is represented in the demand model as yearling, and is calculated and defined in the NR,. A stochastic error term is represented by same manner as A4TB,.2.8 The importance of v,. tax reform impacts on yearling price is noted Because there is no direct feedback from in previous studies (Karungu, Reed, and the demand equation to the supply equation, Tvedt; Buzby and Jessup). the specified model is recursive. In a recursive Foreign investment greatly influences the system, each of the endogenous variables can thoroughbred yearling market. The gross be determined sequentially. Given values for amount of foreign purchases of thoroughbred P,.z, one can solve directly for RFOAL, in the yearlings (GF’P,) and the exchange rate of supply equation. Then, knowing RFOAL,, the United Kingdom pounds for U.S. dollars (EXR,) value of P, can be solved recursively in the are used to capture the export influences of demand equation. A recursive model structure demand on the thoroughbred market. Buyers can be tested for specification error against the from the United Kingdom led foreign pur- hypothesis: p(p,,, v,) = O (Pindyck and Rub- chasers for many years in the study. Gross for- infeld). eign purchases were identified as the most in- fluential macroeconomic variable in Buzby Data and Jessup’s study of yearling price determin- ants. The model is fitted with annual data from While foreign investors are important for 1960–94 for North America. This time frame their large investments in individual thorough- covers the evolution of the industry from its breds, domestic investors buy the majority of era as a gaming monopoly to widespread com- thoroughbreds and are heavily influenced by petition from alternative gaming and the intro- the state of the national economy. The growth duction of simulcasting. Data on RFOAL, were in gross domestic product (GGDP,), calculated obtained from the Jockey Club’s 1995 Fact as {GDP, – GDP,-,}, represents domestic Book: A Guide to the Thoroughbred Industry economic conditions. in North America. Data on Pt and GFPt were Live racing is important to all sectors of collected from various issues of the Annual Auction Review (The Blood-Horse) and rep- resent an annual summary of yearling auctions 8 YTB,is calculated for each year t in the time series in North America. Data on GFP, are available 1960–94 as the present value of expected maximum tax benefits from a fixed capital investment in a thor- only from 1973–94. Prior to 1973, foreign oughbred yearling, projected over a five-year tax re- purchases were relatively insignificant and covery period with a fixed discount rate r as follows: were not reported separately. Essentially, GFP, . m. is a variable with a constant value of zero as- YTB,=~a+~ ,,=1(1 + r)” (1 lNr)N’ sumed for years prior to 1973, and actual data for t = 1960, . . . . 1994, used when GFP, rose to a level of significance to be reported separately. where n is an annual index relative to year t,and N is the tax recovery period of a yearling (which is five PRSE, and NR, data were collected from years). T,,is the highest personal marginal tax rate; D,, various “All About Purses” articles (Law- is annual depreciation expense; C~ is the capital gains rence) appearing in the Thoroughbred Times. tax benefit when allowed, and O otherwise; and the A4TB,-2 and YTB, were calculated using data discount rate r is fixed at 8%. Each tax policy variable is projected over the five-year tax planning horizon as from Standard Federal Tax Reports: 1993 De- expected in year t. preciation Guide and the Internal Revenue 426 Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, December 1997

Table 2. Thoroughbred Yearling Market Model Empirical Results

Supply (RFOAL,) Demand (P,)

Signifi- Signifi- Estimated cance Estimated cance Variable Parameter Levela Variable Parameter LeveP

Constant –1,918.0 0,191 Constant –82,927.8 0.000 (1 ,430.6) (18,138.6) RFOAL,.l 0.876 0.000 YRL, –0.486 0.019 (0.049) (o. 194) P,., 0.104 0.006 YTB, 6.601 0.000 (0.035) (1.023) MTB,.Z 3.634 0.000 PRSE, 7.860 0.000 (0.671) (1.233) FCIt_, –8.626 0.002 GFp, 2.12E–4 0.000 (2.452) (1,89E-5) SFEE,.Z –0.308 0.631 EXR, –2.479 0.919 (0.635) (23.997) GGDP, 10.535 0.097 (6.120) NR, 0.141 0.396 (O.164) Summary Statistics: No. Observations 35 35 Adjusted R2 0.994 0.951 F-Statistic 1,066 0.000 97 0,000 Durbin-Watson 1.54 2.31 Durbin-H 1.423 NA P(l-h v,) –0.162 0.351

Notes: Numbersin parenthesesare standarderrors, aRepresentsthe level of significance associatedwith the estimatedregressionparameters.

Code (Commerce Clearing House). Data on tics, Consumer Price Index. (Descriptive sta- F’CZ, were taken from various issues of the tistics are presented in appendix table A 1.) U.S. Department of Agriculture’s Agricultural Statistics. The Annual Register (The Empirical Results and Discussion Blood-Horse) provided data on SFEE,.2. An annual average stud fee was calculated by av- Estimated results obtained from the data and eraging all advertised stud fees in the register specified model are presented in table 2. As per year. Over the study period, the average appropriate for recursive systems, ordinary annual number of stallions advertised in the least squares was used to estimate parameters. register was 2,321, Data on GGDP,, EXR,, and Overall model results strongly support the the consumer price index used to deflate data suggested model specification and the conclu- expressed in monetary units were obtained sion that the thoroughbred yearling market fol- from the Citibase macroeconomic database. lows a recursive market structure. Notably, the The sources of data for each of these Citibase correlation between error terms of the supply data series are, respectively, U.S. Department and demand equations, p(p,,, v,), of – 0.162 is of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; not significantly different than zero. The ad- Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve justed R2 is .99 and .95 for the supply and System, Foreign Exchange Rates; and U.S. demand equations, respectively. The Durbin- Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statis- Watson statistic in each case indicates the ab- Neibergs and Thalheimer: Thoroughbred Yearling Supply and Demand 427 sence of serial correlation, suggesting that the relatively inelastic demand for a limited num- equations are likely free of specification errors ber of yearlings with specific pedigrees sold such as those caused by omitted variables or for high prices at select sales. Given the low incorrect functional form. The Durbin-H cal- number of foreign-purchased yearlings and the culated for the supply equation which contains demand characteristics of foreign buyers, EXR, a lagged endogenous variable is 1.423; when was not found to significantly impact average compared to the critical value of 1.645 (nor- yearling price. However, the importance to the mal 0,1 distribution for a one-tailed test at the market of foreign purchases is evidenced by 5% level of significance), this supports the the high significance in GFP,. When foreign conclusion of an absence of serial correlation. buyers are active in the market, it increases All coefficients in both the supply and de- competition and the pool of money available mand equations have the anticipated signs. for yearling investment. If, for example, a do- Each coefficient in the supply equation, except mestic investor loses the bid on a yearling to for the constant and SFEE,-2, is significant at a foreign buyer, the domestic investor is likely a level of 1Yo. The lack of significance in to bid on a subsequent yearling in the sale, SFEE,.2 may stem from problems with the thus bolstering the overall market. Based on original data which calculated the average stud theoretical and empirical considerations, both fee based on the advertised price. In many GFP, and EXR, were retained in the model. 10 cases, the actual stud fee paid is negotiated to The number of live races (NR,) was a con- a rate lower than the advertised fee. Also, stud cern of the industry when simulcasting ex- fees are set relative to the strength of the year- panded greatly in the late 1980s. It was widely ling market and the quality of the stallion. believed that simulcasting would negatively Breeders historically have been willing to pay impact the industry by decreasing NR,, which higher stud fees in times when the market was in turn would depress the demand for thor- expanding.g Stud fee is assumed to be an im- oughbred yearlings. The lack of significance portant variable in breeding decisions and is for NR, indicates that the market does not sig- left in the model despite its lack of signifi- nificantly recognize variation in the number of cance. live races as a threat or an incentive to the Alternative specifications analyzing the earning potential of thoroughbred yearling in- lag structure of the supply model were esti- vestments. In sum, the model specification es- mated. A distributed lag specification for the timated in this analysis appears valid based on lagged endogenous variable of RFOAL,.2 and statistical and economic merits. RFOAL,.3, and alternative lags in the price response in addition to P,.z, were estimated. Supply and Demand Parameter Elasticities Empirically these models did not perform well. The supply elasticities and price flexibilities Variables EXR, and IVR, in the demand presented in table 3 provide an indication of equation are statistically insignificant, but the price responsiveness and market charac- have the correct sign. All other estimated de- teristics of thoroughbred yearlings. The price mand coefficients are significant at the 1~o lev- elasticity of supply calculated at the mean is el, with the exception of GGDP,, which is sig- 0.116, indicating an inelastic supply response. nificant at the 10~0 level. In considering the Given the biological constraints, lack of alter- insignificance of EXR,, only 1.890 of the num- ber of yearlings auctioned are purchased by !OAlternative demand models were estimated by foreign buyers. Typically, these buyers have a dropping GFP, or EXR, from the demand model to evaluate potential multicollinearity between these two variables. When GFP, wasdropped, EXRt remained in- gThe correlation between SFEE,_t and Pt-z was significant. When EXR, was dropped, the estimated co- tested for problems of multicollinearity. The variables efficient and the significance level of GFP, did not are not significantly correlated (0. 112 with a p-value change. The variables are significantly negatively cor- of 0.511), related (–0.601 with a p-value of 0.031). 428 Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, December 1997

Table 3. Short-Run Supply Elasticities and in magnitude between the estimated price flex- Demand Flexibilities at the Mean ibility coefficients. The price-quantity flexibility coefficient of Supply (RFOAL,) Demand (P,) –0.426 for YRL, indicates that, as the supply Variable Elasticity Variable Flexibility of registered foals increases, the breeding RFOAL,. , 0.859 YRL, –0.426 sector’s marginal revenue will be positive cet- P,.l 0.116 YTB, 0.536 eris paribus, because the revenue gained from MTB,-, 0.262 PRSEt 2.606 selling more foals is larger than the revenue FCI,-D –0.200 GFP, 0.520 lost from the price decrease associated with EXR, SFEE,-, –0.019* –0.015” the expanded supply, The inverse of the price GGDP, 0.098 flexibility is a good approximation of the NR, 0.242* elasticity when the price elasticities of sub- * The estimated value is not significantly different than stitutes approach zero (Chen and Dharmar- zero. atne). This results in a price elasticity of thor- oughbred yearling demand of approximately native uses, and the long life of broodmares, –2.347 ( 1/–0.426), which is highly elastic. the high asset fixity associated with breeding The combination of inelastic supply and elas- thoroughbred mares, and the nature of invest- tic demand forces market adjustments to oc- ment in the industry, an inelastic supply re- cur primarily as price changes. sponse is expected. A comparison of estimated A comparison of the elasticity and flexibil- supply elasticities of registered foals across ity coefficients within each model identifies studies cannot be completed due to the lack of the relative importance of each variable’s im- comparable studies. In comparison to other pact on RFOAL, and P,, respectively. As char- livestock species with similar biological lags acteristic of an industry with a long adjust- in production, the supply of registered foals is ment process, the variable with the greatest more inelastic than the supply elasticity of impact on RFOAL, is the lagged endogenous dairy heifers with respect to milk price, 0.28 variable, RFOAL,_,, followed by MTB,.2. The (Chavas and Klemme), and the supply elastic- variable exerting the greatest overall impact ity of beef cow replacement heifers with re- on yearling price determination is PRSE,. For spect to calf price, 0.35 (Foster and Burt). each 190 change in PRSE,, P, changes 2.606%; Price flexibilities calculated from the in- this, in turn, would change RFOAL, by verse demand function identify an inflexible 0.3029Z0, given a time lag of two years. All price structure for all price-determining vari- other demand variable flexibilities are less ables with the exception of PRSE,, which has than one, with YTB,, GFP,, and YRL, having a price flexibility of 2.606. The thoroughbred flexibilities of approximately 0.50. yearling price flexibility coefficient with re- spect to purses estimated by Karungu, Reed, Equilibrium Condition and Tvedt is 1.28. Buzby and Jessup did not include purses as a determinant of yearling A recursive system of equations has three po- price. The difference in magnitude between tential intertemporal adjustment processes to the two price flexibility estimates is likely due endogenous changes in price or supply. If the to the difference in sales data. Karungu, Reed, slope of the supply response to a change in and Tvedt used select sale prices and consid- price is greater than the slope of the price re- ered purses only at one Kentucky race track. sponse to a change in supply, the system con- Select sales may be considered breeding stock verges to equilibrium in the absence of exog- sales for yearlings with the most fashionable enous shocks. If the slopes are equal, the pedigrees. By expanding the data to North system oscillates continuously. If the slope of American sales, a greater quality range is en- the supply response to a change in price is less countered where the primary use of a yearling than the slope of a price response to a change is for racing. This accounts for the difference in supply, the system diverges from equilib- Neibergs and Thalheimer: Thoroughbred Yearling Supply and Demand 429

Table 4. Long-Run Comparative Statics

Long-Run Supply (RFOAL) Long-Run Demand (P) Comparative Statics Comparative Statics

Comparative supply Long-Run Comparative Price Long-Run Static Responsea Elasticityb Static Responsea Flexibilityb

a RFOAL dP 4.673 1.734 5.591 1.854 a RPSE d PRSE d RFOAL 6P 20.761 1.495 – 10,082 –0.649 d MTB d klTB d RFOAL 3.924 0.357 4.695 0.381 J3YTB a YTB d RFOAL ap –39.351 –0.912 19.076 0.395 a FCI d FCI d RFOAL ap –1.763 –0.108’ 0.856 0.047’ d SFEE d SFEE d RFOAL 8P 1.260E–4 0.346 1.51OE–4 0.370 d GFP d GFP a RFOAL ap —1.474 –0.010’ —1.764 –0,010 a EXR d EXR d RFOAL ap 6.263 0.065 7.493 0.070 a GGDP d GGDP a RFOAL r3P 0.084 0.162’ 0.100 0.173” d NR 8 NR

‘ The result is the evaluation of the comparative static using the estimated coefficients from the supply and demand equations. b Elasticity and flexibility estimates are calculated at the mean. CEstimat~d coefficient is not significant. rium. The equilibrium condition is represented by substituting the supply model, equation ( 1), in equation (4), which indicates that the thor- into equation (3) takes into account the inter- oughbred yearling market would converge to action of supply and demand simultaneously. equilibrium in the absence of exogenous If a disequilibrating change occurs in the form shocks { 11/0.104I > 1–0.4861 } : of a variation in an exogenous variable, the initial equilibrium will be upset. Endogenous 1 ap variables (RFOAL and P) adjust relative to the (4) > - . L > Ip,l. aRFOAL, aYRL, rq new value of the exogenous variable, plus the ap,.z recursive adjustments between RFOAL and P until long-run equilibrium is reached. The long-run supply elasticities and price flexibil- Long-Run Comparative Statics ities are presented in table 4. The long-run supply coefficients are greater in magnitude The above model can be used to analyze eco- than the short-run coefficients, reflecting the nomic adjustments of the thoroughbred year- greater ability of the market to adjust over ling market over time by evaluating long-run time. The long-run price flexibilities are lower elasticities and/or by simulating market ad- in magnitude than the short-run flexibilities, justments in response to exogenous shocks. reflecting the feedback effects from the supply The derivation of the final form of the model side of the market. 430 Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, December 1997

percent 150 — s $ .- % 100 – — — z g ~ g 50 .5 3 0 0246 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 Year

Figure 2. Time path of adjustment in response to a 10?ZOincrease in average purses

Variables with a long-run elastic response Dynamic Adjustment to Equilibrium in on RFOAL are PRSE and MTB, with long-run Response to a Change in Purses elasticities of 1.734 and 1.495, respectively. Adjustments in RFOAL in response to exog- Purses were identified as the most influential enous shocks originate from adjusting the size variable in the thoroughbred yearling market. of the breeding herd. Changing the size of the Purses cause the greatest magnitude of adjust- breeding herd is a prolonged process due to ment in both the average yearling price and the biological lags in production, constraints the supply of registered foals. By generating associated with asset fixity, and thoroughbred positive economic incentives for all of its sec- registration requirements that prohibit the use tors, purses are potentially the most efficient of artificial insemination and embryo transfer policy instrument available to the thorough- technology. The only variable with a long-run bred industry, Purses have been used as a pol- price flexibility response greater than 1.0 is icy instrument for state breeder incentive pro- PRSE, with a long-run flexibility of 1,854. grams. They also are used by tracks as an This is a decrease from the short-run flexibility incentive for owners to improve the quality coefficient of 2.606, reflecting the feedback ef- and number of horses running at their meet. fects from supply adjustments in the market. An increase in purses has been shown to im- In the short run, price can respond without any prove wagering (Ali and Thalheimer; Thal- supply interaction because of the two-year heimer and Ali 1995a, b, c). biological lag in production. Figure 2 illustrates the dynamic adjustment The long-run adjustment in RFOAL is rel- toward equilibrium of a 10% increase in atively small. This indicates that growth in the PRSE, from its 1994 inflation-adjusted level of breeding industry is limited. The magnitude of $10,91O to $12,001. The purse level is in- the supply and price responses is a weighted creased in year 1, and is held constant at combination of the size of the change in the $12,001 throughout the simulation. Holding exogenous variable, the relative importance of all exogenous variables constant at their 1994 the exogenous variable to the market, the sup- levels and allowing endogenous variables ply response to yearling price, and the yearling RFOAL, and P, to respond iteratively results price response to supply. The high degree of in an initial equilibrium foal crop of 28,997, inelasticity of thoroughbred yearling supply in and an average yearling price of $33,179. Av- combination with the inelastic nature of each erage yearling price (P,) responds immediately of the supply model variables contributes to a to the purse increase, and due to the lack of long aggregate supply adjustment process. immediate supply response, P, adjusts to 141 ‘+0 Neibergs and Thalheimer: Thoroughbred Yearling Supply and Demand 431

Table 5. Dynamic Adjustment to a 109o Increase in Average Purses

Cumulative Cumulative Change in 7. Adjustment Change in 9. Adjustment supply of to Final Yearling to Final Year Foals (No.) Equilibrium Price ($1994) Equilibrium

1 0 0.0 8,575 140.6 2 0 0.0 0 140.6 3 892 17.5 0 140.6 4 781 32.8 –433 133.5 5 684 46.2 –379 127.3 6–10 1,862 82.8 –1,127 108.8 11–15 598 94.5 –365 102.8 16-35 281 100.0 –171 100.0 Total 5,098 6,100

of the long-run equilibrium and then declines importantly, the slow growth in RFOAL, will slowly as RFOAL increases in response to the result in limited growth in services demanded increase in P,. By year 10, Pf has adjusted to and supplied by the breeding sector. From the 108.8% of long-run equilibrium, and 102.85ZO racing sector’s perspective, the slow growth in of the adjustment to long-run equilibrium is RFOAL, will not alleviate the problem facing attained by year 15. In response to the 10% some race tracks of not having an adequate purse increase, the long-run equilibrium level supply of horses to maintain field size. i1While of P, increases from its initial level of $33,179 other factors are sure to impact the industry by $6,100, to result in a long-run equilibrium over this time horizon, the comparative statics of $39,279. illustrate the effect of purses on the industry Due to the biological lags of yearling pro- and their effectiveness as a policy instrument. duction, RFOAL, remains at the initial equilib- The adjustments to long-run equilibrium in rium level for two years as breeders respond RFOAL and P correspond to the response pre- to the new levels of P,. A rapid growth in dicted by the comparative static results pre- RFOAL, occurs from years 3 to 10, and ac- viously reported in table 4. For each dollar counts for 82.870 of the adjustment to long- increase in PRSE, the comparative statics pre- run equilibrium. Over 94% of the long-run ad- dicted a long-run increase of 4.673 and $5.591 justment is attained by year 15. Table 5 shows in RFOAL and P, respectively. The purse in- that in response to the 1090 purse increase, crease of $1,091 would then result in an in- RFOAL increases from its initial level of crease in long-run equilibrium of 5,098 in 28,997 by 5,098, to result in a long-run equi- RFOAL (a 17.6% increase over initial equilib- librium of 34,095. rium), and an increase in P of $6,100 (an in- Table 5 illustrates the expected rapid year- crease of 18.490 over initial equilibrium). ling price adjustment in response to a 1070 in- crease in the average purse per race, In this The Impact of Federal Tax Policy on the example, it takes five years to attain 46% of Market the long-run adjustment, and an additional 10 years to attain 94% of the long-run adjustment The Tax Reform Act of 1986 was a compre- in the supply of foals in response to the purse hensive overhaul of the federal income tax increase initiated in year 1. system. The act significantly changed incen- These results illustrate the rapid price ad- tives for investing by substantially reducing justment in response to purses and the oppor- tunity for breeders to increase marginal reve- I I Field size is the number of horses in an individ- nue by increasing supply. But perhaps more ual race. 432 Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, December 1997

Table 6. Estimated Impact of Federal Tax Policy on the Thoroughbred Market, 1985–94

Impact on Impact on Estimated P, Estimated RFOAL Change in Change in Due to Change in Change in Due to Year P, YTB1 YTB, RFOAL, MTB,., MTB,-Z

1985 –6,605 141 927 1,185 91 331 1986 – 15,393 –324 –2,136 864 126 458 1987 2,006 –763 –5 ,034 –376 108 392 1988 –3,479 31 204 –1,701 –60 –218 1989 –3,078 147 971 – 1,020 –648 –2,357 1990 –2,661 172 1,138 –4,103 –115 –418 1991 –6,364 143 941 –2,294 118 430 1992 –3,755 210 1,384 –3,542 139 504 1993 –571 110 725 –1,657 115 417 1994 2,182 100 659 – 1,900 169 612

marginal income tax rates, and it broadened significant decrease in RFOAL, from the the tax base by eliminating many of the ex- change in MTB,-2 was not felt until 1989 and clusions, deductions, and credits introduced 1990 due to the biological lags of production. into the tax code over the years. The key el- ements of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 af- Conclusions fecting the thoroughbred market included re- duced marginal tax rates, changed depreciation This study analyzed factors impacting price schedules, the elimination of capital gains, and determination in the thoroughbred yearling the reduced ability to write off passive losses. market in North America. Yearling prices can The Tax Reform Act of 1986 is cited by many be used as an indicator of horse values and the thoroughbred market analysts as contributing breeding sector’s financial condition. Given to the rapid decline in yearling price from the lagged time response associated with pro- 1986 to 1992 (Karungu, Reed, and Tvedt; ducing a yearling from the production decision Buzby and Jessup). to breed a mare to the date of sale, a recursive Federal tax policy is important to the thor- model specification was applied to the year- oughbred market, because taxes affect both the ling market. This resulted in estimating a dy- marginal cost of breeding decisions and the namic supply of registered foals equation, and marginal revenue of yearling investment de- an inverse demand equation of average year- cisions. Taxes are second in importance to ling price. Model results indicate that the mar- purses when evaluating market-impacting ket structure for thoroughbred yearlings is variables. The long-run elasticity of MTB and characterized by inelastic supply and elastic YTB on RFOAL is 1.495 and 0.357, respec- demand with market adjustments occurring tive y (table 4). The long-run flexibility of primarily as price changes. The supply of reg- MTB and YTB on P is –0.649 and 0.381, re- istered foals is found to have a more inelastic spectively. supply structure than livestock commodities Table 6 identifies the estimated impact to with comparable biological production lags. the thoroughbred market of the Tax Reform Thk is primarily due to the asset fixity asso- Act of 1986 through YTB, and MTB,.2. Table ciated with thoroughbred investments and the 6 indicates that the Tax Reform Act of 1986 willingness of many yearling breeders and had substantial impacts on P, and RFOAL,. An buyers to subsidize their yearling investments initial impact of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 through periods of nonprofitability. on Pt was –$2, 136 in 1986, while a negative Under static conditions, the model con- impact of – $5,034 was estimated for 1987. A verges to an equilibrium. Yearling prices re- IVeibergs and Thalheimer: Thoroughbred Yearling Supply and Demand 433

spend immediately to exogenous shocks, but ciably from 8.95 at the start of the study pe- the supply of foals has a prolonged adjustment riod in 1960 to 8.31 at the end of the study process. In response to a change in average period in 1994. The level of growth in field purses, average yearling price increases im- size ties all sectors of the industry together in mediately to 141% of its equilibrium value, a slow growth cycle. Field size determines the while supply response takes five years to number of betting combinations available in a achieve 46!Z0 of the equilibrium adjustment, race. As field size increases, “handle,” or the and by the end of 10 years, 83 ?lo of the equi- amount bet per race, is likely to increase. librium adjustment occurs. It takes approxi- When handle increases, the potential payoff to mately 35 years to achieve full equilibrium winning bettors, purses, and track revenues supply adjustment from a change in purse lev- also increase. However, due to the inelastic na- els. This market structure creates the oppor- ture of supply, field size will be slow to in- tunity for yearling breeders and buyers with crease, and some race tracks will continue to predictive foresight on industry trends to take have difficulty maintaining the field size of advantage of market fluctuations, due to im- their races, perpetuating a slow growth cycle mediate price response and a prolonged supply in the industry. adjustment process. The inelastic supply struc- The role of taxes is important for both buy- ture for both short- and long-run outlooks in- ers and breeders. As tax benefits increase, buy- dicates there will be limited growth in services ers are willing to pay more for yearlings, and demanded and supplied by the breeding sector. breeders are willing to supply more yearlings. But perhaps more importantly, the resulting Foreign purchases were found in this study to slow growth in the supply of foals reflects the have a significant but inelastic impact on year- need for long-term planning when considering ling price, indicating that on a national basis, policy factors, such as purses, which may be the relative importance of foreign purchases is changed immediately through policy deci- secondary in importance to domestic policies sions. affecting purses and taxes. The potential impacts to breeders and buy- The model specification for this study was ers from an evolving thoroughbred market are limited to the yearling market. Much work re- directly linked to trends in purses. Purses are mains to be done in the analysis of the thor- currently increasing primarily from the expan- oughbred market. The segregation of the mar- sion in simulcasting, and in some racing juris- ket into quality groups would add to the dictions through the subsidization of purses precision and usefulness of the results. The ex- from alternative gaming revenues. Recently, pansion of the yearling market model into an gross purses have been increasing slightly, but industry-level model that directly incorporates due to the declining number of live races, the the impacts of competition from alternative average purse per race has been increasing be- gaming and its flow-through effect on purses tween 590 and 109ZOper year. Purses are im- and the thoroughbred yearling market would portant to the industry because they create an be useful in the policy arena. Research is also elastic response in both the short and long run needed to identify the exact relationships be- and for both the supply of foals and average tween simulcasting, its impact on live racing yearling price. This indicates that policies tar- opportunities, and its impact on purses. Final- geting purse augmentation will be of the great- ly, the regionalization of market analysis is est benefit to the industry. needed to develop industry information based The decline in the number of live races is on local conditions facing the thoroughbred not viewed in the market as a statistically sig- industry. nificant variable. The decline in live races is matched with a decline in the supply of foals, References so the opportunity for yearling buyers to run their horses in races has not been constrained. Ali, M.M., and R. Thalheimer. “Transportation The average field size has not changed appre- Costs and Product Demand: Wagering on Pari- 434 Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, December 1997

mutuel Horse Racing,” Appl. Econ. 29(1997): The Jockey Club. 1995 Fact Book: A Guide to the 529–42. Thoroughbred Industry in North America. New The Blood-Horse. Annual Auction Review. Lexing- York: The Jockey Club, 1995. ton KY The Blood-Horse, Inc. Various issues, Karungu, l?, M. Reed, and D. Tvedt. “Macroeco- 1960–94. nomic Factors and the Thoroughbred Industry. ” —. Annual Stallion Register. Lexington KY J. Agr. and Appl. Econ. 25(1993): 165–73. The Blood-Horse, Inc. Various issues, 1960–94. Lawrence, R.G, “All About Purses. ” Thorough- Buzby, J.C., and E.L. Jessup. “The Relative Impact bred Times. Various issues, of Macroeconomic and Yearling-Specific Vari- —. “An Econometric Analysis of Changes in ables in Determining Thoroughbred Yearling Quarter Horse Prices, 1950 Through 1967.” Price,” Appl, Econ. 26(1994): 1–8. Unpub. Ph.D. dissertation, Texas A&M Univer- Chavas, J,F!, and R. Klemme. “Aggregate Milk sity, College Station, 1968. Supply Response and Investment Behavior on Marfels, C. “Casino Gaming. ” The Structure of U.S. Dairy Farms. ” Amer. J, Agr. Econ. American Industry, eds,, W. Adams and J. 68(1986):55–66. Brock. Englewood Cliffs NJ: Prentice-Hall, Chen, D. T., and G.S. Dharmaratne. “Farm Price Inc., 1995. Response to Supply Shocks: A Comparison of Pindyck, R. S., and D.L. Rubinfeld. Economic il40d- Alternative Inverse Demand Structural Mod- els and Economic Forecasts, 3rd ed. New York: els.” Rev. Agr. Econ, 18(1996): 137–46. McGraw-Hill, Inc., 1991. Christiansen, E.M., and W.E. Cummings. “The Rosen, S. “Dynamic Animal Economics. ” Amer. J. United States 1994 Gross Annual Wager, ” Zn- Agr. Econ. 69(1987):547–57. ternat. Gaming and Wagering Bus. (1 August Rosen, S., K.M. Murphy, and J.A. Scheinkman. 1996):55–94, “Cattle Cycles,” J. Polit. Econ. 102(1994): Citibase Macroeconomic Database. Dexter MI: 468–92. FAME Information Services, 1994. Simmons, S.A., and R. Sharp. “State Lotteries’ Ef- Commerce Clearing House, Inc., Tax Law Editors, fects on Thoroughbred Horse Racing, ” J. Pol- Standard Federal Tax Reports: 1993 Depreci- icy Analysis and Manage. 6( 1987):446–48. ation Guide. Chicago IL: Commerce Clearing Stein, J.L. “Cobwebs, Rational Expectations, and House, Inc., 1993. Futures Markets. ” Rev. Econ. and Statis. Ezekiel, M. “The Cobweb Theorem.” Quart. J. 74(1992):127–34. Econ. 52(1938):225–80. Thalheimer, R,, and M.M. Ali. “The Demand for Foster, K.A., and O.R. Burt. “A Dynamic Model Parimutuel Horse Race Wagering and Atten- of Investment in the U.S. Beef-Cattle Industry. ” dance.” Manage. Sci. 41 (1995a): 129–43. J. Bus. and Econ. Statis. 11(1992):419–26. —. “Exotic Betting Opportunities, Pricing Gulley, O. D., and EA. Scott. “Lottery Effects on Policies, and the Demand for Parimutuel Horse Parimutuel Tax Revenues, ” National Tax J. Race Wagering.” Appl. Econ. 27(1995b):689– 42(1989):89–93. 703. Hall, R., and D. Jorgenson, “Tax Policy and In- —. “Intertrack Wagering and the Demand for vestment Behavior. ” Amer. Econ. Rev. Parimutuel Horse Racing. ” J. Econ. and Bus. 57(1967):391–414. 74(1995 c):369–83. Hollingsworth, K. “More for Less.” Annual Auc- U.S. Department of Agriculture, Statistical Report- tion Review, 1984. Lexington KY The Blood- ing Service. Agricultural Statistics. Washington Horse, Inc., 1984. DC: Government Printing Office. Various is- Irwin, S.H., and C.S. Thraen. “Rational Expecta- sues, 1960–94. tions in Agriculture? A Review of the Issues Whipple, G. D., and D.J. Menkhaus. “Supply Re- and the Evidence.” Rev. Agr. Econ. 16(1994): sponse in the U.S. Sheep Industry. ” Amer. J. 133–58. Agr. Econ. 71(1989): 126–35. Neibergs and Thalheimer: Thoroughbred Yearling Supply and Demand 435

Appendix

Table Al. Summary Statistics of Variables in Model System, 1960–94

Variable Mean Median Std. Dev. Minimum Maximum

RFOAL, 32,059 30,636 12,009 12,901 51,293 RFOAL,. , 31,417 28,809 12,455 12,240 51,293 P, 35,882 31,857 11,089 24,383 65,015 P,_2 35,923 31,587 11,051 24,383 65,015 NR, 61,759 68,822 13,314 37,661 82,726 FCIt_z 743 671 353 335 1,244 YTB, 2,915 3,016 914 1,630 4,569 MTB,.Z 2,308 2,424 711 1,401 3,732 SFEE,.Z 1,973 2,021 635 1,662 3,705 PRSE, 11,899 11,957 699 10,482 13,031 GFP, 87,950,627 86,911,825 47,887,797 22,361,185 182,238,233 EXR, 212 212 50 130 281 GGDP, 335 331 127 91 588

Notes: All monetary data have been deflated by the consumer price index, where 1994 = 100. GFF’, summary statistics are calculated using nonzero data from 1973–94.