<<

Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

Partial differential equation models in macroeconomics

Yves Achdou, Francisco J. Buera, Jean-Michel Lasry, Pierre-Louis Lions and Benjamin Moll

Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 2014 372, 20130397, published 6 October 2014

References This article cites 51 articles, 8 of which can be accessed free http://rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org/content/372/2028/201303 97.full.html#ref-list-1

Article cited in: http://rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org/content/372/2028/20130397.full. html#related-urls Subject collections Articles on similar topics can be found in the following collections

applied mathematics (148 articles) Receive free email alerts when new articles cite this article - sign up Email alerting service in the box at the top right-hand corner of the article or click here

To subscribe to Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A go to: http://rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org/subscriptions Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014 Partial differential equation models in macroeconomics Yves Achdou1,FranciscoJ.Buera2, Jean-Michel Lasry3, Pierre-Louis Lions4 and Benjamin Moll5 rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org 1Université Paris Diderot, Sorbonne Paris Cité, Laboratoire Jacques-Louis Lions, Paris, France 2Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Chicago, IL 60604, USA 3Department of Mathematics, University Dauphine, 75017 Paris, Review France 4Collège de France, 75005 Paris France Cite this article: Achdou Y, Buera FJ, Lasry 5 J-M, Lions P-L, Moll B. 2014 Partial differential Department of Economics, , Princeton, NJ equation models in macroeconomics. Phil. 08544, USA Trans. R. Soc. A 372: 20130397. http://dx.doi.org/10.1098/rsta.2013.0397 The purpose of this article is to get mathematicians interested in studying a number of partial differential equations (PDEs) that naturally arise One contribution of 13 to a Theme Issue in macroeconomics. These PDEs come from models ‘Partial differential equation models designed to study some of the most important in the socio-economic sciences’. questions in economics. At the same time, they are highly interesting for mathematicians because their structure is often quite difficult. We present a number of examples of such PDEs, discuss what is known Subject Areas: about their properties, and list some open questions applied mathematics for future research.

Keywords: heterogeneous agents, mean field games, 1. Introduction income and wealth distribution, firm size Macroeconomics is the study of large economic systems. distribution Most commonly, this system is the economy of a country. But, it may also be a more complex system such as the world as a whole, comprising a large Author for correspondence: number of interacting smaller geographical regions. Benjamin Moll Macroeconomics is concerned with some of the most e-mail: [email protected] important questions in economics, for example: what causes recessions and what should be done about them? Why are some countries so much poorer than others? Traditionally, macroeconomic theory has focused on studying systems of difference equations or ordinary differential equations describing the evolution of a relatively small number of macroeconomic aggregates. These systems are typically derived from the optimal control problem of a ‘representative agent’. In the past 30 years, however, macroeconomics has seen the development of theories that explicitly model the

2014 The Author(s) Published by the Royal Society. All rights reserved. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

equilibrium interaction of heterogeneous agents, e.g. heterogeneous consumers, workers and 2 firms (see, in particular, the early contributions of Bewley [1], Aiyagari [2], Huggett [3]and rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Hopenhayn [4])...... The development of these theories opens up the study of a number of important questions: why are income and wealth so unequally distributed? How is inequality affected by aggregate economic conditions? Is there a trade-off between inequality and economic growth? What are the forces that lead to the concentration of economic activity in a few very large firms? And why do instabilities in the financial sector seem to matter so much for the macroeconomy? Heterogeneous agent models are usually set in discrete time. While they are workhorses of modern macroeconomics, relatively little is known about their theoretical properties and they often prove difficult to compute. To make progress, some recent papers have therefore studied continuous time versions of such models. Our paper reviews this literature. Macroeconomic Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A models with heterogeneous agents share a common mathematical structure which, in continuous time, can be summarized by a system of coupled nonlinear partial differential equations (PDEs): (i) a Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman (HJB) equation describing the optimal control problem of a single atomistic individual and (ii) an equation describing the evolution of the distribution of a vector of individual state variables in the population (such as a Fokker–Planck equation, Fisher–KPP equation or Boltzmann equation).1 While plenty is known about the properties of each type of 20130397 : 372 equation individually, our understanding of the coupled system is much more limited. Lasry & Lions [5–7] and Lions [8] have termed such a system a ‘mean field game’ and obtained some theoretical characterizations for special cases, but many open questions remain. For useful reference on mean field games, one can see for example Bardi [9], Guéant [10], Guéant et al. [11], Gomes et al. [12] and Cardaliaguet [13]. The purpose of this article is to present important examples of these systems of PDEs that arise naturally in macroeconomics, to discuss what is known about their properties, and to highlight some directions for future research. In §2, we present a model describing an economy consisting of a continuum of heterogeneous individuals that face income shocks and can trade a risk-free bond that is in zero net supply. This is the simplest model to illustrate the basic structure of heterogeneous agent frameworks used in macroeconomics, and it is the building block of many models studying the interaction between macroeconomic aggregates and the distribution of income and wealth. In §3, we review PDEs that have been used to describe the distribution of the many economic variables that obey power laws, for example, city and firm size, wealth and executive compensation. One building block of all of these models is the Fokker–Planck equation for a geometric Brownian motion. This equation is then combined with a model of exit and entry, for instance taking the form of a variational inequality of the obstacle type, derived from an optimal stopping time problem. In §4, we present a class of models describing processes of economic growth owing to experimentation and knowledge diffusion, or alternatively the percolation of information in financial markets. These models generate richer, more non-local dynamics, that give rise to Fisher–KPP- or Boltzmann-type equations. In §5, we introduce a class of models that is substantially more complicated than those in the preceding sections: models with ‘aggregate shocks’ designed to study business cycle fluctuations. These theories have the property that macroeconomic aggregates, including the distribution of individual states, are stochastic variables rather than just varying deterministically as in the models studied thus far. This creates the difficulty that the distribution—an infinite- dimensional object—has to be included in the state space of the individual optimal control problem. The resulting optimal control problem is no longer a standard HJB equation but instead an ‘HJB equation in the space of density functions’, a very challenging object mathematically. We present the most canonical version of such a theory: the model in §2 but now with aggregate income shocks. But, in principle, any of the theories in the preceding sections could be enriched

1Heterogeneous agent models used in macroeconomics typically make the assumption that individuals have identical preferences (even though they are heterogeneous in other dimensions). It is for this reason that only two equations are sufficient for summarizing such economies. Models with heterogeneous preferences can be considered but they involve more equations. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

by introducing such aggregate shocks. Finally, in §6, we note that also models with a finite 3 number of agents, rather than a continuum as in the preceding sections, are of interest in certain rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org macroeconomic applications. We present a model of firm dynamics in an oligopolistic industry ...... which takes the form of a differential game. Space limitations have forced us to leave out other important areas of macroeconomics and economics more broadly where PDEs, and continuous time methods in general, have played an important role in recent years. A good example is the large literature studying the design of optimal dynamic contracts and policies. See for example the recent work by Sannikov [14], Williams [15] and Farhi & Werning [16]. Another area is given by models of the labour market. See for example the recent contribution by Alvarez & Shimer [17] and the review by Lentz & Mortensen [18]. Finally, throughout this paper, we focus on equilibrium allocations in which individuals take as given the actions of others rather than coordinating with them. As a result, Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A these equilibrium allocations are in general suboptimal from the point of view of society as a whole.2 Optimal allocations in heterogeneous agent models can be analysed along the lines of Nuño [19] and Lucas & Moll [20].

2. Income and wealth distribution 20130397 : 372 The discrete time model of Aiyagari [2], Bewley [1] and Huggett [3] is one of the workhorses of modern macroeconomics. This model captures in a relatively parsimonious way the evolution of the income and wealth distribution and its effect on macroeconomic aggregates. It is a natural framework to study the effect of various policies and institutions on inequality. A huge number of problems in macroeconomics have a similar structure and so this is a particularly useful starting point. The simplest formulation of the model is due to Huggett [3] and we here present a continuous time formulation of Huggett’s model presented in Achdou et al. [21].3 There is a continuum of infinitely lived households that are heterogeneous in their wealth a and their income z. Households solve the following optimization problem:  ∞ −ρ max E e tu(c )dt s.t. { } 0 t ct 0

dat = (zt + r(t)at − ct)dt

dzt = μ(zt)dt + σ (zt)dWt

at ≥ a. Households have utility functions u(c) over consumption c that are strictly increasing and strictly −γ concave (e.g. u(c) = c1 /(1 − γ ), γ>0) and they maximize the present discounted value of utility from consumption, discounted at rate ρ. Households can borrow and save at an interest rate r(t) which is determined in equilibrium and they optimally choose how to split their total income zt + r(t)at between consumption and saving. Their income evolves exogenously according ¯ to a diffusion process dzt = μ(zt)dt + σ (zt)dWt in a closed interval [z, z] (it is reflected at the boundaries if it ever reaches them). Importantly, there is a state constraint a ≥ a for some scalar −∞ < a ≤ 0. This state constraint has the economic interpretation of a borrowing constraint,e.g.if a = 0 households can only save and cannot borrow at all. The interest rate r(t) must be such that the following equilibrium condition is satisfied: ag(a, z, t)da dz = 0, where g(a, z, t) denotes the cross-sectional distribution of households with wealth a and income z at time t. The interpretation of this equilibrium condition is as follows: wealth a here takes the form of bonds, and the equilibrium interest rate r is such that bonds are in zero net supply.Thatis, for every dollar borrowed, there is someone else who saves a dollar.

2In the sense of the ‘Pareto optimality’ criterion typically used in economics: there exists an alternative allocation such that all individuals in the economy are weakly better off. 3Also see Bayer & Waelde [22,23] who explore a similar model. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

v The equilibrium can be characterized in terms of an HJB equation for the value function 4 and a Fokker–Planck equation for the density of households g.Inastationary equilibrium, the rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org unknown functions v and g and the unknown scalar r satisfy the following system of coupled ...... PDEs (stationary mean field game) on (a, ∞) × (z, z¯):

1 2 σ (z)∂zzv + μ(z)∂zv + (z + ra)∂av + H(∂av) − ρv = 0, (2.1) 2

1 2 − ∂zz(σ (z)g) + ∂z(μ(z)g) + ∂a((z + ra)g) + ∂a(∂pH(∂av)g) = 0, (2.2)  2 g(a, z)da dz = 1, g ≥ 0 (2.3)  and ag(a, z)da dz = 0, (2.4) Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A

where the Hamiltonian H is given by

H(p) = max(−pc + u(c)). (2.5) c≥0 20130397 : 372 The function v satisfies a state constraint boundary condition at a = a and Neumann boundary conditions at z = z and z = z¯. In general, the boundary value problem including the Bellman equation (2.1) and the boundary condition has to be understood in the sense of viscosity (see Bardi & Capuzzo [24], Crandall et al. [25], Barles [26]), whereas the boundary problem with the Fokker–Planck equation (2.3) is set in the sense of distributions. An important issue is to check that (2.1) actually yields an optimal control (verification theorem): this is a direct application of Itô’s formula if v is smooth enough; for general viscosity solutions, one may apply the results of Bouchard & Touzi [27]andTouzi[28] (this has not been done yet). With well chosen initial and terminal conditions, solutions to the HJB equation (2.1) are expected to be smooth and we therefore look for such smooth solutions. If v is indeed smooth, the state constraint boundary condition can be shown to imply

(z + ra)λ + H(λ) ≥ (w + ra)∂av(a, z) + H(∂av(a, z)) ∀λ ≥ ∂av(a, z)

or equivalently

z + ra + ∂pH(∂av) ≥ 0, a = a (2.6)

so that the trajectory of a points towards the interior of the state space. Finally, note that the interest rate r—which is determined by the equilibrium condition (2.4)—is the only variable through which the distribution g enters the HJB equation (2.1). The time-dependent analogue of (2.1)–(2.4) is also of interest. In the time-dependent equilibrium, the unknown functions v and g satisfy the following system of coupled PDEs (time-dependent mean field game) on (a, ∞) × (z, z¯) × (0, T):

1 2 ∂tv + σ (z)∂zzv + μ(z)∂zv + (z + r(t)a)∂av + H(∂av) − ρv = 0, (2.7) 2

1 2 ∂tg − ∂zz(σ (z)g) + ∂z(μ(z)g) + ∂a((z + r(t)a)g) + ∂a(∂pH(∂av)g) = 0, (2.8)  2 g(a, z, t)da dz = 1, g ≥ 0 (2.9)  and ag(a, z, t)da dz = 0, (2.10)

where the Hamiltonian H is given by (2.5). The density g satisfies the initial condition g(a, z,0)= v g0(a, z). For the terminal condition for the value function , we generally take T large and impose v(a, z, T) = v∞(a, z), where v∞ is the stationary value function, i.e. the solution to the stationary Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

4 v problem (2.1)–(2.4). The function also still satisfies the state constraint boundary condition 5 (2.6) and Neumann boundary conditions at z = z and z = z¯. rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org ...... (a) Theoretical results Achdou et al. [21] have analysed some theoretical properties of both the time-varying and stationary problems. We here briefly review the (rather incomplete) theoretical knowledge of these problems, followed by a list of open questions regarding in particular the well-posedness of the problems. Achdou et al. [21] first analyse the stationary problem (2.1)–(2.4) under the additional assumption that the state constraint satisfies a > −z/r. They show that under this assumption the state constraint (2.6) binds for low enough income z, that is, the borrowing

constraint is ‘tight’. Intuitively, individuals with low income z would like to borrow but cannot if Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A their wealth is already at a. Of particular interest is the stationary saving policy function

s(a, z) = z + ra + ∂pH(∂av(a, z)), that is the optimally chosen drift of wealth a, and the behaviour of the implied stationary distribution g. Importantly, one can show that the expansion of the function s around a satisfies

∗ ∗ 20130397 : 372 the following property: there exists z with z < z < z¯ such that  ¯ ¯ ∗ s(a, z) ∼−sz a − a, sz > 0, z ≤ z ≤ z , (2.11) meaning that in particular the derivative ∂as becomes unbounded when we let a go to a. It then follows from this property that the stationary distribution g is unbounded and has a Dirac mass ∗ at a = a for z ≤ z . The existence of a Dirac mass in the stationary version of (2.7)–(2.10) of course complicates the mathematics substantially. At the same time, it is also one of the economically most interesting predictions of the model. What fraction of individuals in an economy such as that of the USA are borrowing constrained and how we would expect this to change when various features of the environment (say the stochastic process for z) change is an important question with wide-reaching policy implications. That interesting economics and challenging mathematics go hand in hand is one of the main themes of this paper. Achdou et al. [21] prove the existence of a solution to (2.1)–(2.4), i.e. of a stationary equilibrium. v The key step in the proof is to analyse solutions and g to (2.1)–(2.3) for given r and to show that the corresponding first moment of g, m(r) = ag(a, z)da dz, goes to a as r →−∞and that it becomes unbounded as we take r to ρ−. It follows from this that there exists an r such that (2.4) holds. Currently, open theoretical questions are

1. Uniqueness of a solution to (2.1)–(2.4), i.e. of a stationary equilibrium. 2. Existence of a solution to (2.7)–(2.10), i.e. of a time-dependent equilibrium. 3. Uniqueness of a solution to (2.7)–(2.10), i.e. of a time-dependent equilibrium.

The main difficulty in the first question, uniqueness of a stationary solution, lies in showing that (or finding conditions under which) the first moment of g, m(r), is monotone as a function of r. It should also be noted that non-uniqueness is a very real possibility in many equilibrium models arising in economics, and that a better understanding of the conditions under which non-uniqueness can arise is equally interesting to economists as proving uniqueness.

(b) Numerical methods Achdou et al. [21] have also developed numerical methods for solving both the stationary and time-dependent problems, based on Achdou & Capuzzo-Dolcetta [29] and Achdou [30]. Figure 1 plots the optimal stationary saving policy function s and the implied distribution

4In principle, the stationary mean-field game (2.1)–(2.4) may not have a unique solution, and hence v∞ may not be uniquely defined. As we discuss in more detail below, we have not found any examples of such non-uniqueness in our numerical simulations. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

(a)(b) 6 rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org 0.6 0.25 ...... 0.4 0.20 0.2 0 0.15 −0.2 0.10 −0.4 density g ( a , z ) savings s ( a , z ) savings −0.6 0.05 −0.8 0 0 1.5 0 1.5 5 2 10 1.0 4 1.0 wealth, a15 wealth, a 6 20 income, z 25 0.5 8 0.5 income, z

Figure 1. Numerical solution to stationary equilibrium (2.7)–(2.10). (a) Saving as function of income and wealth. Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A (b) Distribution of income and wealth. (Online version in colour.)

−γ g. These are computed under the assumption that u in (2.5) is given by u(c) = c1 /(1 − γ ) with γ = 2. In figure 1, one can see that s satisfies (2.11) and g has a Dirac mass for low 20130397 : 372 z (the numerical method computes discretized versions of the equations, so the Dirac mass corresponds to a finite density). Time-dependent solutions can be computed in a similar fashion and the evolution of the distribution over time can be visualized as ‘movies’ (e.g. http://www.princeton.edu/∼moll/aiyagari.mov). An interesting exercise is to ‘calibrate’ this model and to compare the resulting distribution of wealth illustrated in figure 1 with that in empirical data for developed countries. In the data, wealth is extremely unequally distributed. For example, in the USA, the top 1% richest individuals own around 35% of aggregate wealth [31,32]. In contrast, it turns out that the degree of wealth inequality generated by this model is substantially smaller than the one observed in the data. This observation was first made by Aiyagari [2]. This has motivated the study of richer models of individual heterogeneity and wealth accumulation. Examples include models in which individuals have access to different returns to their savings [31,33], for instance because they run private enterprises in a world with imperfect capital markets [34–36], and models in which individuals have different preferences for current and future consumption [37]. A close interplay between numerical solutions of calibrated models and data is a central theme in the macroeconomic literature reviewed in this paper (and which we do not discuss in more detail due to space limitations).

3. Models of power laws One of the most ubiquitous regularities in empirical work in economics and finance is that the empirical distribution of many variables can well be approximated by a power law. Examples are the distributions of income and wealth, of the size of cities and firms, stock market returns, trading volume and executive pay. See Gabaix [38], who reviewed the theoretical and empirical literature on power laws. Gabaix [39] has proposed a simple explanation of power law phenomena that naturally leads to PDEs: many variables follow geometric Brownian motions, combined with a ‘small friction’ such as a minimum size in the form of a reflecting barrier or small ‘death shocks’. The following material is based on Gabaix [38]. Consider a stochastic process

dzt =¯μ dt +¯σ dWt, (3.1) zt where μ<¯ 0andσ>¯ 0 are scalars. For sake of concreteness, consider the case where z represents the size or productivity of a firm, and we are interested in the firm size distribution. But of course z could be city size or any other variable as well. Further assume that there is a minimum firm Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

size zmin in the form of a reflecting barrier (other mechanisms are possible as well and we explore 7 some below). The stationary firm size distribution f satisfies the Fokker–Planck equation rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org ...... 1 ∂ σ¯ 2 2 − ∂ μ¯ = 2 zz( z f ) z( zf ) 0 (3.2) and  f (z)dz = 1, f ≥ 0, (3.3)

∞ on (zmin, ), with boundary condition

1 ∂ σ¯ 2 2 −¯μ = = 2 z( z f ) zf 0, z zmin. Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A

It is easy to see that the solution to (3.2) is

ζ −ζ− 2μ¯ f (z) = ζ z z 1, ζ = 1 − , (3.4) min σ¯ 2 that is, a power law with exponent ζ>1. This basic idea can be generalized in a number of 20130397 : 372 ways and applied in a number of different contexts and we here review some of these other applications.

(a) Entry, exit and firm size distribution An important paper by Luttmer [40] has applied the same logic to the question why the size distribution of firms follows a power law. We here review a simplified version of Luttmer’s model. The problem also corresponds to a continuous time formulation of that originally studied by Hopenhayn [4]. Each firm has a profit function π(z, m[f ]) which is strictly increasing in its own productivity z, and strictly decreasing in a geometric average of all other firms’ productivities5   1/θ θ m[f ] = z f (z)dz , θ>0.

The value of a firm is the present discounted value of profits, discounted at rate ρ. Firms’ productivity and hence profits evolve according to the stochastic process dzt = μ(zt)dt + σ (zt)dWt which we later specialize to (3.1), following Luttmer [40]. Firms have only one choice: whether to remain active or whether to exit the industry. If a firm exits the industry, it obtains a scrap value ψ, but it can never re-enter the industry. When firms exit, they mechanically get replaced by a group of entrants of equal mass whose initial productivity is given by some finite and positive z0. Firms therefore solve a stopping time problem

 τ  v = E −ρtπ + −ρτ ψ (z0) maxτ 0 e (zt, m[f ]) dt e , 0

dzt = μ(zt)dt + σ (zt)dWt.

5 / −γ γ> This dependence is motivated as follows. Firms face demand functions (p(z) P) , 1wherep(z)isthepriceoffirmz and −γ / −γ P is a ‘price index’ P = ( p(z)1 f (z)dz)1 (1 ). This specification of the demand function is standard in economics (so-called isoelastic demand obtained from Spence–Dixit–Stiglitz preferences). Each firm’s profit function is given by

 −γ  −γ p 1 p γ − −γ γ γ π = max p − = (p¯ − 1)z 1p¯ P , p¯ = p P z P γ − 1  γ − / −γ γ − −γ and the optimal price is p(z) = p¯/z,sothatP = p¯( z 1f (z)dz)1 (1 ) and hence π(z, m[f ]) = (p¯ − 1)z 1(m[f ]) with θ = γ − 1. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

v The value function (z) can be characterized by a variational inequality of the obstacle type [24,41]. 8 As before the density of firms f satisfies a Fokker–Planck equation. In the stationary version of rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org this problem, the unknown functions v and f satisfy ......

1 2 min ρv − σ (z)∂zzv − μ(z)∂zv − π(z, m[f ]), v − ψ = 0, (3.5) 2

1 2 ∂zz(σ (z)f ) − ∂z(μ(z)f ) = 0, (3.6) 2 f (z)dz = 1, f ≥ 0 (3.7)   1/θ = θ and m[f ] z f (z)dz (3.8) Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A

R+ 6 on . The variational inequality (3.5) now determines an endogenous threshold zmin at which firms exit. Because firms exit immediately when their productivity reaches zmin, f satisfies = μ = the boundary condition f (zmin) 0. Luttmer [40] shows that under the assumption that (z) μ¯ z, σ (z) = σ z with μ<¯ 0andσ>¯ 0(i.e.zt follows (3.1)) and some other appropriately chosen assumption (e.g. that π is a power function with appropriately chosen exponents), the system 20130397 : 372 > can be solved explicitly. He further shows that, for z z0, the stationary distribution satisfies −ζ− f (z) = cz 1 for some constant c > 0 and with ζ given by the same formula as in (3.4). The model of firm dynamics considered here therefore generates the empirical regularity that the right tail of the firm size distribution follows a power law. While the case in which zt follows a geometric Brownian motion (3.1) is very well understood, a natural question is what the exit decision and the firm size distribution look like for more general stochastic processes and perhaps also more general interdependencies between firms m[f ]. For this more general set-up, open questions are

1. Existence and uniqueness of a stationary equilibrium, i.e. solutions to (3.5)–(3.8). 2. Existence and uniqueness of the time-dependent counterpart. 3. Development of numerical methods for solving both stationary and time-dependent equilibria.

Stokey [42] discusses other examples of stopping time problems in economics, many of them describing richer versions of the model of firm dynamics introduced in this section. This includes the problem of firms that set their price subjected to an adjustment cost. These models are important in macroeconomics, because the existence of frictions to the adjustment of prices is the main motivation for the use of monetary policy to stabilize business cycle fluctuations. Recent examples are given by Golosov & Lucas [43] and Alvarez & Lippi [44].

(b) Other applications of theories of power laws The ideas presented in the preceding two sections have been used to understand the emergence of power laws in a number of different contexts. For example, Benhabib et al. [31] and in particular Benhabib et al. [33] develop models of the wealth distribution whose mathematical structure is quite similar to the one presented here. Similarly, Jones [45] applies the same insights into the question why the top of the income distribution (the infamous ‘one percent’) can be well described by a power law.

6Equation (3.5) can also be written somewhat more intuitively as

ρv − 1 σ 2(z)∂ v − μ(z)∂ v − π(z, m[f ]), v − ψ ≥ 0 0 = 2 zz z v − ψ ρv − 1 σ 2 ∂ v − μ ∂ v − π ≥ , 2 (z) zz (z) z (z, m[f ]) 0. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

4. Knowledge diffusion and growth 9 rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org

We now present some models of knowledge diffusion that have recently been used in ...... macroeconomics, international trade and finance. These differ from the classic mean field games presented in §§2 and 3 in that the law of motion of the distribution no longer takes the form of a Fokker–Planck equation describing a local diffusion process. Instead, this law of motion takes the form of equations describing richer more ‘non-local’ dynamics, for example Fisher–KPP- or Bolztmann-type equations. They also differ in that the long-run behaviour of the systems they describe is not stationary. Instead, these models are designed to feature sustained growth. As such they can be used to try to answer some of the most important questions in economics, for example: what generates long-run growth? What is the relation between growth and inequality?

In §4a, we first present some problems that are purely ‘mechanical’ in the sense that they do not Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A feature an optimal control problem. We then add such a control problem in §4b.

(a) Diffusion and experimentation as an engine of growth

The following is based on Alvarez et al. [46], Lucas [47] and in particular Luttmer [48]. Consider an 20130397 : 372 economy populated by a continuum of individuals indexed by their productivity or knowledge + z ∈ R . The economy is described by its distribution of knowledge with cdf G(z, t). The evolution of G is modelled as a process of individuals meeting others from the same economy, comparing ideas, improving their own productivity. Meetings happen at Poisson intensity α, and from the point of view of an individual, a meeting is simply a random draw from the distribution G.When ameetingoccurs,apersonz compares his or her productivity with the person he or she meets and leaves the meeting with the best of the two productivities max{z, z }. Individual productivities also fluctuate in the absence of a meeting. In particular individuals ‘experiment’ and their productivity may either increase or decrease according to the process d log zt = σ dWt, σ>0. Given this structure, it is convenient to work with x = log z and the corresponding distribution F,andone can show that this distribution satisfies

σ 2 ∂tF − ∂xxF =−αF(1 − F), (4.1) 2

+ on R × R , and with boundary conditions

= = = lim F(x, t) 0, lim F(x, t) 1, F(x,0) F0(x), (4.2) x→−∞ x→∞ where F0(x) is the initial productivity distribution. As Luttmer [48] points out, this is a Fisher– KPP-type equation [49,50] whose theoretical properties are well understood [51]. In particular, one can show that (4.1) admits ‘travelling wave’ solutions, i.e. solutions of the form

F(x, t) = Φ(x − γ t). (4.3)

One can further show that if the√ initial distribution is a Dirac point mass, the limiting distribution is a travelling wave with γ = σ 2α. If the distribution F is a travelling wave (4.3), productivity z = ex is on average growing at the constant rate γ and hence one can say that the economy is on a ‘balanced√ growth path’ with growth rate γ . The interpretation of the formula for the growth rate γ = σ 2α is also very natural: it says that it is the combination of ‘experimentation’ parametrized by σ and ‘diffusion’ parametrized by α that is the engine of growth in this economy. Either force in isolation would lead to stagnation, but the two together create sustained growth. Similarly, applying some results from the literature studying (4.1), Luttmer [48] shows that√ the distribution −ζ Φ on this balanced growth path satisfies (1 − Φ(x))/e x → c as x →∞with ζ = 2α/σ meaning that the distribution of z = ex follows an asymptotic power law with parameter ζ with a low ζ Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

indicating a fat tail, i.e. a high degree of inequality. Summarizing, on a balanced growth path, 10 the model generates the following predictions for the growth rate and inequality in the tail of the rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org income distribution: ...... √ 1 σ growth = γ = σ 2α, inequality = = √ . (4.4) ζ 2α

The theory presented in this section therefore has some non-trivial implications for one of the big questions raised in the introduction of this paper: is there a trade-off between inequality and growth? In particular, varying the parameter σ which parametrizes the degree of uncertainty at the individual level, one can see that there is indeed such a trade-off: a rise in σ leads not only to higher growth, but also higher inequality. Interestingly, however, the same is not true for α

variations in the parameter measuring how much knowledge diffusion takes place: a rise in Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A α leads to both higher growth and lower inequality. Now, to make things more interesting, the reader should imagine an extension of the model presented here where α and σ are outcomes of choices and/or can be affected by economic policy. We pursue one such extension in §4b.In such an environment, policies that increase the amount of knowledge diffusion α have the twin benefits of stimulating growth while at the same time reducing inequality.

Economists have studied various versions of the Fisher–KPP equation (4.1). Lucas [47]and 20130397 : 372 Alvarez et al. [46] study the version of (4.1) with σ = 0:

∂tF =−αF(1 − F), (4.5)

+ on R × R . To generate sustained growth, they assume that the initial distribution satisfies − / −ζx → →∞ ζ> (1 F0(x)) e c as x for some constants c, 0, meaning that the initial distribution for z = ex is asymptotically a power law as in (3.4).7 Luttmer [52] studies the equation

σ 2 ∂tF − ∂xxF =−α min{F,1− F} 2 + on R × R which can be solved explicitly.

(b) Knowledge diffusion and search While the models in the previous section are interesting in that they describe environments in which there is sustained growth, they are somewhat less interesting than those in §§2 and 3 in that individuals in the economy did not make any choices, i.e. solve optimal control problems. Lucas & Moll [20] extend the set-up in the previous section to feature such an optimal choice. In this extension, one can then ask questions such as: is the equilibrium growth rate of the economy optimal or should policy makers intervene to boost (or perhaps depress) economic growth? In Lucas & Moll [20], individuals have one unit of time and they can split it between producing with the knowledge they already have, or they can search for productivity enhancing ideas. Search increases the likelihood of meeting other individuals. In particular, the Poisson meeting rate of an individual who searches a fraction s of their time is α(s) which is strictly increasing and concave. Conditional on a meeting the knowledge diffusion process is exactly as described in the previous section. The cost of search is that it interferes with production. In particular, the output of an individual with productivity z = ex who searches a fraction s of their time is (1 − s)ex. Individuals maximize the present discounted value of future output  ∞ −ρ v(x,0)= max E e t(1 − s )ext dt ∈ 0 t st [0,1] 0

dxt = σ dWt + dJt,

7As shown by Luttmer [48], the travelling wave solution obtained in the case (4.1) with σ>0 satisfies this property and hence this is a relatively innocuous assumption. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

α where Jt is a Poisson process with intensity (st) that jumps when individuals learn something 11 useful. The equilibrium of this economy can be described in terms of a system of two integro-PDEs rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org for the value function v and the density of the productivity distribution f : ......  σ 2 ∞ x ∂tv + ∂xxv + max (1 − s)e + α(s) (v(y, t) − v(x, t))f (y, t)dy − ρv = 0, (4.6) 2 s∈[0,1] x   2 ∞ x σ ∗ ∗ ∂tf − ∂xxf + α(s (x, t))f (x, t) f (y, t)dy − f (x, t) α(s (y, t))f (y, t)dy = 0 (4.7) 2 −∞  x and f (z, t)dz = 1, f ≥ 0, (4.8)

R × R+ ∗ = on and where s is the maximand of (4.6). There is also an initial condition f (x,0) f0(x). It ∗ α Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A can be seen that (4.1) is the special case of (4.7) in which the optimal control s and hence also are = x constant across x-types, and written in terms of the cdf F(x, t) 0 f (x, t)dx. However, in general, ∗ ∗ it will not be true that s is constant for all x. Instead, s is usually decreasing in x. Lucas & Moll [20] study the special case of (4.6)–(4.8) with σ = 0. They show that the system admits solutions of the travelling wave type, that is

v(x, t) = w(x − γ t), f (x, t) = φ(x − γ t), 20130397 : 372 and they develop numerical methods for computing such solutions numerically, and in particular to find the growth rate γ of the system. However, there remain many open questions, among which are

1. Existence and uniqueness of a solution to (4.6)–(4.8). 2. Asymptotic behaviour of f for different initial conditions f0, in particular the one where f0 is a Dirac point mass. Does the solution converge to a travelling wave f (x, t) = φ(x − γ t)? If so, what does this limiting distribution look like? And what is the growth rate γ and the degree of inequality? 3. Development of numerical methods for solving the time-dependent problem (4.6)–(4.8).

Regarding the second question, a natural conjecture would be that the limiting distribution is a travelling wave with growth rate and tail inequality −  ∞  ∞ 1 1 γ = σ 2 α(s∗(x))φ(x)dx, = σ 2 α(s∗(x))φ(x)dx . −∞ ζ −∞ ∗ These are the natural generalizations of the formulae (4.4) in §4a to the case where s varies across productivity types. If this conjecture turns out to be correct, one prediction of the model would ∗ be that policies that increase s for part of the population have the benefit of simultaneously stimulating growth and reducing inequality. Ideas similar to those presented in this section in the context of search and knowledge diffusion have been applied to different contexts. For example, Duffie et al. [53] and Lagos & Rocheteau [54] and others use search theory to model the trading frictions that are characteristic of over-the- counter markets, and to examine the effects of these frictions on asset prices and trading volumes. A mathematical analysis of a similar model is provided by Gomes & Ribeiro [55]. (c) Diffusion and international trade An alternative route to enrich the model of knowledge diffusion is to consider explicit mechanisms mediating the interactions among individuals. One possible avenue is explored by Alvarez et al. [56], who consider a multi-country model in which knowledge is transmitted through the interaction with the sellers of goods to a country. In their theory, barriers to trade affect the composition of sellers to a country, and therefore they impact the diffusion of knowledge. The higher the trade costs are, the more likely it is that sellers in a country are given by relatively inefficient local producers. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

The central object in their theory is the distribution of productivities across potential producers 12 of different goods G(z, t), denoting the fraction of goods that can be produced with productivity rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org less than z. Similar to the previous models, an individual producer meets other producers at the ...... constant Poisson rate α. The main difference is that now draws come from the distribution of sellers, which depends on the distribution of productivities of producers from all countries in the world, and trade costs 1/κ, κ ∈ [0, 1]. As before, it is convenient to work with x = log(z)and the corresponding distribution F, and define δ = log(κ). For the case of a world with n symmetric countries, the evolution of the distribution F(x, t) solves the following non-local Fisher–KPP-type equation:8

∂tF =−α(1 − M)F (4.9)

+ Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A on R × R where  x n−1 n−2 M(x, t) = (F(y − δ, t) + (n − 1)F(y + δ, t)F(y, t) )∂xF(y, t)dy (4.10) −∞ is the distribution of productivity of sellers to a country. The boundary conditions are given by

(4.2). For κ = 1(δ = 0) and n = 1, this equation simplifies to the one analysed in §4a, but more 20130397 : 372 generally only the behaviour of the solution for large x is fully understood. One can show that this equation admits solutions of the travelling wave type

F(x, t) = Φ(x − γ t), (4.11)

− / −ζx → →∞ ζ> provided that (1 F0(x)) e c as x for some constants c, 0, that is the initial distribution of productivity z = ex follows an asymptotic power law. It can also be shown that the growth rate is γ = nα/ζ. That is, in the present model, there are growth benefits from openness to international trade: the higher is the number of trading partners of a country n, the higher is its growth rate. This is in contrast to most standard trade models in which trade only confers static benefits, that is trade typically leads to a higher level of a country’s gross domestic product (GDP) but not a higher growth rate. Natural open questions are

1. Existence and uniqueness of a solution to (4.9) and (4.10). 2. Development of numerical methods for computing both stationary and time-dependent solutions.

Another interesting extension could be the addition of noise in the form of a geometric Brownian motion to (4.9) along the lines of equation (4.1).

(d) Information percolation in finance A related class of models arises when studying the distribution of information across individuals in an economy, e.g. beliefs about the value of a particular financial asset. These models are useful to understand the dynamics of asset prices and how these are affected when market participants do not share common beliefs about the ‘intrinsic’ value of a financial asset. A simple example is provided by Duffie & Manso [58], who consider the beliefs about the realization of a binary random variable. Individuals are initially endowed with a prior about this realization. Over time, individuals randomly meet at a constant Poisson rate α. Upon a meeting, individuals exchange their information and update their beliefs. In their example, they show that beliefs are characterized by a distribution over a sufficient statistic x, and the updating of beliefs after

8Related equations have been studied by Berestycki et al. [57]. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

a meeting with an individual of belief x is simply given by the sum of x and x . The evolution of 13 the distribution of the sufficient statistic F(x, t) is given by the PDE rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org  +∞ ...... ∂tf (x, t) =−αf (x, t) + α f (y, t)f (x − y, t)dy. −∞ This equation can be solved explicitly using Fourier transforms. A natural extension is to endogenize the search effort α, similar to §4b. This is pursued in Duffie et al. [59]. Other recent contributions in this area include Amador & Weill [60] and Golosov et al. [61]. 5. Business cycles: models with aggregate shocks

Some of the most important questions in macroeconomics are concerned with business cycle Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A fluctuations, that is the fluctuations of macroeconomic aggregates like GDP, aggregate investment and asset prices such as the interest rate. The models presented so far are not well suited to address these questions, because all of them featured macroeconomic aggregates that are deterministic. Instead, we want theories in which these aggregates are stochastic. Denhaan [62,63] and Krusell & Smith [37] have extended theories with heterogeneity at the individual level to feature aggregate risk. We here present a continuous time formulation from Achdou et al. [64]. 20130397 : 372 To introduce these ideas in the simplest possible way, consider the model of §2 but assume that income is ztAt,wherezt is an idiosyncratic income process as before but now income also has an aggregate component At.Thatis,ifAt falls by 10%, it means that the income of everyone in the ∈{ } economy falls by 10%. For the sake of simplicity, assume that At A1, A2 is a two-state Poisson φ process. The process jumps from state 1 to state 2 with intensity 1 and vice versa with intensity φ 2. The introduction of aggregate shocks creates a major difficulty: in contrast to the case without aggregate uncertainty studied in §2, it becomes necessary to include the entire distribution of income and wealth g as a state variable in the optimal control problem of individuals. This distribution is now itself a random variable and hence calendar time t is no longer a sufficient statistic to describe the behaviour of the system. = The aggregate state is (Ai, g), i 1, 2 and the individual state is (a, z), so that the value function v of an individual is i(a, z, g). This value function satisfies the equation

= 1 σ 2 ∂ v + μ ∂ v + + ∂ v 0 (z) zz i (z) z i (Aiz ri(g)a) a i 2  δv i + φ (v − v ) + T[g, ∂av ](a, z) da dz i j i i δg(a, z) + ∂ v − ρv H( a i) i (5.1) and ∂ v = 1 ∂ σ 2 − ∂ μ − ∂ + − ∂ ∂ ∂ v T[g, a i] 2 zz( (z)g) z( (z)g) a((zAi ra)g) a( pH( a i)g) (5.2) for i = 1, 2, j = i. The domain of this equation is (a, ∞) × (z, z¯) × S,whereS is the space of density functions. The Hamiltonian H is defined in (2.5), and there is again a state constraint at a = a. δv /δ i g(a, z) denotes the functional derivative of Vi with respect to g at point (a, z)andT defined ∂ v in (5.2) is the ‘Fokker–Planck’ operator that maps functions g and a i to the time derivative of g. Note that (5.1) is not an ordinary HJB equation because of the presence of g in the state space. The difficulty, of course, is that g is an infinite-dimensional object. v If the functions i(a, z, g) were known, the value function corresponding to a given path (At) would then be found by solving a Fokker–Planck equation for gt and plugging gt into the v functions i. However, (5.1) is a PDE with a variable lying in an infinite dimensional space. Therefore, its numerical approximation is very difficult. For this reason, instead of using the infinite-dimensional Bellman equation (5.1) coupled with a stochastic Fokker–Planck equation, Achdou et al. [64] consider a situation in which aggregate shocks occur only finitely many times and at finite time intervals of length ,thatisattimes τn = n, n = 1, ..., N, N = 1/. There is therefore only a finite (but possibly large) number of Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

v v paths ( t, gt). For each path, ( t, gt) solve a system of forward–backward PDEs between the 14 aggregate shocks and satisfy suitable transmission conditions at the shocks. It is crucial that the rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org variables of the PDEs are (t, a, z), therefore lie in a finite dimensional space. Hence, a situation with, ...... for example, 10 shocks leads to 210 = 1024 paths and can be simulated numerically. The hope is that the model with a finite number of shocks approximates the model when At is a two-state Poisson process, as  → 0. To see why economists find it useful to have a model like the present one that generates predictions about the consumption and saving behaviour of individuals over the business cycle and at different points in the wealth distribution, let us come back to one of the questions raised in the introduction: what should be done if the economy is hit by a recession? A policy that is often advocated is fiscal stimulus, that is a one-time transfer from government to households with the aim of increasing their disposable income (in practice, this is achieved, for example, by sending Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A households tax rebate cheques). The crucial question is usually whether such fiscal stimulus will be effective and in particular whether households will actually increase their spending. The critical object one would like to know is the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of income = ∂ =−∂ ∂ v which, in the model, is MPCi(a, z, g) zci(a, z, g), where ci pH( a i) is optimal consumption. This object answers the question: if a household receives an unexpected increase in income z, what fraction of it will it consume and what fraction will it save? Again, the presence of the 20130397 : 372 state constraint is important here. For the same reasons discussed in §2, individuals with wealth = + equal to a and low enough income z will have ci(a, z, g) zAi ra, i.e. they consume their entire income rather than saving it, and hence have a high MPC. However, similar to the model in §2, it turns out that calibrated versions of the model do not generate high enough average MPCs when compared with the data, mainly because not enough individuals are borrowing constrained for reasonable parameter values. This has motivated the development of alternative models, for example models with more than one asset (e.g. Kaplan & Violante [65], who argue for the importance of distinguishing between liquid and illiquid assets). Models with aggregate shocks such as (5.1) are by far the most challenging in terms of the mathematics, and many open questions remain. Among these are

1. Existence and uniqueness of solutions to (5.1). 2. A theoretical understanding of the behaviour of g. For example, given a stationary process for At (such as the two-state Poisson process), does there exist a ‘stationary equilibrium’ for g? Similarly, are there certain regions of the space of density functions S in which g lives ‘most of the time’? 3. Development of efficient and robust approximation schemes to (5.1) and results regarding their convergence.

Regarding the first question, it should again be noted that non-uniqueness is quite possible and understanding non-uniqueness is equally interesting to economists as proving uniqueness. One approach to obtaining more tractable formulations of models with aggregate shocks has been to simplify the heterogeneity at the individual level. For example, Brunnermeier & Sannikov [66], He & Krishnamurthy [67,68], Adrian & Boyarchenko [69] and Di Tella [70] all study business cycles in models of financial intermediation with frictions and argue that these frictions give rise to interesting nonlinear behaviour of macroeconomic aggregates. For example, GDP may have a bimodal stationary distribution even if the driving stochastic process is unimodal. These papers all make the assumption that there are only two (or three) types of agents, so that the wealth distribution can be summarized by the share of wealth of one of the two types. The big advantage of these two approaches is that this is a one-dimensional rather than an infinite-dimensional object. Related, business cycle fluctuations can also be generated from theories without aggregate shocks. An important early paper by Scheinkman & Weiss [71] demonstrates that in a model with only a finite number of agents (two in their framework) idiosyncratic shocks (in combination with missing insurance markets) can lead to aggregate fluctuations. See Conze et al. [72] and Lippi et al. [73] for other applications of their framework. These authors again make assumptions that Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

avoid dealing with an infinite-dimensional problem. However, for many interesting economic 15 questions, it may be necessary to consider richer forms of heterogeneity. Our hope is therefore rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org that some progress can be made on infinite dimensional problems such as (5.1)......

6. Models with finite number of agents In this paper, we have mostly focused on models with a continuum of individuals (mean field games). While these frameworks are useful to study a very large class of macroeconomic phenomena, their applicability to other important macro questions is limited. In some industries, production is concentrated in a very small number of producers, who act strategically when making their production, innovation and pricing decisions. The strategic nature of their decision Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A could have important aggregate implications. For example, Atkeson & Burstein [74]considera model with a continuum of sectors and a finite number of firms in each sector to explain why there are large and systematic deviations of the law of one price across countries. Aghion et al. [75] study a model of innovation in duopolist industries to analyse the relationship between competition and innovation.

In this section, we introduce a continuous time version of the canonical model of firm 20130397 : 372 dynamics in an oligopolistic industry introduced by Ericson & Pakes [76], and recently studied by Weintraub et al. [77] and Doraszelski & Judd [78], among many others. We show that this model takes the form of a differential game. = π There are two firms i 1, 2 that compete with each other. Firm i has profits (zi, qi, qj), where = π j i.Profits are increasing in productivity zi and own quantity qj, but decreasing in the quantity of the other firm qj. The quantity choice also affects the evolution of the firm’s productivity which = μ + σ evolves as dzit (zit, qit)dt (zit)dWit. We assume that there is ‘learning-by-doing’, so that μ is increasing in qit (of course, other assumptions also are possible). We assume that the two firms play a Nash equilibrium, that is their choices of qit are best responses to each other. Given the symmetry of the problem, we look for a symmetric Nash equilibrium. To this end denote by z a firm’s own productivity and by x the productivity of the other firm. In a symmetric Nash equilibrium, the value function v(z, x)ofafirmsatisfies

2 2 σ (z) σ (x) ∗ ∂zzv + ∂xxv + μ(x, q (x, z, ∂xv, ∂zv))∂xv + H(z, x, ∂zv, ∂xv) − ρv = 0 (6.1) 2 2 + + ∗ on R × R , and where the Hamiltonians H and optimal choice q jointly satisfy

∗ H(z, x, pz, px) = max(π(z, q, q (x, z, px, pz)) + μ(z, q)pz) q ∗ ∗ q (z, x, pz, px) = arg max(π(z, q, q (x, z, px, pz)) + μ(z, q)pz). q

There are many possible extensions of this simple framework. Naturally, the model can be generalized to n > 2. One can also consider versions of the model with entry and exit of firms, along the lines of the analysis in §3a. One way to model this process is to consider a maximum number of potential firms n¯. In this case, the relevant ‘aggregate’ state is given by the vector of characteristics of all the active and potential firms, for example, their respective z. An alternative route, which is the one that is typically followed in the literature, is to assume that the state describing an individual firm takes only a finite set of values. In this case, one can describe the aggregate state with the distribution of firms over these (finite) characteristics. The first route leads naturally to PDE methods. We are not aware of a general characterization of these problems. As in the previous examples, the open questions are

1. Existence and uniqueness of a solution to (6.1). 2. Development of numerical methods for computing both stationary and time-dependent solutions when the state variable is continuous. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

7. Conclusion 16 rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org

We have surveyed a large literature in macroeconomics that studies theories that explicitly ...... model the equilibrium interaction of heterogeneous agents. These theories share a common mathematical structure which can be summarize by a system of coupled nonlinear PDEs or mean field game. Some of our examples are well-understood problems in the theory of PDEs, whereas others present new and challenging mathematical problems. The development of numerical methods for actually solving these in practice is equally important. We view this to be a very promising area for future research, or, as economists like to say, we see large ‘gains from trade’ between macroeconomists and mathematicians working on PDEs.

Funding statement. Y.A. was partially supported by ANR project nos. ANR-12-MONU-0013 and ANR-12-BS01-

0008-01. Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A References 1. Bewley T. 1986 Stationary monetary equilibrium with a continuum of independently fluctuating consumers. In Contributions to mathematical economics in honor of Gerard Debreu (eds W Hildenbrand, A Mas-Collel), pp. 79–102. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North- 20130397 : 372 Holland. 2. Aiyagari SR. 1994 Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving. Q. J. Econ. 109, 659–684. (doi:10.2307/2118417) 3. Huggett M. 1993 The risk-free rate in heterogeneous-agent incomplete-insurance economies. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 17, 953–969. (doi:10.1016/0165-1889(93)90024-M) 4. Hopenhayn HA. 1992 Entry, exit, and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica 60, 1127–1150. (doi:10.2307/2951541) 5. Lasry J-M, Lions P-L. 2006 Jeux à champ moyen. I. Le cas stationnaire. C. R. Math. Acad. Sci. Paris 343, 619–625. (doi:10.1016/j.crma.2006.09.019) 6. Lasry J-M, Lions P-L. 2006 Jeux à champ moyen. II. Horizon fini et contrôle optimal. C. R. Math. Acad. Sci. Paris 343, 679–684. (doi:10.1016/j.crma.2006.09.018) 7. Lasry J-M, Lions P-L. 2007 Mean field games. Jpn J. Math. 2, 229–260. (doi:10.1007/ s11537-007-0657-8) 8. Lions P-L. 2007–2011 Cours du Collège de France. See http://www.college-de-france. fr/default/EN/all/equ_der/. 9. Bardi M. 2012 Explicit solutions of some linear-quadratic mean field games. Netw. Heterog. Media 7, 243–261. (doi:10.3934/nhm.2012.7.243) 10. Guéant O. 2009 A reference case for mean field games models. J. Math. Pures Appl. 92, 276–294. (doi:10.1016/j.matpur.2009.04.008) 11. Guéant O, Lasry J-M, Lions P-L. 2011 Mean field games and applications. In Paris-Princeton Lectures on Mathematical Finance 2010. Lecture Notes in Mathematics, vol. 2003, pp. 205–266. Berlin, Germany: Springer. 12. Gomes DA, Mohr J, Souza RR. 2010 Discrete time, finite state space mean field games. J. Math. Pures Appl. 93, 308–328. (doi:10.1016/j.matpur.2009.10.010) 13. Cardaliaguet P. 2010 Notes on mean field games. Preprint. 14. Sannikov Y. 2008 A continuous-time version of the principal-agent problem. Rev. Econ. Stud. 75, 957–984. (doi:10.1111/j.1467-937X.2008.00486.x) 15. Williams N. 2011 Persistent private information. Econometrica 79, 1233–1275. (doi:10.3982/ ECTA7706) 16. Farhi E, Werning I. 2013 Insurance and taxation over the life cycle. Rev. Econ. Stud. 80, 596–635. (doi:10.1093/restud/rds048) 17. Alvarez F, Shimer R. 2011 Search and rest unemployment. Econometrica 79, 75–122. (doi:10.3982/ECTA7686) 18. Lentz R, Mortensen DT. 2010 Labor market models of worker and firm heterogeneity. Annu. Rev. Econ. 2, 577–602. (doi:10.1146/annurev.economics.102308.124511) 19. Nuño G. 2013 Optimal control with heterogeneous agents in continuous time. Working Paper Series 1608. Frankfurt am Main, Germany: European Central Bank. 20. Lucas RE, Moll B. 2014 Knowledge growth and the allocation of time. J. Polit. Econ. 122, 1–51. (doi:10.1086/674363) Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

21. Achdou Y, Lasry J-M, Lions P-L, Moll B. 2014 Heterogeneous agent models in continuous 17 time. Working papers. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University. rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org 22. Bayer C, Waelde K. 2010 Matching and saving in continuous time: theory. CESifo working ...... paper no. 3026. See http://www.cesifo-group.de/de/ifoHome/publications/working-papers/ CESifoWP/CESifoWPdetails?wp_id=14555568. 23. Bayer C, Waelde K. 2013 The dynamics of distributions in continuous-time stochastic models. Discussion paper. See https://www.wias-berlin.de/people/bayerc/files/BW13.pdf. 24. Bardi M, Capuzzo-Dolcetta I. 1997 Optimal control and viscosity solutions of Hamilton–Jacobi– Bellman equations. Berlin, Germany: Springer. 25. Crandall MG, Ishii H, Lions P-L. 1992 User’s guide to viscosity solutions of second order partial differential equations. Bull. Am. Math. Soc. 27, 1–67. (doi:10.1090/S0273- 0979-1992-00266-5)

26. Barles G. 2013 An introduction to the theory of viscosity solutions for first-order Hamilton– Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A Jacobi equations and applications. In Hamilton–Jacobi equations: approximations, numerical analysis and applications. Lecture Notes in Mathematics, vol. 2074, pp. 49–109. Heidelberg, Germany: Springer. 27. Bouchard B, Touzi N. 2011 Weak dynamic programming principle for viscosity solutions. SIAM J. Control Optim. 49, 948–962. (doi:10.1137/090752328) 28. Touzi N. 2013 Optimal stochastic control, stochastic target problems, and backward SDE. Fields 20130397 : 372 Institute Monographs, vol. 29. New York, NY: Springer; Toronto, Canada: Fields Institute for Research in Mathematical Sciences. [With chapter 13 by Angès Tourin.] 29. Achdou Y, Capuzzo-Dolcetta I. 2010 Mean field games: numerical methods. SIAM J. Numer. Anal. 48, 1136–1162. (doi:10.1137/090758477) 30. Achdou Y. 2013 Finite difference methods for mean field games. In Hamilton–Jacobi equations: approximations, numerical analysis and applications. Lecture Notes in Mathematics, vol. 2074, pp. 1–47. Heidelberg, Germany: Springer. 31. Benhabib J, Bisin A, Zhu S. 2011 The distribution of wealth and fiscal policy in economies with finitely lived agents. Econometrica 79, 123–157. (doi:10.3982/ECTA8416) 32. Piketty T. 2014 Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge, MA: Press. 33. Benhabib J, Bisin A, Zhu S. 2013 The distribution of wealth in the Blanchard–Yaari model. Working papers. New York, NY: . 34. Cagetti M, De Nardi M. 2006 Entrepreneurship, frictions, and wealth. J. Polit. Econ. 114, 835–870. (doi:10.1086/508032) 35. Buera FJ, Shin Y. 2013 Financial frictions and the persistence of history: a quantitative exploration. J. Polit. Econ. 121, 221–272. (doi:10.1086/670271) 36. Moll B. In press. Productivity losses from financial frictions: can self-financing undo capital misallocation? Am. Econ. Rev. 37. Krusell P, Smith AA. 1998 Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy. J. Polit. Econ. 106, 867–896. (doi:10.1086/250034) 38. Gabaix X. 2009 Power laws in economics and finance. Annu. Rev. Econ. 1, 255–293. (doi:10.1146/annurev.economics.050708.142940) 39. Gabaix X. 1999 Zipf’s law for cities: an explanation. Q. J. Econ. 114, 739–767. (doi:10.1162/ 003355399556133) 40. Luttmer EGJ. 2007 Selection, growth, and the size distribution of firms. Q. J. Econ. 122, 1103– 1144. (doi:10.1162/qjec.122.3.1103) 41. Bensoussan A, Lions J-L. 1982 Applications of variational inequalities in stochastic control. Studies in Mathematics and its Applications, vol. 12. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland. 42. Stokey NL. 2009 The economics of inaction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 43. Golosov M, Lucas RE. 2007 Menu costs and Phillips curves. J. Polit. Econ. 115, 171–199. (doi:10.1086/512625) 44. Alvarez F, Lippi F. 2013 Price setting with menu cost for multi-product firms. EIEF Working Papers Series 1302. Rome, Italy: Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance (EIEF). 45. Jones 2014 A schumpeterian model of top income inequality. Working paper. Stanford, CA: . 46. Alvarez FE, Buera FJ, Lucas REJ. 2008 Models of idea flows. NBER Working Papers, no. 14135. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. 47. Lucas RE. 2009 Ideas and growth. Economica 76, 1–19. (doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.2008. 00748.x) Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

48. Luttmer EG. 2012 Eventually, noise and imitation implies balanced growth. Federal 18 Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Working Papers, no. 699. See http://ideas.repec.org/p/fip/ rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org fedmwp/699.html...... 49. Fisher RA. 1937 The wave of advance of advantageous genes. Ann. Eugen. 7, 355–369. (doi:10.1111/j.1469-1809.1937.tb02153.x) 50. Kolmogorov A, Petrovskii I, Piskunov N. 1937 A study of the diffusion equation with increase in the amount of substance, and its application to a biological problem. Math. Appl. (Soviet Series) 25, 242–270. (doi:10.1007/978-94-011-3030-1_38) 51. McKean HP.1975 Application of Brownian motion to the equation of Kolmogorov–Petrovskii– Piskunov. Commun. Pure Appl. Math. 28, 323–331. (doi:10.1002/cpa.3160280302) 52. Luttmer EG. 2014 Competitive knowledge diffusion and inequality. Working papers. Minneapolis, MN: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

53. Duffie D, Garleanu N, Pedersen LH. 2005 Over-the-counter markets. Econometrica 73, 1815– Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A 1847. (doi:10.1111/j.1468-0262.2005.00639.x) 54. Lagos R, Rocheteau G. 2009 Liquidity in asset markets with search frictions. Econometrica 77, 403–426. (doi:10.3982/ECTA7250) 55. Gomes D, Ribeiro R. 2013 Mean-field games with logistic population dynamics. In IEEE 52nd Annual Conf. on Decision and Control, Florence, Italy, 10–13 December 2013, pp. 2513–2518.

(doi:10.1109/CDC.2013.6760258) 20130397 : 372 56. Alvarez FE, Buera FJ, Lucas REJ. 2013 Idea flows, economic growth, and trade. NBER Working Papers, no. 19667. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. 57. Berestycki H, Nadin G, Perthame B, Ryzhik L. 2009 The non-local Fisher–KPP equation: travelling waves and steady states. Nonlinearity 22, 2813–2844. (doi:10.1088/0951- 7715/22/12/002) 58. Duffie D, Manso G. 2007 Information percolation in large markets. Am. Econ. Rev. 97, 203–209. (doi:10.1257/aer.97.2.203) 59. Duffie D, Malamud S, Manso G. 2009 Information percolation with equilibrium search dynamics. Econometrica 77, 1513–1574. (doi:10.3982/ECTA8160) 60. Amador M, Weill P-O. 2012 Learning from private and public observations of others? Actions. J. Econ. Theory 147, 910–940. (doi:10.1016/j.jet.2012.02.001) 61. Golosov M, Lorenzoni G, Tsyvinski A. 2009 Decentralized trading with private information. NBER Working Papers, no. 15513. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. 62. Den Haan WJ. 1996 Heterogeneity, aggregate uncertainty, and the short-term interest rate. J. Bus. Econ. Stat. 14, 399–411. (doi:10.1080/07350015.1996.10524669) 63. Den Haan WJ. 1997 Solving dynamic models with aggregate shocks and heterogeneous agents. Macroecon. Dyn. 1, 355–386. (doi:10.1017/S1365100597003040) 64. Achdou Y, Lasry J-M, Lions P-L, Moll B. 2014 Wealth distribution and the business cycle. Working papers. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University. 65. Kaplan G, Violante G. In press. A model of the consumption response to fiscal stimulus payments. Econometrica. 66. Brunnermeier M, Sannikov Y. 2014 A macroeconomic model with a financial sector. Am. Econ. Rev. 104, 379–421. (doi:10.1257/aer.104.2.379) 67. He Z, Krishnamurthy A. 2012 A model of capital and crises. Rev. Econ. Stud. 79, 735–777. (doi:10.1093/restud/rdr036) 68. He Z, Krishnamurthy A. 2013 Intermediary asset pricing. Am. Econ. Rev. 103, 732–770. (doi:10.1257/aer.103.2.732) 69. Adrian T, Boyarchenko N. 2012 Intermediary leverage cycles and financial stability. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 567. See http://ideas.repec.org/p/ fip/fednsr/567.html. 70. Di Tella S. 2013 Uncertainty shocks and balance sheet recessions. Working paper. Stanford, CA: Stanford University. 71. Scheinkman JA, Weiss L. 1986 Borrowing constraints and aggregate economic activity. Econometrica 54, 23–45. (doi:10.2307/1914155) 72. Conze A, Lasry JM, Scheinkman J. 1993 Borrowing constraints and international comovements. Hitotsubashi J. Econ. 34 (Special I), 23–47. 73. Lippi F, Ragni S, Trachter N. 2014 State dependent monetary policy. CEPR Discussion Papers, no. 9795. See http://ideas.repec.org/p/cpr/ceprdp/9795.html. Downloaded from rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org on October 7, 2014

74. Atkeson A, Burstein A. 2008 Pricing-to-market, trade costs, and international relative prices. 19 Am. Econ. Rev. 98, 1998–2031. (doi:10.1257/aer.98.5.1998) rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org 75. Aghion P, Bloom N, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P. 2005 Competition and innovation: an ...... inverted-U relationship. Q. J. Econ. 120, 701–728. (doi:10.1093/qje/120.2.701) 76. Ericson R, Pakes A. 1995 Markov-perfect industry dynamics: a framework for empirical work. Rev. Econ. Stud. 62, 53–82. (doi:10.2307/2297841) 77. Weintraub GY, Benkard CL, Roy BV. 2008 Markov perfect industry dynamics with many firms. Econometrica 76, 1375–1411. (doi:10.3982/ECTA6158) 78. Doraszelski U, Judd KL. 2012 Avoiding the curse of dimensionality in dynamic stochastic games. Quant. Econ. 3, 53–93. (doi:10.3982/QE153) Phil.Trans.R.Soc.A 20130397 : 372