CONCLUSION: the Virtues of Majoritarian Democracy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

CONCLUSION: the Virtues of Majoritarian Democracy DEPARTAMENTO DE CIENCIA POLÍTICA Y RELACIONES INTERNACIONALES Facultad de Derecho Universidad Autónoma de Madrid Working Papers Online Series www.uam.es/centros/derecho/cpolitica/papers.html Estudio/Working Paper 25/2004 Democracy in Comparative Perspective Jan Erik-Lane Dpto. de Ciencia Política Univesidad de Ginebra Seminario de Investigación de Ciencia Política C u rso 2003-2004 δ Una versión anterior (co-autorada) de este trabajo se presentó en el congreso internacional ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops celebrado en Edimburgo (marzo-abril 2003). Agradezco a todos los participantes en dichas sesiones, y en especial a su director Daniele Caramani, todos los comentarios y sugerencias que hicieron al texto y que han sido incorporadas en esta versión revisada. Igualmente, mis co-autores en aquel trabajo (Górniak, Kosic, Kiss y Kandulla), son en parte responsables de los méritos que esta investigación pueda reunir. José Ignacio Torreblanca Payá, profesor de la UNED, ha comentado y criticado varias versiones de este trabajo. Agradezco también los comentarios y críticas de los evaluadores anónimos de la RECP. Todos ellos han contribuido a mejorar sustancialmente este artículo. Por supuesto, los fallos que puedan subsistir son atribuibles únicamente a la autora. Por ultimo, la mayor parte de la investigación empírica en este trabajo se ha realizado dentro del grupo de trabajo EURONAT, financiado por la Comisión Europea (HPSE-CT2001-00044) [http://www.iue.it/RSCAS/Research/EURONAT/ Index.shtml]. 1 “Il faut en outre connaitre la vrai nature des choses par rapport a l’ordre de faits sur lesquels on veut etre instruit; il faut les classer methodiquement, pouvoir en montrer la liason, c’est-a-dire les rapports qui font de l’un une cause et de l’autre un resultat.” (Say 1996: 84-5) INTRODUCTION ”Democracy” is first and foremost a word. It has today an immense positive evaluation but what we are searching for is what it refers to in reality. We will take the normative meaning of ”democracy” as given, and then look for what it stands for in the real world which we observe with out senses. Alas, it is all too well known that ”democracy” is an ambiguous word with many meanings. How can one enhance conceptual clarity in relation to the various concepts of democracy? The uses of ”democracy” have been examined in several major semantical investigations. A number of scholars have distinguished between various meanings of the word in order to have a set of different concepts. We will not multiply these enquiries into the meaning of ”democracy”, but we do accept that the word is ambiguous. We will separate between three key concepts of democracy: 2 - Democracy as constitutional government today - Democracy as citizen participation in politics - Democracy as an egalitarian society It is quite obvious that ”democracy” is used in all three meanings above. What is perhaps not equally clear is that these three concepts 1) –3) overlap only to a certain extent. In reality, these conceptions are quite distinct as a country may practice constitutional government but give a little role to citizen participation in politics and embrace an economy which contains lots of inequalities. Perhaps this is a description of the United States or Switzerland today where less than 50 per cent of the population participates in ordinary elections? However, both these two countries employ the referendum institution to express citizen preferences which is a positive. Most so-called democracies concentrate upon representation by providing Parliaments with a major role in channelling citizen preferences into government policies. Finally, some demo cries underline equality more than others, like the Nordic countries where both income equality and gender equality is higher than in many other democratic countries. Constitutional democracy may be practiced in different ways. The political system of democratic countries offers a large set of different institution in terms of which the Rule of Law may be guaranteed. Usually two questions are raised in relation to institutions that guarantee the”Rule of Law” or ”Rechtsstaat”, namely: 3 - Why is constitutional democracy stable in some countries but not in others? - Are different institutions for constitutional democracy conducive to different policy outputs or outcomes? Constitutional democracy is a system of government where procedures are respected and citizens can seek redress against wrong decisions as well as express grievances against the administration. Constitutional democracy is government through checks and balances, where centres of power constitute counter-veiling forces. Why is it the case that constitutional democracy works in some democracies but remains fragile in others? A number of hypotheses have been suggested to account for the probability that one country succeeds in establishing the Rule of Law. We will examine these hypotheses here using as recent available data as possible about almost all the countries of the world. Interestingly, one finds that all the major factors employed in social science theories have been suggested such as economic ones, social structure, culture, history and the very institutions of constitutional democracy themselves. Another major problem in relation to constitutional democracy is whether certain institutions matter more than others, or if some institutions have a different impact than others. Constitutional democracy may be based upon a plethora of institutions safeguarding decentralisation of power as well as human rights. A country may opt for a thin or a thick institutional set-up to protect and enhance its Rule of Law. Does it matter for outcomes? There are a number of theories that argue that democracy can be done under various institutions and it matters which institutions a country chooses and 4 implements. Thus, Robert Dahl opposed Madisonian democracy to Rousseau democracy and Arend Lijphart suggested that Westminster democracy operated very differently from Consensus democracy. What evidence is there actually that confirms these ideas that alternative models of democracy result in different styles of decision-making or outcomes? We have here three sets of problems concerning the interpretation of democracy today. The first set includes all kinds of questions about the stability of the democratic regime. What are the sources of political stability in a democracy and what do some democratic countries hover between the Rule of Law and authoritarianism? The second set deals more with democratic politics than with democratic procedures. It asks a number of questions about who participate in politics and how citizen preferences are translated into government decisions. Third, there is the problem of inequality in democratic countries, which calls for an analysis of whether democratic policy-making can reduce social and gender inequalities. THREE PERSPECTIVES UPON DEMOCRACY While it is true that these three sets of problems of democratic government do not constitute an exhaustive listing of questions social scientists tend to raise in relation to democracy, they cover a fair amount of territory. Thus, they include the constitutional perspective upon democracy, the behavioural perspective as well and the policy view as well. Let us comment somewhat more upon each of these perspectives. 5 The Constitutional Perspective To a constitutionalist the rules of democracy are at the centre of interest. They must satisfy a number of requirements including transparency, stability, procedural accountability, human rights and division of power. In a constitutional approach to democracy these requirements are not only means to the accomplishment of citizen rule but they are regarded as goals in themselves. When they collide with the expression of the will of the people, then institutionalism would favour that the rules prevail. The constitutional perspective focuses upon the Rule of Law in the context of a democratic regime. The idea of a Rechtsstaat was launched before the advent of democracy, however. Universal male and female suffrage was introduced everywhere after the erection of Rule of Law. Thus, the constitutional monarchies in Western Europe practiced the Rechtsstaat before they accepted universal suffrage. And the theory of the constitutional state underlined the requirements of Rule of Law without emphasizing universal suffrage or even demanding it. The great theoreticians of the constitutional state in the 19th century underlined other things than one man – one vote or one woman – one vote. They focussed upon the exercise of power within the limits of the law – the requirement of legality. As a consequence they demanded that the state should be based upon a fundamental law – lex suprema – which outlined the structure of government and identified both its possibilities 6 and limits. Such a basic law could be codified as with Continental Europe or it could consist of conventions as in the United Kingdom. Constitutionalism in the early 19th century dealt more with the procedures of government than with universal human rights. A constitutional state would respect certain human rights like the classical negative freedoms but it was not considered essential that all people could vote. Freedom of thought, of expression and of religion together with property rights constituted vital elements of a constitutional state, but it was not until late 19th century that universal suffrage was made part of the constitutional state. Several constitutional scholars pressed more for parliamentarism
Recommended publications
  • Facets of Democracy: an Overview
    Molung Educational Frontier 15 Facets of Democracy: An Overview Aswasthama Bhakta Kharel, PhD* Abstract Democracy allows the expression of political preferences of citizens in a state. It advocates the rule of law, constraints on executive’s power, and guarantees the provision of civil liberties. It also manages to ensure human rights and fundamental freedoms of people. In democracy, people are supposed to exercise their freely expressed will. Ordinary people hold the political power of the state and rule directly or through elected representatives inside a democratic form of government. Democracy is a participatory and liberal way of governing a country. Different countries in the world have been practicing various models of democracy. There remains the participation of people in government and policy-making of the state under democracy. But when the majority can pull the strings of the society without there being legislation for protecting the rights of the minority, it may create a severe risk of oppression. Many countries of the world at the present time are facing democratic deficits. In several countries, the democratic practices are not adequately regulated and governed, as a result, the rise of violations of rules of law is observed. Even a few countries practicing democracy are not living peacefully. This situation has put a significant question about the need and sustainability of democracy. Democracy is a widely used system of governance beyond having several challenges. Here the concept, origin, models, dimensions, practices, challenges, solutions, and future of democracy are dealt to understand the structure of ideal democracy. Keywords: democracy, human rights, rule of law, sustainable development, election Methodology The methodology applied in maintaining this research paper includes documentary analysis qualitatively where different journals, public documents, organizational reports, articles, and books are referred, and their factual data are considered.
    [Show full text]
  • Stable Democracy and Good Governance in Divided Societies
    Faculty Research Working Papers Series Stable Democracy and Good Governance in Divided Societies: Do Powersharing Institutions Work? Pippa Norris February 2005 RWP05-014 The views expressed in the KSG Faculty Research Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the John F. Kennedy School of Government or Harvard University. Copyright belongs to the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only. POWER-SHARING INSTITUTIONS – NORRIS 2/7/2005 6:20 PM Draft @ 2/7/2005 6:20 PM Words 16,687 Stable democracy and good governance in divided societies: Do power-sharing institutions work? Pippa Norris McGuire Lecturer in Comparative Politics John F. Kennedy School of Government Harvard University Cambridge, MA 02138 [email protected] www.pippanorris.com Synopsis: Consociational theory suggests that power-sharing institutions have many important consequences, not least that they are most likely to facilitate accommodation and cooperation among leadership elites, making them most suitable for states struggling to achieve stable democracy and good governance in divided societies. This study compares a broad cross-section of countries worldwide, including many multiethnic states, to investigate the impact of formal power-sharing institutions (PR electoral systems and federalism) on several indicators of democratic stability and good governance. The research demonstrates three main findings: (i) worldwide, power-sharing constitutions combining PR and federalism remain relatively rare (only 13 out of 191 states); (ii) federalism was found to be unrelated to any of the indicators of good governance under comparison; and (iii) PR electoral systems, however, were positively related to some indicators of good governance, both worldwide and in multiethnic states.
    [Show full text]
  • Ethnic Conflicts & the Informational Dividend of Democracy
    ETHNIC CONFLICTS & THE INFORMATIONAL DIVIDEND OF DEMOCRACY∗ Jeremy Laurent-Lucchettiy Dominic Rohnerz Mathias Thoenig§ November 2019 Abstract Prevailing explanations view democracy as an institutional arrangement that solves a class conflict between a rich elite and the rest of population. We study the logic of democratic transition when ethnic tensions are more salient than the poor/rich divide. We build a simple theory where (i) ethnic groups negotiate over allocating the economic surplus and (ii) both military and political mobiliza- tions rest on the unobserved strength of ethnic identity. By eliciting information on mobilization, free and fair elections restore inter-ethnic bargaining efficiency and prevent conflict outbreak. We show that democratic transition can be rationally chosen by autocrats, even if it involves a risk of losing power, as elections reduce the informational rent of the opposition, allowing the legitimately elected ruler to grab more economic surplus. Our setup generates new predictions on the nature of political regime, government tenure, ethnic favoritism and social unrest for ethnically divided countries - all consistent with novel country-level and ethnic group-level panel evidence on democratization in the post-decolonization period. JEL classification: C72, D02, D72, D74, D82, P16. Keywords: Democracy, Elections, Conflict, Asymmetric Information, Ethnic Identity, Institutions, Government Tenure, Political Regime, Ethnic Favoritism. ∗We thank Brendan Berthold and Pascal Zumbühl for excellent research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • Patterns of Democracy This Page Intentionally Left Blank PATTERNS of DEMOCRACY
    Patterns of Democracy This page intentionally left blank PATTERNS OF DEMOCRACY Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries SECOND EDITION AREND LIJPHART First edition 1999. Second edition 2012. Copyright © 1999, 2012 by Arend Lijphart. All rights reserved. This book may not be reproduced, in whole or in part, including illustrations, in any form (beyond that copying permitted by Sections 107 and 108 of the US Copyright Law and except by reviewers for the public press), without written permission from the publishers. Yale University Press books may be purchased in quantity for educational, business, or promotional use. For information, please e-mail [email protected] (US offi ce) or [email protected] (UK offi ce). Set in Melior type by Integrated Publishing Solutions, Grand Rapids, Michigan. Printed in the United States of America. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Lijphart, Arend. Patterns of democracy : government forms and performance in thirty-six countries / Arend Lijphart. — 2nd ed. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-0-300-17202-7 (paperbound : alk. paper) 1. Democracy. 2. Comparative government. I. Title. JC421.L542 2012 320.3—dc23 2012000704 A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. This paper meets the requirements of ANSI/NISO Z39.48–1992 (Permanence of Paper). 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 for Gisela and for our grandchildren, Connor, Aidan, Arel, Caio, Senta, and Dorian, in the hope that the twenty-fi rst century—their century—will yet become more
    [Show full text]
  • The Philosophy of Democracy and the Paradoxes of Majority Rule
    Eerik Lagerspetz The Philosophy of Democracy and the Paradoxes of Majority Rule Introduction fter forty years of intensive theoretical research, the rela- tionship between social choice and traditional political Aphilosophy is still unclear. For some theorists of democracy, the Arrow theorem and the related results are conclusive proofs that our democratic institutions are deeply defective. Thus, R.P. Wolff uses the results in his A Defence of Anarchism as a part of his general attack on the legitimacy of democratic institutions and as a part of his defence of anarchic consensualism (Wolff 1976, 58-67), while Daniel Bell, in The Coming of Post-Industrial Society, tries to derive a justification for technocratic elitism from the same re- sults (Bell 1974, 305-13). Such dramatic conclusions are, however, uncommon. Like many welfare economists (cf. Johansen 1987, 439), most normative theorists of democracy have, while perhaps men- tioning the results in a footnote, simply ignored them (cf. Dummett 1984, 295-6). 95 Some theorists of democracy have claimed that the Arrow im- possibility theorem and its relatives (among which the most impor- tant are the Gibbard-Satterthwaite theorem on the universality of strategic possibilities and the McKelvey theorem on agenda-setters’ power) are just mathematical curiosities. This claim has been made several times (see Dahl & Lindblom 1953, 422; Plamenatz 1973, 183-4; Tullock 1967; Spitz 1984, 24-5). However, such a rebuttal implies that some of the postulates used in the theorems are false or meaningless when applied to real democratic procedures. An out- right rejection of the relevance of the theorems should be based on a criticism of some specific, identifiable suppositions1.
    [Show full text]
  • Democracy and Human Rights: the Role of the UN
    Democracy and Human Rights: The Role of the UN DiscussionPaper September 2013 Successful democratic governance must inevitably focus on promotion and protection of human rights and fundamental freedoms. For without this protection there can be no democracy in any meaningful sense. Copyright © United Nations, 2013. Views expressed in this publication do not necessarily reflect those of the United Nations, or of International IDEA, its Board or its Council members All photographs © International IDEA 2013 ISBN: 978-91-86565-89-3 INTERNATIONAL IDEA AT A GLANCE Democracy remains a universal human aspiration and a powerful force of political mobilization for change, as witnessed by citizen-led movements which are demanding democratic reform. International IDEA’s Strategy 2012–2017 What is International IDEA? The International Institute for Democracy and Contents Electoral Assistance (International IDEA) is an intergovernmental organization with a mission to support sustainable democracy worldwide. The objectives of the Institute are to support stronger democratic institutions and processes, Key Recommendations 6 and more sustainable, effective and legitimate democracy. Executive Summary 7 International IDEA is the only global intergovernmental organization with the sole Conclusions 7 mandate of supporting democracy; its vision is Recommendations 9 to become the primary global actor in sharing comparative knowledge and experience in support of democracy. 1. Introduction 12 Background and Objectives of the Round Table 12 What does International IDEA do? Structure of the Round Table 13 International IDEA produces comparative knowledge in its key areas of expertise: electoral 2. Human Rights and Democracy Building: Setting the Constitutional and processes, constitution building, political Governance Framework 14 participation and representation, and democracy and development, as well as on democracy as it relates to gender, diversity, and conflict and 3.
    [Show full text]
  • Analyzing Patterns of Democracy in Central and Eastern Europe
    ANALYZING PATTERNS OF DEMOCRACY IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE By Karolína Púllová Submitted to Central European University Department of Political Science In partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts Supervisor: Associate Professor Matthijs Bogaards CEU eTD Collection Vienna, Austria (2021) Author’s Declaration I, the undersigned, Karolína Púllová, candidate for the MA degree in Political Science declare herewith that the present thesis is exclusively my own work, based on my research and only such external information as properly credited in notes and bibliography. I declare that no unidentified and illegitimate use was made of the work of others, and no part of the thesis infringes on any person’s or institution’s copyright. I also declare that no part of the thesis has been submitted in this form to any other institution of higher education for an academic degree. Vienna, 01/06/2021 __________________________ Signature CEU eTD Collection ii Abstract Arend Lijphart’s typology of democratic systems, where he differentiates between majoritarian and consensus democracies, has been regarded as one of the most prominent and influential typologies of modern democratic systems. However, in recent decades its usefulness as a typology of democratic systems started to be questioned, as many scholars by replicating his work revealed that some of his core findings do not hold outside his sample of mature democracies. The present thesis tests the usefulness of Lijphart’s typology, firstly by analyzing institutional constellation in two of the newest democracies from the Central and Eastern European region – Croatia and Serbia, and, secondly by mapping more recent institutional changes and developments in the sample of ten Central and Eastern European democracies, which were previously analyzed by Andrew Roberts in 2006.
    [Show full text]
  • Ethnic Conflicts and the Informational Dividend of Democracy
    Ethnic Conflicts and the Informational Dividend of Democracy J. Laurent-Lucchetti 1 D. Rohner 2;3 M. Thoenig 2;3 1 University of Geneva 2 University of Lausanne 3 CEPR Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics , June 2021 • Prevailing narrative: Democracy is an institutional arrangement that solves a class conflict between a rich elite and the rest of the population. ! Democratic transition entails a transfer of power (de jure) from the rich elite to the population and more redistribution ! Considerable explanatory power when political cleavage is between rich & poor (19th century Europe) • Post-decolonization period: ! Ethnic rather than class conflicts (Esteban and Ray, 2008) ! Less than 1=3 of all transitions driven by distributive conflicts between elites and masses (Haggard and Kaufman, 2012). Our Research Question: What is the logic of democratic transitions when ethnic tensions are more salient than poor/rich divide? Motivation • Broad question: Why do we observe democratic transitions ? • Post-decolonization period: ! Ethnic rather than class conflicts (Esteban and Ray, 2008) ! Less than 1=3 of all transitions driven by distributive conflicts between elites and masses (Haggard and Kaufman, 2012). Our Research Question: What is the logic of democratic transitions when ethnic tensions are more salient than poor/rich divide? Motivation • Broad question: Why do we observe democratic transitions ? • Prevailing narrative: Democracy is an institutional arrangement that solves a class conflict between a rich elite and the rest of the population.
    [Show full text]
  • Organisational Social Influence on Directed Hierarchical Graphs, From
    www.nature.com/scientificreports OPEN Organisational Social Infuence on Directed Hierarchical Graphs, from Tyranny to Anarchy Charlie Pilgrim1*, Weisi Guo2,4 & Samuel Johnson3,4 Coordinated human behaviour takes place within a diverse range of social organisational structures, which can be thought of as power structures with “managers” who infuence “subordinates”. A change in policy in one part of the organisation can cause cascades throughout the structure, which may or may not be desirable. As organisations change in size, complexity and structure, the system dynamics also change. Here, we consider majority rule dynamics on organisations modelled as hierarchical directed graphs, where the directed edges indicate infuence. We utilise a topological measure called the trophic incoherence parameter, q, which efectively gauges the stratifcation of power structure in an organisation. We show that this measure bounds regimes of behaviour. There is fast consensus at low q (e.g. tyranny), slow consensus at mid q (e.g. democracy), and no consensus at high q (e.g. anarchy). These regimes are investigated analytically, numerically and empirically with diverse case studies in the Roman Army, US Government, and a healthcare organisation. Our work demonstrates the usefulness of the trophic incoherence parameter when considering models of social infuence dynamics, with widespread consequences in the design and analysis of organisations. Social and political systems display different types of order and structure, with very different outcomes. Small-scale informal organisations might be skill or power based, whereas large-scale social systems ofen involve complex politics. Some form of formal or latent hierarchy is present in almost all social organisations.
    [Show full text]
  • The New Anarchists
    A Movement of Movements?—5 david graeber THE NEW ANARCHISTS t’s hard to think of another time when there has been such a gulf between intellectuals and activists; between theorists of Irevolution and its practitioners. Writers who for years have been publishing essays that sound like position papers for vast social movements that do not in fact exist seem seized with confusion or worse, dismissive contempt, now that real ones are everywhere emerging. It’s particularly scandalous in the case of what’s still, for no particularly good reason, referred to as the ‘anti-globalization’ movement, one that has in a mere two or three years managed to transform completely the sense of historical possibilities for millions across the planet. This may be the result of sheer ignorance, or of relying on what might be gleaned from such overtly hostile sources as the New York Times; then again, most of what’s written even in progressive outlets seems largely to miss the point—or at least, rarely focuses on what participants in the movement really think is most important about it. As an anthropologist and active participant—particularly in the more radical, direct-action end of the movement—I may be able to clear up some common points of misunderstanding; but the news may not be gratefully received. Much of the hesitation, I suspect, lies in the reluc- tance of those who have long fancied themselves radicals of some sort to come to terms with the fact that they are really liberals: interested in expanding individual freedoms and pursuing social justice, but not in ways that would seriously challenge the existence of reigning institu- tions like capital or state.
    [Show full text]
  • Drafting Counter-Majoritarian Democracy the Venice
    Drafting Counter-Majoritarian Democracy The Venice Commission’s Constitutional Assistance Valentina Volpe* Abstract 811 I. Introduction 812 II. The Venice Commission: A Global Actor with a European Heritage 813 III. A Dialogue Between European and National Legal Spaces: The Venice Commission’s Constitutional Assistance 817 IV. Between Téchne and Politeia: Limits and Strengths of the Venice Commission’s Constitutional Assistance 818 V. A Counter-Majoritarian Model of Democracy: Promoting European Constitutionalism Beyond Borders 821 1. Primacy of International Law 823 2. Respect for ECHR Standards 826 a) Prohibition of Discrimination (Art. 14 ECHR) 826 b) Abolition of the Death Penalty (Protocol No. 6 ECHR) 828 3. Checks and Balances 830 a) Unicameralism and Bicameralism 831 b) Parliamentarism and Presidentialism 834 4. Constraints on Direct Democracy 838 VI. Democracy by Whom? 841 Abstract Since its creation at the end of the Cold War, the European Commission for Democracy through Law (Venice Commission) has been providing technical-legal assistance in the area of constitutional reform to new or re- stored Central-European democracies. This article suggests that “constitu- tional assistance”, encouraging the adoption of supranational and European * Senior Research Fellow, Max Planck Institute for Comparative Public Law and Interna- tional Law, Heidelberg; Associate Lecturer, Lille Catholic University, Campus of Paris, and LUISS Guido Carli University, Rome. The author wishes to express her gratitude to Anne Peters, Simona Granata-Menghini, Carolyn Moser and Giovanni Boggero for their helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper. The author is also grateful to Natalia Filandria- nou, Elisa Andreotti and Junyu Chen for their precious research assistance and to Joel Maupin for linguistic revision.
    [Show full text]
  • How Consensual Are Consensual Democracies?
    How Consensual Are Consensus Democracies? A Reconsideration of the Consensus/Majoritarian Dichotomy and a Comparison of Legislative Roll-Call Vote Consensus Levels from Sixteen Countries Brian D. Williams University of California at Riverside ______________________________________________________________________________ Abstract In the following study, I develop two new institutional dimensions of consensus/majoritarian democracies, building on the variables of the two forms of democracy identified by Lijphart. Based on these two new dimensions, I establish a classification of consensual regime types and winnow out two permutations which would most closely approximate the ideal of domestic social conflict resolution, and could also more plausibly be explained by irenic cultural norms, rather than institutional mechanisms. Then I conduct an empirical investigation to assess whether there is a correlation between consensus or majoritarian democracies and average levels of legislative roll-call vote consensus acquired over time. My results suggest that proportional representation and ideological cohesion are not in tension with one another, as the opponents of PR would have us believe, and in fact may be more amenable to consensus building and ideological cohesion than their majoritarian counterparts. Interested researchers should aim to substantiate the correlation between consensual institutions and outcomes, and then conduct thicker investigations in order to determine whether consensual outcomes in consensus democracies can be explained
    [Show full text]