The Return of Judicial Repression: What Has Happened to the Strike?
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
The Forum Volume 10, Issue 1 2012 Article 8 LABOR IN AMERICAN POLITICS The Return of Judicial Repression: What Has Happened to the Strike? Chris Rhomberg, Fordham University Recommended Citation: Rhomberg, Chris (2012) "The Return of Judicial Repression: What Has Happened to the Strike?," The Forum: Vol. 10: Iss. 1, Article 8. DOI: 10.1515/1540-8884.1492 ©2012 De Gruyter. All rights reserved. Brought to you by | Fordham University Library Authenticated Download Date | 4/10/15 5:14 PM The Return of Judicial Repression: What Has Happened to the Strike? Chris Rhomberg Abstract Discussions of the current state of American labor have overlooked the fact that the strike, a principal form of union and working class power, has virtually disappeared from American life. The rise of an anti-union institutional legal regime has undermined the right to strike and effectively reversed the structure of incentives for collective bargaining envisioned under the National Labor Relations Act. The dynamics of the current regime are illustrated by one of the largest and longest strikes of recent decades, the 1995 Detroit Newspapers strike. The consequences go beyond unionized labor and constitute a de-democratization of workplace governance in the United States. KEYWORDS: strikes, collective bargaining, unions Author Notes: Chris Rhomberg is an associate professor of sociology at Fordham University. His article “A Signal Juncture: The Detroit Newspaper Strike and Post-Accord Labor Relations in the United States,” [American Journal of Sociology, 115/6 (May 2010): 1853–94] received the Distinguished Scholarly Article Award from the American Sociological Association section on Labor and Labor Movements, and was co-winner of the Distinguished Contribution to Scholarship (Article) Award from the ASA section on Political Sociology. He is the author of The Broken Table: The Detroit Newspaper Strike and the State of American Labor (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2012). Brought to you by | Fordham University Library Authenticated Download Date | 4/10/15 5:14 PM Rhomberg: What Has Happened to the Strike? 1 No discussion of unions or collective bargaining in the contemporary United States should proceed without considering workers’ right to strike, a right explic- itly protected by the 1935 National Labor Relations Act (NLRA) and effectively recognized as a basic human right by the United Nations’ International Labor Or- ganization (Gernigon, Odero, and Guido, 1998). The right to strike was a crucial part of the system for democratic workplace governance under the NLRA, as the U.S. Supreme Court affirmed in its 1960 Insurance Agents decision. There is only one problem now: The strike has virtually disappeared from American life. The numbers are stark. During the 1970s, an average of 289 major work stoppages involving 1000 or more workers occurred annually in the U.S. By the 1990s, that number had fallen to about thirty-five per year, and in 2009 there were no more than five (Lambert 2005; U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics 2011). Nor can the decline in the number of strikes be explained solely by declining union density in the economy. According to a study by sociologist Jake Rosenfeld (2006), un- ionization among private sector, full-time employees fell by 40 percent between 1984 and 2002, but the drop in total strike frequency was even greater, falling by more than two thirds. Why has the strike disappeared, and what does that mean for us now? Since the 1980s, the forces of economic globalization, technological change, and corporate re-structuring have all put increasing pressure on the employment rela- tionship. None of those forces by themselves, however, need automatically lead to the disappearance of either strikes or unions, as the comparative experience of other industrialized countries shows. Rather, the most important cause has been the profound change in the legal and institutional regime governing labor relations and workers’ rights in the U.S. The strike has been transformed from an economic bargaining tactic and protected legal right to a more high-risk confrontation, in which the issues at stake are no longer the dollars-and-cents on the table but the continued existence of the collective bargaining relationship. To understand these changes, we first need to acknowledge that our tradi- tional notions of strikes are either poor caricatures or badly out of date. We can then illustrate the historic shift by recalling how the New Deal system of labor relations was supposed to work, and how it stabilized under the so-called post- World War II labor “accord.” From the beginning, however, a rival, anti-union path of institutional development grew alongside and apart from the New Deal order. The balance of power shifted in the 1980s, with the ascendancy of the anti- union regime. Backed by Republican administrations and increasingly conserva- tive federal courts, employers began not only to resist unions in unorganized sec- tors but to try to eliminate unions where they were already established. The attempt to de-unionize in the private sector was largely successful, and set the stage for the current attacks on public-sector unions and collective bargaining rights. The effects of the anti-union regime are far-reaching: The de- Brought to you by | Fordham University Library Published by De Gruyter, 2012 Authenticated Download Date | 4/10/15 5:14 PM 2 The Forum Vol. 10 [2012], No. 1, Article 8 cline of unionization is a major factor in the rise of American economic inequality and the stagnation of earnings among middle and lower income groups. More than that, the political consequences are as important as the economic ones. The loss of workers’ rights to bargain collectively and to strike represents a significant de-democratization of American society, in the institutional governance of the workplace and in the civic ecology of the community. How We Misunderstand Strikes The disappearance of the strike is an historic event, but one that is scarcely re- ported in the mainstream news. The typical news coverage of labor issues, media scholar Christopher Martin (2004) writes, commonly tells a story organized by certain value assumptions or frames. These include, first, that the “consumer is king,” meaning that readers are addressed in terms of the values of individual pri- vate consumption. Second, the experience of consumption is divorced from the process of production. Except for the occasional scandal affecting consumer safe- ty, how goods and services arrive in the market is generally invisible and is not a matter of public concern. Since production occurs mostly offstage, the principal actors in the economy appear instead to be the “heroic” Wall Street titans and corporate CEOs that dominate the daily business news. For everyone else, the labor market is presumed to be meritocratic, and mobility is the result of individu- al choice. If workers do not like their job, they can and should just get another, using whatever bootstraps they may have. By contrast, collective economic action by definition is bad, and upsets the “natural” equilibrium of the free market. As Martin argues, these assumptions inform the ways the media cover labor disputes, especially strikes. Underlying conflicts of interest between busi- ness and labor are often left unexamined in favor of the clash of personalities among management and union leaders. Reports of negotiations highlight the em- ployers’ market-driven “offers,” while union “demands” seem like unreasonable claims for special privilege. As a result, strikes often appear as unnecessary or ego-driven conflicts led by fist-pounding union “bosses” demanding “More!” The government, meanwhile, stands apart and is mainly responsible to minimize pub- lic (i.e. consumer) inconvenience and the threat of disorder, even if this means forcing strikers to return to work. These kinds of narratives are familiar, but they also reduce the struggles of entire industries and communities to the personalities and egos of a few (usually) men. In addition, hidden within them are social science concepts that continue to shape our understanding of strikes. For example, economic theories of strikes generally begin with a market relationship in which employers and unions bargain the price of labor. Each party is assumed to enjoy organizational security, act ra- tionally, and calculate the costs and benefits of the decision to strike. Ideally, Brought to you by | Fordham University Library Authenticated Download Date | 4/10/15 5:14 PM Rhomberg: What Has Happened to the Strike? 3 through negotiation both sides should be able to estimate each other’s room for concessions and thereby reach agreement without enduring the actual costs of a strike. In this model, the key questions are first, the sheer incidence of strikes (or why they should occur at all), and second, the strong correlation of strike frequen- cy with short-term fluctuations in the business cycle (that is, strikes increase in a growing economy when labor markets are tight and wages lag behind inflation, and decrease in downturns when unemployment is high). For the first question, the conventional answer suggests some form of error or failure in bargaining, due to imperfect or uncertain information or the behavioral irrationality of one or both sides. Some economists stress the role of long-term bargaining relationships or coordination in reducing uncertainty. Others distinguish union leaders from the rank-and-file and assign imperfect information to the latter: Impelled to strike by restive members, leaders must balance workers’ wage demands with the econom- ic needs of the firm. This makes the bargaining relationship one-sided— employers are presumed to act with market efficiency while only workers must change their concessions to come around to an acceptable compromise (Ashenfelter and Johnson 1969; Franzosi 1989). Nevertheless, such imagery dominates both ordinary and legal interpreta- tions of unions and strikes: Collective bargaining is a private contest with stable set of participants and rules, like a regular Friday night poker game among friends.