On the Optimality of a Dominant Unit of Account∗

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

On the Optimality of a Dominant Unit of Account∗ On the Optimality of a Dominant Unit of Account¤ Matthias Doepke Martin Schneider Northwestern University Stanford University June 2009 Abstract We develop a theory that gives rise to an endogenous unit of account. Agents enter into non-contingent contracts with a variety of business part- ners. Trade unfolds sequentially and is subject to random matching. By using a unified unit of account, agents can lower their exposure to relative price risk, avoid costly default, and create more total surplus. We discuss the use of a unified unit of account in intertemporal trade and the robustness of a unit of account when there is aggregate price-level uncertainty. ¤Preliminary and incomplete. Financial support from the National Science Foundation (grant SES-0519265) and the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. Doepke: Depart- ment of Economics, Northwestern University, 2001 Sheridan Road, Evanston, IL 60208 (e-mail: [email protected]). Schneider: Department of Economics, Stanford University, Landau Economics Building, 579 Serra Mall, Stanford, CA 94305 (e-mail: [email protected]). 1 Introduction An important function of money is to serve as a unit of account. Within countries, contracts tend to be denominated in a common unit. Most often, the medium of exchange also serves as the unit of account. However, the function of unit of account is logically separate from money’s role as a medium of exchange. In addition, there are many examples of the use of a unit of account that is different from the medium of exchange. In some cases, the currency of another country can serve as a unit of account. One example of this is the use of the U.S. dollar in foreign trade relationships not involving the United States. There are even examples of units of accounts that do not correspond to the medium of exchange of any country. Well-known example include the livre tournois in France, which was used as a unit of account for many years even when no corresponding coin was in circulation, and the ECU (European Currency Unit), which was based on a basket of European currencies and served as a unit of account in European Trade before the introduction of the Euro. Most models of money focus on the medium-of-exchange role of money. In con- trast, this paper develops a theory of the emergence of a unified unit of account. In our view, a key function of a unified unit of account is to lower relative-price risk in agents’ balance sheets. Production often takes place in chains, where pro- ducers enter into various contracts with both their suppliers and their customers. We describe an environment where such contracts are non-contingent, and where default is costly. In addition, contracting is non-synchronized, in the sense that agents meet their business partners sequentially and do not know everybody who they will interact with when contracting starts. We show that in such an environment, the adoption of a unified unit of account can serve to minimize relative-price risk, leading to more opportunities for trade and less need for col- lateral. Our work is related to a small literature on the optimality of nominal contracts. Jovanovic and Ueda (1997) consider a static moral hazard problem in which nom- inal output is observed before the price level (and therefore real output) is re- vealed. In addition, contracts are not negotiation proof, so that principal and 1 agent have an incentive to renegotiate after nominal output is observed. In par- ticular, in the optimal renegotiation-proof solution the principal offers full insur- ance to the agent once nominal output is known. This implies that the real wage depends on nominal output, so that the contract can be interpreted as a nomi- nal contract. Freeman and Tabellini (1998) consider an overlapping-generations economy with spatially separated agents in which fiat money serves as a medium of exchange. The authors show that under several particular circumstances it is then also optimal to use fiat money as a unit of account. Unlike these papers, in our theory neither delays in observation of prices or the use of money as a medium of exchange plays any role. Instead, we emphasize the use of a uni- fied unit of account to lower the relative-price risk that economic agents carry on their balance sheets, leading to more possibilities for exchange and less need for collateral. 2 The Model 2.1 Environment The model economy extends over two dates, 0 and 1. The economy is populated by two groups of agents, farmers and artisans. There is a finite set © of different types of farmers enumerated by A; B; : : : as well as a finite number n of different types of artisans enumerated by 1; 2; : : : n. There is a continuum of agents of each type; the mass of type i agents is denoted ¹i. An individual agent is identified by a pair (i; ¶), where ¶ 2 [0; ¹i]. The size of the set © and the number of artisans will be specified below when we study specific examples. Each agent is endowed with one unit of labor at date 0. Each type has a tech- nology that uses labor to make a good that is specific to him. We label a good by the type who produces it, that is, there are farm goods A; B; : : : and artisanal goods 1; 2;:::. An artisan makes his specific artisanal good one-for-one from la- bor. A farmer can use one unit of labor to produce 1 + θ units of his specific farm good. Instead of making his specific good, an agent may also use labor one-for- one to produce a numeraire good 0. Labor allocated to making the specific good 2 is denoted h and must be either zero or one; the remaining time 1 ¡ h is enjoyed as leisure. In some examples below, we also assume that an agent of type i is endowed with ki units of good zero that can be stored at no cost until date 1. The key difference between farmers and artisans is in how their specific goods are sold. Farm goods can be sold in a spot market that opens at date 1. In the spot market, farm good i can be exchanged into good 0 at price pi. The price pi is stochastic and given exogenously. The vector of all farm good prices is denoted by p. In contrast, artisans produce customized goods for a particular customer. At date 0, before production takes place, every artisan (i; ¶) is matched to one potential customer. If the artisan agrees to make and supply his artisanal product to the matched customer at date 1, no other agent can obtain utility from that product at date 1. In particular, an artisan cannot produce artisanal products for himself. The details of the matching process are described below. For now, we summarize the outcome of matching by a function c, where c(i; ¶) denotes the index pair of agent (i; ¶)’s customer. Since matching will be one-to-one, there is an inverse function s such that s(i; ¶) identifies an agent’s potential supplier of an artisanal good. The role of artisans and artisanal goods in the model is to generate a need for credit. Indeed, an artisan must commit to work at date 0 to produce the cus- tomized (nontradable) good at date 1. Moreover, the customer does not have sufficient tradable goods at date 0 to pay for the customized good up front. Ex- change must thus be arranged through a system of forward contracts. The role of farmers and farm goods in the model is twofold. First, farm goods have quoted prices, so that contract can be denominated in farm goods. In contrast, the cus- tomized artisanal goods are not traded in spot markets and contracts cannot be denominated in them. Second, farmers are naturally exposed to aggregate risk induced by price volatility.1 Price risk will matter because default on forward contracts is costly. Our analysis will consider how exchange can be organized in the economy to optimally deal with price risk. 1Price volatility is the only source of aggregate risk in our model. In addition, there is idiosyn- cratic risk from the matching process, to be discussed below. 3 The utility function of a type i agent (farmer or artisan) is given by: Xn u(x0; x; h) = x0 + (1 + θ) xl ¡ h: l=1 Here x0 is consumption of numeraire good and xl is consumption of the cus- tomized good produced by artisan l. Since every agent will be matched to one supplier, a feasible allocation has an agent (i; ¶) consume a positive amount of at most one artisan good, namely that produced by his supplier s(i; ¶). Given that the utility cost of production is one, assuming θ > 0 ensures that producing artisan goods in a match is optimal. Since all agents in the model are risk neutral, a concern with price risk will arise exclusively from costs of default. We have also assumed that no agent consumes farm goods. One interpretation is that farm goods are monies, and that farmers actually produce other goods that they sell to agents outside the model in ex- change for money. As a result, their revenue is in money. The exogenous farm prices would then represent exchange rates between different monies and good 0. A feasible allocation must respect the technology of the agents as well as the outcomes of the matching process. The latter generates a network that links sup- pliers and customers at date 0, and prohibits trades of artisanal goods except through those links.
Recommended publications
  • Monetary Policy in Economies with Little Or No Money
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY IN ECONOMIES WITH LITTLE OR NO MONEY Bennett T. McCallum Working Paper 9838 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9838 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2003 This paper was prepared for presentation at the December 16-17, 2002, meeting of the Hong Kong Economic Association. I am indebted to Marvin Goodfriend, Lok Sang Ho, Allan Meltzer, and Edward Nelson for helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research ©2003 by Bennett T. McCallum. All rights reserved. Short sections of text not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit including © notice, is given to the source. Monetary Policy in Economies with Little or No Money Bennett T. McCallum NBER Working Paper No. 9838 July 2003 JEL No. E3, E4, E5 ABSTRACT The paper's arguments include: (1) Medium-of-exchange money will not disappear in the foreseeable future, although the quantity of base money may continue to decline. (2) In economies with very little money (e.g., no currency but bank settlement balances at the central bank), monetary policy will be conducted much as at present by activist adjustment of overnight interest rates. Operating procedures will be different, however, with payment of interest on reserves likely to become the norm. (3) In economies without any money there can be no monetary policy. The relevant notion of a general price level concerns some index of prices in terms of a medium of account.
    [Show full text]
  • Cryptocurrency: the Economics of Money and Selected Policy Issues
    Cryptocurrency: The Economics of Money and Selected Policy Issues Updated April 9, 2020 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov R45427 SUMMARY R45427 Cryptocurrency: The Economics of Money and April 9, 2020 Selected Policy Issues David W. Perkins Cryptocurrencies are digital money in electronic payment systems that generally do not require Specialist in government backing or the involvement of an intermediary, such as a bank. Instead, users of the Macroeconomic Policy system validate payments using certain protocols. Since the 2008 invention of the first cryptocurrency, Bitcoin, cryptocurrencies have proliferated. In recent years, they experienced a rapid increase and subsequent decrease in value. One estimate found that, as of March 2020, there were more than 5,100 different cryptocurrencies worth about $231 billion. Given this rapid growth and volatility, cryptocurrencies have drawn the attention of the public and policymakers. A particularly notable feature of cryptocurrencies is their potential to act as an alternative form of money. Historically, money has either had intrinsic value or derived value from government decree. Using money electronically generally has involved using the private ledgers and systems of at least one trusted intermediary. Cryptocurrencies, by contrast, generally employ user agreement, a network of users, and cryptographic protocols to achieve valid transfers of value. Cryptocurrency users typically use a pseudonymous address to identify each other and a passcode or private key to make changes to a public ledger in order to transfer value between accounts. Other computers in the network validate these transfers. Through this use of blockchain technology, cryptocurrency systems protect their public ledgers of accounts against manipulation, so that users can only send cryptocurrency to which they have access, thus allowing users to make valid transfers without a centralized, trusted intermediary.
    [Show full text]
  • Law-And-Political-Economy Framework: Beyond the Twentieth-Century Synthesis Abstract
    JEDEDIAH BRITTON- PURDY, DAVID SINGH GREWAL, AMY KAPCZYNSKI & K. SABEEL RAHMAN Building a Law-and-Political-Economy Framework: Beyond the Twentieth-Century Synthesis abstract. We live in a time of interrelated crises. Economic inequality and precarity, and crises of democracy, climate change, and more raise significant challenges for legal scholarship and thought. “Neoliberal” premises undergird many fields of law and have helped authorize policies and practices that reaffirm the inequities of the current era. In particular, market efficiency, neu- trality, and formal equality have rendered key kinds of power invisible, and generated a skepticism of democratic politics. The result of these presumptions is what we call the “Twentieth-Century Synthesis”: a pervasive view of law that encases “the market” from claims of justice and conceals it from analyses of power. This Feature offers a framework for identifying and critiquing the Twentieth-Century Syn- thesis. This is also a framework for a new “law-and-political-economy approach” to legal scholar- ship. We hope to help amplify and catalyze scholarship and pedagogy that place themes of power, equality, and democracy at the center of legal scholarship. authors. The authors are, respectively, William S. Beinecke Professor of Law at Columbia Law School; Professor of Law at Berkeley Law School; Professor of Law at Yale Law School; and Associate Professor of Law at Brooklyn Law School and President, Demos. They are cofounders of the Law & Political Economy Project. The authors thank Anne Alstott, Jack Balkin, Jessica Bulman- Pozen, Corinne Blalock, Angela Harris, Luke Herrine, Doug Kysar, Zach Liscow, Daniel Markovits, Bill Novak, Frank Pasquale, Robert Post, David Pozen, Aziz Rana, Kate Redburn, Reva Siegel, Talha Syed, John Witt, and the participants of the January 2019 Law and Political Economy Work- shop at Yale Law School for their comments on drafts at many stages of the project.
    [Show full text]
  • Like a Good Neighbor: Monetary Policy, Financial Stability, and the Distribution of Risk”
    Discussion of “Like a Good Neighbor: Monetary Policy, Financial Stability, and the Distribution of Risk” Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel Institute of Economics, Catholic University of Chile 1. This Paper This paper develops an elegant model on a relevant issue. The issue is a specific market failure—the lack of inflation-indexed debt— which, combined with real output uncertainty, precludes optimal risk sharing among consumers hit by idiosyncratic shocks. The paper starts with a benchmark two-period consumption and risk-sharing model under complete markets for a closed economy where agents are hit by idiosyncratic output shocks. By trading state-contingent Arrow-Debreu assets, idiosyncratic risk is completely traded away and the economy attains the first-best Pareto-optimal general equi- librium. This model follows closely the world asset trading model due to Lucas (1982) (nicely presented in chapter 5 of Obstfeld and Rogoff 1996), where two countries hit by idiosyncratic output shocks engage in first-best international exchange of state-contingent Arrow-Debreu assets. Then the paper shows that when debt contracts are not specified in real (or inflation-indexed) terms but only in nominal terms (as observed in most financial markets), risk sharing is incomplete and the first-best equilibrium cannot be attained. Does inflation or nom- inal income targeting pursued by a monetary authority restore the first-best equilibrium when only nominal debt is available? Not when the central bank monetary authority targets inflation (or the price level). However, when the central bank targets nominal income, engi- neering real-time inflation perfectly and negatively correlated with real output, the first-best equilibrium is reestablished.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: a Marxist Critique
    Class, Race and Corporate Power Volume 7 Issue 1 Article 1 2019 Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Michael Roberts [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Roberts, Michael (2019) "Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique," Class, Race and Corporate Power: Vol. 7 : Iss. 1 , Article 1. DOI: 10.25148/CRCP.7.1.008316 Available at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower/vol7/iss1/1 This work is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts, Sciences & Education at FIU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Class, Race and Corporate Power by an authorized administrator of FIU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Abstract Compiled from a series of blog posts which can be found at "The Next Recession." Modern monetary theory (MMT) has become flavor of the time among many leftist economic views in recent years. MMT has some traction in the left as it appears to offer theoretical support for policies of fiscal spending funded yb central bank money and running up budget deficits and public debt without earf of crises – and thus backing policies of government spending on infrastructure projects, job creation and industry in direct contrast to neoliberal mainstream policies of austerity and minimal government intervention. Here I will offer my view on the worth of MMT and its policy implications for the labor movement. First, I’ll try and give broad outline to bring out the similarities and difference with Marx’s monetary theory.
    [Show full text]
  • Virtual Currencies – Key Definitions and Potential Aml/Cft Risks
    FATF REPORT Virtual Currencies Key Definitions and Potential AML/CFT Risks June 2014 FINANCIAL ACTION TASK FORCE The Financial Action Task Force (FATF) is an independent inter-governmental body that develops and promotes policies to protect the global financial system against money laundering, terrorist financing and the financing of proliferation of weapons of mass destruction. The FATF Recommendations are recognised as the global anti-money laundering (AML) and counter-terrorist financing (CFT) standard. For more information about the FATF, please visit the website: www.fatf-gafi.org © 2014 FATF/OECD. All rights reserved. No reproduction or translation of this publication may be made without prior written permission. Applications for such permission, for all or part of this publication, should be made to the FATF Secretariat, 2 rue André Pascal 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France (fax: +33 1 44 30 61 37 or e-mail: [email protected]). Photocredits coverphoto: ©Thinkstock VIRTUAL CURRENCIES – KEY DEFINITIONS AND POTENTIAL AML/CFT RISKS CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................................... 3 KEY DEFINITIONS: ................................................................................................................................ 3 Virtual Currency .................................................................................................................................... 4 Convertible Versus Non-Convertible Virtual Currency ........................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • IRS Notice 2014-21
    1 Notice 2014-21 SECTION 1. PURPOSE This notice describes how existing general tax principles apply to transactions using virtual currency. The notice provides this guidance in the form of answers to frequently asked questions. SECTION 2. BACKGROUND The Internal Revenue Service (IRS) is aware that “virtual currency” may be used to pay for goods or services, or held for investment. Virtual currency is a digital representation of value that functions as a medium of exchange, a unit of account, and/or a store of value. In some environments, it operates like “real” currency -- i.e., the coin and paper money of the United States or of any other country that is designated as legal tender, circulates, and is customarily used and accepted as a medium of exchange in the country of issuance -- but it does not have legal tender status in any jurisdiction. Virtual currency that has an equivalent value in real currency, or that acts as a substitute for real currency, is referred to as “convertible” virtual currency. Bitcoin is one example of a convertible virtual currency. Bitcoin can be digitally traded between users and can be purchased for, or exchanged into, U.S. dollars, Euros, and other real or virtual currencies. For a more comprehensive description of convertible virtual currencies to date, see Financial Crimes Enforcement Network (FinCEN) Guidance on the Application of FinCEN’s Regulations to Persons Administering, Exchanging, or Using Virtual Currencies (FIN-2013-G001, March 18, 2013). SECTION 3. SCOPE In general, the sale or exchange of convertible virtual currency, or the use of convertible virtual currency to pay for goods or services in a real-world economy transaction, has tax consequences that may result in a tax liability.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Digital Currency in Historical Perspective: Another Crossroad in Monetary History1
    Central Bank Digital Currency in Historical Perspective: Another Crossroad in Monetary History1 Michael D. Bordo, Rutgers University, NBER and Hoover Institution, Stanford University Economics Working Paper 21113 HOOVER INSTITUTION 434 GALVEZ MALL STANFORD UNIVERSITY STANFORD, CA 94305-6010 July 14, 2021 Digitalization of Money is a crossroad in monetary history. Advances in technology has led to the development of new forms of money: virtual (crypto) currencies like bitcoin; stable coins like libra/diem; and central bank digital currencies (CBDC) like the Bahamian sand dollar. These innovations in money and finance have resonance to earlier shifts in monetary history: 1) The shift in the eighteenth and nineteenth century from commodity money (gold and silver coins) to convertible fiduciary money and inconvertible fiat money; 2) the shift in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries from central bank notes to a central bank monopoly;3) Then evolution since the seventeenth century of central banks and the tools of monetary policy. This paper makes the case for CBDC through the lens of monetary history. The bottom line is that the history of transformations in monetary systems suggests that technical change in money is inevitably driven by the financial incentives of a market economy. Government has always had a key role in the provision of outside money, which is a public good. Government has also regulated inside money provided by the private sector. This held for fiduciary money and will likely hold for digital money. CBDC could make monetary policy more efficient, and it could transform the international monetary and payments systems. Keywords: digitalization, financial innovation, evolution, central banks, monetary policy, international payments JEL Codes: E5, F4, N2.
    [Show full text]
  • Bitcoin and the Myths of Neoliberalism
    Bitcoin and the Myths of Neoliberalism Mary Mellor ITCOIN AS THE INITIATOR OF A WAVE OF CRYPTOCURRENCIES EMERGED AT A VERY critical moment. In 2009 neoliberal, financialised globalisation with its B anti-state, laissez faire ethos was faltering. The financial crisis had threatened the stability of the banking system and thereby the money supply. Bitcoin seemed to offer something quite distinctive, a new form of money. As a private digital currency, Bitcoin was designed to be purely a technical mechanism linking anonymous users. The complex computer programme on which it is based does not require the authority of a state or the intermediation of a bank. It does not need a location or a headquarters. However, although its technology is innovative, the ethos of Bitcoin is rooted in neoliberalism. Bitcoin is presented as a passive enabler of individualised market exchange. This focus on the market chimes with neoliberal ‘handbag economics’. Handbag economics adopts the gendered analogy of the public sector as being like a household dependent on the market as the breadwinner. The assumption is that all the funding for public expenditure is drawn from the market. This is a zero-sum view. Money spent in the public sector is seen as a drain of money from the private sector. It is assumed that there is a limited pool of money, that money is inherently in short supply. The state must therefore be as small as possible. Requests to increase public funding are often met by the question ‘where’s the money to come from?’ and the claim that there is no ‘magic money tree’.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Bank Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles and Core Features
    Central bank digital currencies: foundational principles and core features Bank of Canada European Central Bank Bank of Japan Report no 1 Sveriges Riksbank in a series of collaborations Swiss National Bank from a group of central banks Bank of England Board of Governors Federal Reserve System Bank for International Settlements This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2020. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISBN: 978-92-9259-427-5 (online) Contents Executive summary ........................................................................................................................................................................... 1 1. Introduction ...................................................................................................................................................................... 2 1.1 The report ................................................................................................................................................................. 3 1.2 CBDC explained ...................................................................................................................................................... 3 “Synthetic CBDC” is not a CBDC .................................................................................................................................................. 4 2. Motivations, challenges and risks ............................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 10: Money and Banking Section 1 Objectives
    Chapter 10: Money and Banking Section 1 Objectives 1. Describe the three uses of money. 2. List the six characteristics of money. 3. Analyze the sources of money’s values. Chapter 10, Section 1 Copyright © Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 2 Key Terms • money: anything that serves as a medium of exchange, a unit of account, and a store of value • medium of exchange: anything that is used to determine value during the exchange of goods and services • barter: the direct exchange of one set of goods or services for another • unit of account: a means for comparing the values of goods and services • store of value: something that keeps its value if it is stored rather than spent Chapter 10, Section 1 Copyright © Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 3 Key Terms, cont. • currency: coins and paper bills used as money • commodity money: objects that have value in and of themselves and that are also used as money • representative money: objects that have value because the holder can exchange them for something else of value • specie: coined money, usually gold or silver, used to back paper money • fiat money: objects that have value because a government has decreed that they are an acceptable means to pay debts Chapter 10, Section 1 Copyright © Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 4 Introduction • How does money serve the needs of our society? – Money provides means for comparing values of goods and services. – Money also serves as a store of value. – Without money, we wouldn’t be able to get the things that we need and want. Chapter 10, Section 1 Copyright © Pearson Education, Inc.
    [Show full text]
  • Four Phases in the History of Money V3
    Four Phases in the History of Money Luis Angeles * January 2019 Abstract In this paper I offer a new characterisation of the history of money into four major phases, from the earliest written records during the 3 rd millennium BC to the present day. This characterization sheds light on both the nature and the evolution of money, and helps us to understand today’s monetary arrangements. Money evolves over time as the media of exchange in use change from metal to coinage and from coinage to different forms of debt, and as the unit of account becomes more or less linked to the value of a commodity or a physical object. * Adam Smith Business School (Economics), University of Glasgow. University Avenue, Glasgow G12 8QQ, United Kingdom. Email: [email protected] 1 1. Introduction This paper organizes the history of money into four phases or eras, from the 3 rd millennium BC to the present day. Doing so not only enhances our understanding of how money has evolved over time; it also clarifies our views about the nature of money and renders our current monetary system intelligible. Although the literature on the history of money is vast, the characterization presented here is novel and gives a unifying thread to monetary arrangements over all recorded human history. Economists typically define money as “any asset that can easily be used to purchase goods and services” (Krugman and Wells 2006, p. 722). Money is then said to fulfil several functions, notably those of serving as a medium of exchange, a unit of account, and a store of value.
    [Show full text]