Durham E-Theses

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Durham E-Theses Durham E-Theses The development of American institutional economics Rutherford, Malcolm How to cite: Rutherford, Malcolm (1979) The development of American institutional economics, Durham theses, Durham University. Available at Durham E-Theses Online: http://etheses.dur.ac.uk/7908/ Use policy The full-text may be used and/or reproduced, and given to third parties in any format or medium, without prior permission or charge, for personal research or study, educational, or not-for-prot purposes provided that: • a full bibliographic reference is made to the original source • a link is made to the metadata record in Durham E-Theses • the full-text is not changed in any way The full-text must not be sold in any format or medium without the formal permission of the copyright holders. Please consult the full Durham E-Theses policy for further details. Academic Support Oce, Durham University, University Oce, Old Elvet, Durham DH1 3HP e-mail: [email protected] Tel: +44 0191 334 6107 http://etheses.dur.ac.uk THE DEVELOPMENT OF AMERICAN INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS by MALCOLM RUTHERFORD B.A. Heriot-Watt University, 1971. M.A. Simon Fraser University, 1973. A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED IN FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY In the Department of Economics University of Durham. 1979 . c Malcolm Rutherford 1979. The copyright of this thesis rests with the author. No quotation from it should be published without his prior written consent and information derived from it should be acknowledged. ABSTRACT Institutional economics is a particularly ill-defined concept, and a great deal of disagreement surrounds its meaning. Both the nature and development of institutional economics have been t'he subject of dispute for some sixty years; even those who claim to be institutionalists do not always agree on these issues. This thesis is an examination of the development and nature of American institutionalism. It proceeds through a detailed study of the intellectual currents in nineteenth century America which gave rise to the movement, and the work of those writers generally accepted as institutionalists. Most attention is given to T. lieblen, W.H. Hamilton, W.C. Mitchell, J.R. Commons, R.G. Tugwell, and C.E. Ayres. It is argued that institutionalism grew out of the impact of evolutionism and historicism in American thought. These factors resulted in the development of the "new school" of German influenced scholars, the work of Thorstein l/eblen, and the rise of pragmatism. Institutionalism is a combination of l/eblenism, pragmatism, and the ideas of new school writers such as R.T. Ely and H.C. Adams. The examination of the work of the major institutionalists reveals that while they do share a core of very general method• ological and economic views, there are a number of points of significant variation. It is also noticeable that the economic theories that institutionalism contains are not rigorously developed and contain many weaknesses. The thesis contends that institutionalism can best be seen as a broad movement con• taining within itself a number of distinguishable "wings," "groups," or "traditions." Its failure to develop a greater degree of coherence and more satisfactory theoretical ideas is attributed to the problems inherent in the epistemological and methodological positions adopted by its members. i v • TABLE OF CONTENTS Acknowledgement v 1 . Introduction 1 2. Background to Institutionalism 10 3. The New School, R.T. Ely, H.C. Adams, and S.N. Patten 66 4. Thorstein l/eblen's Evolutionary Economics 113 5. Walton Hamilton and the Formation of the Institutionalist Concept 158 6. Wesley Mitchell: Institutionalism and Quantitative Economics 190 7. John R. Commons: Institutionalism and Collective Action 234 B. Rexford G. Tugwell: Institutionalism and Economic Planning 296 9. Clarence Ayres: Institutionalism, Technology, and Progress 349 10. The Nature and Development of Institutional Economics 391 Bibliography 420 ACKNOWLEDGEMENT I would like to acknowledge the invaluable assistance of my thesis supervisor, Professor Denis O'Brien of the University of Durham. His interest, guidance, and willingness to devote his time to my mork, made writing this thesis a much more pleasurable task than would otherwise have been the case. I must also thank Professor Allan Gruchy of the University of Maryland for arranging my stay in College Park, which gave me access to research material I could not have obtained in Britain, and for all the comments and suggestions he made on my work. Any errors still remaining are, of course, solely my own res• ponsibility . My acknowledgements would not be complete without mentioning my wife's continuous support and encouragement, and her typing of the draft and the final version of the thesis. CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION Institutional economics has been a source of considerable perplexity for the student of economic thought ever since the term was first introduced into the literature by Walton Hamilton 1 in 1919. The major problem has aliuays been that there is remarkably little agreement concerning exactly what institutionalism is. This lack of agreement, it should be noted, extends well into the ranks of those who call themselves institutionalists. In Walton Hamilton's original article institutional economics was defined in terms of a very broad approach to the subject of economics. Institutional economics was, for Hamilton, the attempt to develop a theory of the "economic order,which involved (1) the concept of "process" or cumulative evolutionary change, (2) the study of institutions, (3) a concern for "social control" or problem solving, and (4) the use of the findings of "modern psychology" concerning the role of habituation in human behaviour.^ Hamilton admitted that no consistent body of institutionalist doctrine existed at that time, but he held out the hope that one 1. W.H. Hamilton, "The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory," reprinted in Industrial Policy and Institutionalism (Clifton, 1974), pp.187-198. 2. Ibid., p.190. 3. Ibid., pp.190-196. 2 . would eventually be arrived at. Among those contributing to the beginnings of this institutional economics Hamilton listed Thorstein l/eblen, Wesley Mitchell, and various other dissenters 4 from economic orthodoxy. In the 1920's and 1930's institutionalism attracted many adherents, so much so that L. Robbins was moved to complain of the "wide area of power" held by institutionalists in American economics.'' However, the movement, as even institutionalists admitted, was extremely diverse, and many attempts were made to define the common elements in institutionalist thought and to discover if any progress had been made toward developing what could be called a body of institutionalist economic theory.^ Most non-institutionalist investigators found little evidence of any definable institutional theory, and many characterised the movement as consisting largely of historical, descriptive, or quantitative investigations of particular institutions, combined 7 with a dislike of abstract theorising. It must be said that institutionalists themselves did much to contribute to this negative Q appraisal, although some writers argued that the characterisation 4. Ibid . , pp.197-198. 5. L. Robbins, An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science (London, 1932), p.104. 6. See for instance the Round Table Conferences, "Institution• alism: What It Is and What It Hopes to Become," American Economic Review 21, Supp. (1931): 134-141; and "Institutional Economics," American Economic Review 22, supp. (1932): 105-116. See also L.D. Edie, "The Institutional Concept," Quarterly Journal of Economics 41 (1927): 405-440; and Paul Homan, "An Appraisal of Institutional Economics," American Economic Review 22 (1932): 10-17; 3.R. Commons, "Institutional Economics," American Economic Review 21 (1931): 648-657; and the comments by J.E. Shafer, 3.R. Commons, and N.L. Silverstein in the American Economic Review 22 (1932): 261-269. 7. P. Homan, op.cit., pp.12-17; 3.3. Spengler, in "Institution• alism: What It Is and What It Hopes to Become," op.cit., pp.135-137; L. Robbins, op.cit., p.104. 8. For example, L.D. Edie, op • cit., pp.405-440; N.L. Silverstein, 3 . aias inadequate, particularly with respect to the theoretical 9 content to be found in Ueblen's work. A.L. Harris, for instance, argued that Veblen had more in common with Marx than with other 1 0 institutionalists, and, as Ueblen is frequently regarded as the "father" of institutionalism, such ideas created problems in the understanding of the development of institutionalism and in the 1 1 location of the sources of institutionalist thought. Despite these difficulties, the view of institutionalism as essentially descriptive and lacking in theory took hold in many 1 2 textbooks. What is more, the growth of institutionalism was checked at the end of the 1930's, and the movement declined in importance. This led some commentators to conclude that 1 3 institutionalism was dying out. As is now quite clear such judgements were considerably premature. In the post-1945 period institutionalism has gradually made itself felt once more, and institutionalists are now well represented in organisations such as the Association for Evolutionary Economics and in the pages of "An Appraisal of Institutional Economics: Comment," American Economic Review 22 (1932): 268-269; W.E. Atkins et al., Economic Behavior, An Institutional Approach (Boston, 1931)} see also D. Hamilton, "Why is Institutional Economics Mot Institutional?," American Journal of Economics and Sociology 12 (1962): 312. 9. D R Scott, "Veblen Not An Institutional Economist," American Economic Review 23 (1933): 274-277;K.L. Anderson, "The Unity of l/eblen's Theoretical System," Quarterly Journal of Economics 47 (1933): 598-626. 10. A.L. Harris, "Types of Institutionalism," Journal of Political Economy 40 (1932): 721-749. 11. See for instance E. Roll, A History of Economic Thought, 4th ed. (London, 1973), p.453. Roll is forced to speculate on the existence of an "oral tradition" linking Ueblen to the later institutionalists.
Recommended publications
  • “Original Institutional Economics” in the Post-World War II Period and the Perspectives of Today,’ Economic Thought, 7.1, Pp
    Economic Thought 7.1: 63-86, 2018 The Decline of the ‘Original Institutional Economics’ in the Post-World War II Period and the Perspectives of Today1 Arturo Hermann, Italian National Institute of Statistics, Rome, Italy [email protected] Abstract Original, or ‘old’, institutional economics (OIE) – also known as ‘institutionalism’ – played a key role in its early stages; it could be said that it was once the ‘mainstream economics’ of the time. This period ran approximately from the first important contributions of Thorstein Veblen in 1898 to the implementation of the New Deal in the early 1930s, where many institutionalists played a significant role. However, notwithstanding its promising scientific and institutional affirmation, institutional economics underwent a period of marked decline that spanned from the mid-1930s to the late 1980s, when a new season for institutional economics was set in motion. In order to cast some light on this complex issue – without any claim of completeness – we have organised the work as follows: in the first section we consider the main interpretations of this phenomenon. In the subsequent sections we analyse a number of ‘endogenous’ aspects which might have played a significant role in the period of decline: (i) the relations of institutional economics with Keynes’s macroeconomic theory; (ii) the links between theoretical and empirical analysis and the supposed lack of a clear theory; (iii) the interdisciplinary orientation. Keywords: Original institutional economics, social valuation, political economy, interdisciplinarity JEL Codes: B25, B41, B52, E61 1. The Decline of Institutionalism and the Main Existing Interpretations The Ascendance and Decline of Institutionalism Institutional economics originated in the United States in the first decades of the 20th century.
    [Show full text]
  • Effective Competition and Corporate Disclosure A
    EFFECTIVE COMPETITION AND CORPORATE DISCLOSURE A CRITICAL STUDY by RAZAHUSSEIN M, DEVJI B. Sc. (Econ)», University of London, 1961 Barrister-at-Law, Honourable Society of Middle Temple, London, 1962 A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION In the Faculty of Graduate Studies We accept this thesis as conforming to the required staricTardT THE UNIVERSITY OF BRITISH COLUMBIA September, 1968 In presenting this thesis in partial ful• filment of the requirements for an advanced degree at the University of British Columbia, I agree that the Library shall make it freely available for reference and study* I further agree that permission for ex• tensive copying of this thesis for scholarly purposes may be granted by the Head of my Department or by his representatives. It is understood that copying or publication of this thesis for financial gain shall not be allowed without my written permission. Faculty of Commerce and Business Administration, The University of British Columbia, Vancouver 8, B. C. Canada. ABSTRACT Economic activity in the United States and Canada is predominantly performed by corporations. They are by far the largest private employers of workers, the biggest investors and the predominant instrument of production. They are rapidly growing in size, are generating sufficient funds internally to carry out most of their expansion programs, and are diversifying into unrelated activities. Their affairs are increasingly managed by professional executives who have little, if any, stake In the risk capital. The shareholders, who are legally pre• sumed to exercise control over the powers and actions of corporate executives, are normally too numerous and scattered so as not to be in a position to have a significant influence on the policies of the corporations.
    [Show full text]
  • The Death of the Firm
    Article The Death of the Firm June Carbone† & Nancy Levit†† INTRODUCTION A corporation is simply a form of organization used by human beings to achieve desired ends. An established body of law specifies the rights and obligations of the people (including shareholders, officers, and employees) who are associated with a corporation in one way or another. When rights, whether constitutional or statutory, are ex- tended to corporations, the purpose is to protect the rights of these people.1 In the Supreme Court’s decision in Burwell v. Hobby Lob- by—and more generally in corporate and employment law—the firm as entity is disappearing as a unit of legal analysis. We use the term “firm” in this Article in the sense that Ronald Coase did to describe a form of business organization that or- ders the production of goods and services through use of a sys- tem internal to the enterprise rather than through the use of independent contractors.2 The idea of an “entity” in this sense † Robina Chair in Law, Science and Technology, University of Minneso- ta Law School. †† Curators’ and Edward D. Ellison Professor of Law, University of Mis- souri – Kansas City School of Law. We thank William K. Black, Margaret F. Brinig, Naomi Cahn, Paul Callister, Mary Ann Case, Lynne Dallas, Robert Downs, Max Eichner, Martha Fineman, Barb Glesner Fines, Claire Hill, Brett McDonnell, Amy Monahan, Charles O’Kelley, Hari Osofsky, Irma Russell, Dan Schwarcz, Lynn Stout, and Erik P.M. Vermeulen for their helpful comments on drafts of this Article and Tracy Shoberg and Shiveta Vaid for their research support.
    [Show full text]
  • For Peer Review Journal: Journal of the History of Economic Thought
    Cambridge University Press Dunn's "The Economics of John Kenneth Galbraith" For Peer Review Journal: Journal of the History of Economic Thought Manuscript ID: Draft Manuscript Type: Review Article [email protected] Page 1 of 8 Cambridge University Press 1 2 3 Book Review for the Journal of the History of Economic Thought 4 5 6 7 By Cameron M. Weber, PhD student in economics and history at the New School for Social 8 9 Research and Adjunct Faculty, FIT/SUNY and St. John’s University, New York. 10 11 12 February 2013 13 14 15 Email: [email protected], homepage: cameroneconomics.com 16 17 18 For Peer Review 19 Book reviewed: Stephen P. Dunn. The Economics of John Kenneth Galbraith: Introduction, 20 21 Persuasion and Rehabilitation . (Cambridge, New York, Melbourne, Madrid, Cape Town, 22 23 Singapore, Sao Paulo, Delhi, Dubai, Tokyo, Mexico City: Cambridge University Press, 2010), 24 25 26 pp. xx, 477, US$115.00, ISBN 978-0521-51876-5. 27 28 29 Review: 30 31 32 Stephen Dunn describes this book as having its main goal to show that John Kenneth Galbraith’s 33 34 35 (JKG’s) thought has been under-appreciated by both Post-Keynesians and Institutionalists in the 36 37 history of economic thought. But in reality the book is really of two parts, the first is Dunn’s 38 39 very detailed and engaging description of JKG’s thought without tying-in in any systematic way 40 41 42 followers or precursors, the second is to relate JKG’s influence on those that followed him, 43 44 especially in Post-Keynesian Economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Guide to Further Reading
    Guide to further reading To follow contemporary debates in organisational economics and organisation theory it is necessary to consult the journals, of which there are too many to list. For organisational economics I would recommend the Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. Of more relevance to this book, in terms of airing inter- and intradisciplinary differences, the Journal of Economic Perspectives is better. The leading journals in organisation theory have increasingly given attention to organisational economics. The most important are: Administrative Science Quarterly; Academy of Management Review; Organization Science; and Organization Studies. In addition, the editors of Human Relations are keen on including interdisciplinary work, particularly from sociologists, economists and psychologists. The main emphasis of this guide is not journal articles but edited collections of readings and introductory books. Starting with game theory, Poundstone, The Prisoner's Dilemma (1993), gives a straightforward introduction to, and a history of, the theory. Avoiding the maths again, Dixit and Nalebuff, Thinking Strategically (1991), gives an idea of the applications of game theory. Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (1990), is not only influential, but highly readable. Neoclassical, managerial and behavioural theories of the firm are all dealt with clearly in Sawyer's excellent little book, Theories of the Firm (1979). For more general overviews and explicit critiques of economics, Galbraith ought to be read at some point, and his book, A History of Economics (1987) is better than the many more scholarly histories of economics. Hodgson's Economics and Institutions (1988) is a more difficult and sustained critique of contemporary economics, but he gives considerable attention to organisational economics.
    [Show full text]
  • A Modern Reader in Institutional and Evolutionary Economics : Key Concepts / Edited by Geoffrey M
    A Modern Reader in Institutional and Evolutionary Economics EUROPEAN ASSOCIATION FOR EVOLUTIONARY POLITICAL ECONOMY Series Editor: Geoffrey M. Hodgson, University of Hertfordshire Business School, UK Mixed Economies in Europe: An Evolutionary Perspective on their Emergence, Transition and Regulation Edited by Wolfgang Blaas and John Foster The Political Economy of Diversity: Evolutionary Perspectives on Economic Order and Disorder Edited by Robert Delorme and Kurt Dopfer On Economic Institutions: Theory and Applications Edited by John Groenewegen, Christos Pitelis and Sven-Erik Sjöstrand Rethinking Economics: Markets, Technology and Economic Evolution Edited by Geoffrey M. Hodgson and Ernesto Screpanti Environment, Technology and Economic Growth: The Challenge to Sustainable Development Edited by Andrew Tylecote and Jan van der Straaten Institutions and Economic Change: New Perspectives on Markets, Firms and Technology Edited by Klaus Nielsen and Björn Johnson Pluralism in Economics: New Perspectives in History and Methodology Edited by Andrea Salanti and Ernesto Screpanti Beyond Market and Hierarchy: Interactive Governance and Social Complexity Edited by Ash Amin and Jerzy Hausner Employment, Technology and Economic Needs: Theory, Evidence and Public Policy Edited by Jonathan Michie and Angelo Reati Institutions and the Evolution of Capitalism: Implications of Evolutionary Economics Edited by John Groenewegen and Jack Vromen Is Economics an Evolutionary Science? The Legacy of Thorstein Veblen Edited by Francisco Louçã and Mark Perlman Technology and Knowledge: From the Firm to Innovation Systems Edited by Pier Paolo Saviotti and Bart Nooteboom Evolution and Path Dependence in Economic Ideas: Past and Present Edited by Pierre Garrouste and Stavros Ioannides A Modern Reader in Institutional and Evolutionary Economics: Key Concepts Edited by Geoffrey M.
    [Show full text]
  • Volume 7 Issue 5 + 6 2020
    COSMOS + TAXIS A Galbraithian Perspective on Epistemic Institutionalism and True Liberalism THEODORE BURCZAK Denison University Email: [email protected] Web: https://denison.edu/people/theodore-burczak Near the end of his book on F. A. Hayek, Peter Boettke advocates for a “true liberalism” growing out of Hayek’s the institutional framework that best enables epistemically thought that is “most conducive to human flourishing” limited individuals to strive and flourish. (Boettke 2018, p. 252). A consistent theme in Hayek’s oeu- This is a seriously truncated vision. A “true” liberal rec- vre is a careful investigation of what Boettke calls “epis- ognizes that a “valid image of the modern economy” is not temic institutionalism.” For Boettke, it is Hayek’s explora- one where most individuals are responding to price signals tion of epistemic institutionalism that helps produce this that emerge from competitive markets (Galbraith 2001, p. true liberalism. This short paper sketches a counterargu- 118). People shaping tin are not typically working in a small ment that Hayek’s epistemic institutionalism is hobbled, shop, buying raw material from and selling their product 5 making Hayekian liberalism itself truncated and “false,” directly into the global market. Much more likely, the metal more akin to a species of conservatism. A genuine liberal- worker is employed by a large organization with production ism based on a more thoroughgoing epistemic institution- units spread around the globe, where flows of sheet metal alism is far more progressive than the typical Hayekian is are directed by administered prices and decisions of pur- likely apt to accept. chasing managers.
    [Show full text]
  • Specialization and Trade
    Specialization and Trade 100148_FM.indd 1 5/20/16 9:15 PM 100148_FM.indd 2 5/20/16 9:15 PM Specialization and Trade A RE-INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS Arnold Kling CATO INSTITUTE WASHINGTON, D.C. 100148_FM.indd 3 5/20/16 9:15 PM Copyright © 2016 by Arnold Kling. All rights reserved. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Names: Kling, Arnold S., author. Title: Specialization and trade : a reintroduction to economics : an introduction / Arnold Kling. Description: Washington, D.C. : Cato Institute, [2016] | Includes bibliographical references and index. Identifiers: LCCN 2016017478 (print) | LCCN 2016023070 (ebook) | ISBN 9781944424152 (pbk. : alk. paper) | ISBN 9781944424176 (audiobook : alk. paper) | ISBN 9781944424169 (ebook) Subjects: LCSH: Economics. | Economic specialization. | Interna- tional trade. Classification: LCC HB171 .K545 2016 (print) | LCC HB171 (ebook) | DDC 330—dc23 Printed in the United States of America. CATO INSTITUTE 1000 Massachusetts Ave., N.W. Washington, D.C. 20001 www.cato.org 100148_FM.indd 4 5/20/16 9:15 PM CONTENTS Foreword . vii. Acknowledgments . .ix . Introduction . 1. 1. Filling in Frameworks . 21. 2. Machine as Metaphor . 37. 3. Instructions and Incentives . 51 4. Choices and Commands . .61 . 5. Specialization and Sustainability . .77 . 6. Trade and Trust. 91 7. Finance and Fluctuations . 103. 8. Policy in Practice . 121. 9. Macroeconomics and Misgivings . 135. 10. Concluding Contemplation . .177 . Appendix: How Housing and Mortgage Policy Worked in Practice . .179 . v 100148_FM.indd 5 5/20/16 9:15 PM 100148_FM.indd 6 5/20/16 9:15 PM Foreword Early in 2015, I came across a volume of essays edited by E. Roy Weintraub titled MIT and the Transformation of American Economics.1 After digesting the essays, I thought to myself, “So that’s how it all went wrong.” Let me hasten to mention that my own doctorate in eco- nomics, which I obtained in 1980, comes from MIT.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 February 20, 2015 HAROLD DEMSETZ Arthur Andersen UCLA Alumni Emeritus Professor Emeritus Business Economics Address: Departmen
    February 20, 2015 HAROLD DEMSETZ Arthur Andersen UCLA Alumni Emeritus Professor Emeritus Business Economics Address: Department of Economics, University of California, Los Angeles, California 90095. Telephones: Office: (2l3) 825-365l; Home: (818) 343-8743 Fax: 310-825-9528 (Departmental fax). Education Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois: Ph.D. and M.A. (Economics, l959); MBA (1954) University of Illinois, Urbana, Illinois: B.S. (Economics, l953) Professional Employment Academic Emeritus Professor, UCLA 1994 University of California, Los Angeles, California. Professor, l97l to 1994. Arthur Andersen UCLA Alumni Chair in Business Economics, 1986 to 1995. Director, Economic/Business Program, l983 to 1995. Chairman, Economics Department, l978-l980. Assistant Professor to Associate Professor, 1960-1963. Senior Research Fellow, the Hoover Institution, l97l-l979; Washington University, St. Louis, Missouri Visiting Distinguished Professor, l982-l983. University of Chicago, Chicago, Illinois Associate to full Professor of Economics, Graduate School of Business and the Law School, l963-l97l; visiting Professor, 1990. University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan Instructor to Assistant Professor, Economics Department, l958-l960. Non-academic Consultant to the RAND Corporation, l96l-l962. 1 Scientific Analyst for the Center for Naval Analyses, while on leave from U.C.L.A., l963. Consultant to General Motors, l974. Consultant to ARCO, l976-l985. Honorary Societies and Awards Fellow, American Academy of Arts and Sciences. Honorary Doctorate of Humane Letters, received from Northwestern University 1994 Honorary Doctorate of Social Studies, received from Francisco Marraquinn University 1996 Listed in Great Economists Since Keynes, by Mark Blaugh, l983. Listed in Who=s Who in Economics, Who=s Who in America, Who's Who in the Social Sciences, Who's Who in the West and in other similar directories.
    [Show full text]
  • Walton Hamilton, Amherst, and the Brookings
    WALTON HAMILTON, AMHERST, AND THE BROOKINGS GRADUATE SCHOOL: INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS AND EDUCATION. Malcolm Rutherford University of Victoria (This Draft September 2001) The research for this paper made extensive use of the Brookings Institution Archives, and the Walton Hamilton papers at the Tarlton Law Library at the University of Texas. I also benefited from access to the Archives of the War Labor Policies Board at the National Archives, College Park, Maryland; the Morris A Copeland and Carter Goodrich papers at the Rare Book and Manuscript Library, Columbia University; the Clarence Ayres papers at the Center for American History at the University of Texas; the H. C. Adams and I. Leo Sharfman papers at the Bentley Historical Library, University of Michigan; the Isador Lubin, Rexford Tugwell, and Mordecai Ezekiel papers at the Franklin D. Roosevelt Library, Hyde Park, New York, and the Archives of the Laura Spelman Rockefeller Memorial at the Rockefeller Archive Center, Sleepy Hollow, New York. My thanks also to the Amherst College Archives and Special Collections for information on course offerings, to my research assistant, Cristobal Young, for biographical research, and to Mark Perlman, Robert Whaples, Sherry Kasper, Roger Backhouse, and Julian Reiss for useful information and comments. Any errors are my responsibility. This research has been supported by a Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada Research Grant (project # 410-99-0465). 1 1. Introduction This paper is a small part of a larger project concerning the
    [Show full text]
  • 1 John Dewey's Theory of Democracy and Its
    JOHN DEWEY'S THEORY OF DEMOCRACY AND ITS RELEVANCE TO THE STUDY OF ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL PHENOMENA* Arturo Hermann+ Abstract John Dewey is recognized as one of the most significant figures in American philosophy. His influence extended to economic and social sciences as well, also through his action in the fields of education and culture, where he promoted important reform projects aimed at the development of pluralism and critical thought. Within the ambit of social sciences, Dewey's key contribution lies in removing the concepts of democracy and participation from the limbo of abstraction in which they tended to be confined in previous approaches and in connecting them explicitly to the evolution of economic and social forms. In this way, it becomes possible to analyze the various spheres — in particular, economic, social, scientific, technological, political, psychological and ethical — which, in their complex links, combine to shape the features of culture, democracy and participation in any given context. In this perspective, he highlights the social significance of a systematic integration of a pluralistic scientific method in the cultural framework of society and in the corresponding dynamics of collective action. This analytical approach can help to shed light on the problems and tensions brought about by structural changes, the full comprehension of which requires the study of the corresponding evolutionary interaction between human nature and the characteristics of the cultural system. In this sense, Dewey's approach presents significant points of convergence with important strands of social thought and, in particular, with institutional economics. For this reason, it can offer an interesting perspective for an interdisciplinary and pluralistic study of economic and social phenomena.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 CHICAGO and INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS1 Malcolm Rutherford
    CHICAGO AND INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS1 Malcolm Rutherford University of Victoria 1. Introduction For most economists the terms “Chicago economics” and “institutionalism” denote clearly antithetical approaches to the discipline. Various members of the modern “Chicago School” have made highly dismissive remarks concerning American institutionalism. Coase has commented that American institutionalists were anti-theoretical, and that “without a theory they had nothing to pass on except a mass of descriptive material waiting for a theory, or a fire” (Coase 1984, p. 230). Some of these attitudes have their roots in the interwar period, most obviously in Frank Knight’s bitingly critical attacks on the methodology and policy positions of institutionalist and advocates of the “social control” of business (Knight 1932). Nevertheless, what this presentation seeks to reveal is a much more complex interrelation between institutional and Chicago economics. To fully understand this relationship it is necessary to begin with the early years of the Chicago Department of Economics. 2. Chicago Economics and Institutionalism 1892-1919 The Chicago Department of Political Economy was begun in 1892 with Laurence Laughlin as its head. While Laughlin was extremely conservative in his economic and political views, and very much at odds with the historicist or “new” school influence in American economics, he built a department that was extremely diverse in its interests and had significant representation of those critical of “orthodox” economics (Nef 1934). Most obviously, Laughlin brought Thorstein Veblen with him from Cornell, and shortly thereafter placed him in charge of editing the Journal of Political Economy. As Hodgson has argued (Hodgson 2004), Veblen’s years at Chicago (from 1892 to 1906) were remarkably creative ones.
    [Show full text]