Here Is No Volatility

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Here Is No Volatility Asymptotics of a Two-Scale Sto chastic Volatility Mo del y z J.P. Fouque G. Papanicolaou K.R. Sircar To Jacques-Louis Lions on the occasion of his seventieth birthday Abstract We present an asymptotic analysis of derivative prices arising from a sto chastic volatility mo del of the underlying asset price that incorp orates a separation b etween the short tick-by- tick time-scale of uctuation of the price and the longer less rapid time-scale of volatility uctuations. The mo del includes leverage or skew e ects a negative correlation b etween price and volatility sho cks, and a nonzero market price of volatility risk. The results can be used to estimate the latter parameter, which is not observable, from at-the-money Europ ean option prices. Detailed simulations and estimation of parameters are presented in [6]. 1 Intro duction Sto chastic volatility mo dels have b ecome p opular for derivative pricing and hedging in the last ten years as the existence of a non at implied volatility surface or term-structure has b een noticed and b ecome more pronounced, esp ecially since the 1987 crash. This phenomenon, which is well- do cumented in, for example, [9 , 12 ], stands in empirical contradiction to the consistent use of a classical Black-Scholes constant volatility approach to pricing options and similar securities. However, it is clearly desirable to maintain as many of the features as p ossible that have contributed to this mo del's p opularity and longevity, and the natural extension pursued in the literature and in practice has b een to mo dify the sp eci cation of volatility in the sto chastic dynamics of the underlying asset price mo del. One approach, termed the implied deterministic volatility IDV approach [5, Chapter 8], is to supp ose volatility is a deterministic function of the asset price X : volatility= t; X , so that the t t sto chastic di erential equation mo deling the asset price b ecomes dX = X dt + t; X X dW : t t t t t The function C t; x giving the no-arbitrage price of a Europ ean derivative security at time t when the asset price X = x then satis es the generalized Black-Scholes PDE t 1 2 2 t; xx C + r xC C =0; C + xx x t 2 with r the constant risk free interest rate and with terminal condition appropriate for the contract. This has the nice feature that the market is complete which, in this context, means that the CNRS-CMAP, Ecole Polytechnique, 91128 Palaiseau Cedex France, [email protected]. This work was done while visiting the Department of Mathematics, Stanford University. y Department of Mathematics, Stanford University, Stanford CA 94305, [email protected] z Department of Mathematics, University of Michigan, Ann Arb or MI 48109, [email protected] 1 derivative's risk can theoretically b e p erfectly hedged by the underlying, and there is no volatility risk premium to b e estimated. However, while attempts to infer a lo cal volatility surface from market data by tree metho ds [13 ] or relative-entropy minimization [2 ] or interp olation [15 ] have yielded interesting qualitative prop erties of the risk-neutral probability distribution used by the market to price derivatives such as excess skew and leptokurtosis in comparison to the lognormal distribution, this approach has not pro duced a stable surface that can b e used consistently and with con dence over time. For this reason, we concentrate on the \pure" sto chastic volatility approach of [8 ] reviewed in [16 , Section 1.2] or [3 ], in which volatility is mo deled as an It^o pro cess driven by a Brownian t motion that has a comp onent indep endent of the Brownian motion W driving the asset price. t There has b een a lot of analysis of sp eci c It^o mo dels in the literature [14 , 17 , 7] bynumerical and analytical metho ds, many of which have ignored skew e ects and/or the volatility risk premium for tractability. Our goal [6 ] is to estimate these parameters from market data and to test their stability over time and thus the p otential usefulness of sto chastic volatility mo dels for hedging derivatives. What is to our knowledge new here in comparison with previous empirical work on sto chastic volatility mo dels is our keeping of these two factors, use of high-frequency intraday data, and an asymptotic simpli cation of option prices predicted by the mo del that allows for easy estimation of the volatility risk premium from at-the-money market option prices. The latter exploits the separation of time-scales rst intro duced in this context in [16 ]. It is often observed that while volatility might uctuate considerably over the many months comprising the lifetime of an options contract, it do es not do so as rapidly as the sto ck price itself. That is, there are p erio ds when the volatility is high, followed by p erio ds when it is low. Within these p erio ds, there might be much uctuation of the sto ck price as usual, but the volatility can be considered relatively constantuntil its next \ma jor" uctuation. The \minor" volatility uctuations within these p erio ds are relatively insigni cant, esp ecially as far as option prices, which come from an average of a functional of p ossible paths of the volatility, are concerned. Many authors, for example [1], have prop osed nonparametric estimation of the pricing measure for derivatives. The analysis in [16 ] is indep endent of sp eci c mo deling of the volatility pro cess, but results in bands for option prices that describ e p otential volatility risk in relation to its historical auto correlation decay structure, while obviating the need to estimate the risk premium. However, the market in at-the-money Europ ean options is liquid and its historical data can b e used to estimate 1 this premium . For this reason, we shall attempt this with a mo del that is highly parametric, but complex enough to re ect an imp ortantnumb er of observed volatility features: 1. volatility is p ositive; 2. volatility is rapidly mean-reverting see for example [10 ]; 3. volatility sho cks are negatively correlated with asset price sho cks. That is, when volatility go es up, sto ck prices tend to go down and vice-versa. This is often referred to as leverage [4 ], and it at least partially accounts for a skewed distribution for the asset price that lognormal or zero-correlation sto chastic volatility mo dels do not exhibit. The skew is do cumented in empirical studies of historical sto ck data. 2 Mo del The mo del wecho ose is that volatility is the exp onential of a mean-reverting Ornstein-Uhlenbeck OU pro cess or, equivalently, log is mean-reverting OU. With a suitable initial distribution, t 1 This was suggested to us by Darrell Due. 2 the volatility pro cess is stationary and ergo dic which allows us to use averaging principles to ap- proximate the option price, separating the minor and ma jor uctuations. This mo del has b een considered in [14 ] and it is related to EGARCH mo dels which, as shown in [11 ], are weak approx- imations to the continuous-time di usion. Another mo del that is stationary and can be similarly implemented and analyzed is when is a mean-reverting Feller or Cox-Ingersoll-Ross pro cess [3 ]. t The nal ingredient is to mo del the two time scales describ ed previously. To this end, we intro duce a small parameter " > 0 describing the discrepancy between the scales, and mo del the " volatilityas = , where is exp onential OU. Thus the volatilityisthe pro cess \sp eeded- t t t=" t up" to re ect that there are many ma jor uctuations over the life of the options contract this time scale is O 1 in the usual time-unit of years, but not as many as there are minor It^o uctuations. We de ne Y := log and supp ose it satis es t t ^ dY = m Y dt + dZ t t t " " ^ for constants >0; > 0;m and Z a Brownian motion. Then Y := log is describ ed by t t t " " ^ p = dY dt + m Y dZ t t t " " p where now and have b een replaced by =" and = " to mo del rapid mean reversion and overall ^ variance of order one. Finally, to incorp orate the correlation skew e ect dhW; Z i = dt,we write t p 2 ^ Z = W + 1 Z , where W and Z are indep endent Brownian motions, to arrive at the nal t t t " sto chastic volatility mo del for the sto ck price X t " " " Y " t dX = X dt + e X dW 1 t t t t q " " 2 p 2 m Y dW + 1 dZ dt + dY = t t t t " " Then, by the usual no-arbitrage argument, as detailed for example in [16 , Section 1.3], the Europ ean " call option price C t; x; y satis es y 2 1 xe " 2y 2 " " " " " p C e x C C C + + + + r xC C t xx xy yy x 2 " 2" " p m y C = 0 3 + y " " " + C T ; x; y = x K " where is the market price of volatility risk whichwe assume constant. If C t; x; y satis es this " " " " equation then from It^o's formula C = C t; X ;Y satis es the sto chastic di erential equation t t " " " " " " Y " " " ^ t p p dC =[rC + r X C + C ]dt + e X C dW + C dZ 4 t t x y t x y " " p From this expression we see that an in nitesimal change in the volatility risk = " changes the in nitesimal rate of return of the option by times the change in volatility risk.
Recommended publications
  • Managing Volatility Risk
    Managing Volatility Risk Innovation of Financial Derivatives, Stochastic Models and Their Analytical Implementation Chenxu Li Submitted in partial fulfillment of the Requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY 2010 c 2010 Chenxu Li All Rights Reserved ABSTRACT Managing Volatility Risk Innovation of Financial Derivatives, Stochastic Models and Their Analytical Implementation Chenxu Li This dissertation investigates two timely topics in mathematical finance. In partic- ular, we study the valuation, hedging and implementation of actively traded volatil- ity derivatives including the recently introduced timer option and the CBOE (the Chicago Board Options Exchange) option on VIX (the Chicago Board Options Ex- change volatility index). In the first part of this dissertation, we investigate the pric- ing, hedging and implementation of timer options under Heston’s (1993) stochastic volatility model. The valuation problem is formulated as a first-passage-time problem through a no-arbitrage argument. By employing stochastic analysis and various ana- lytical tools, such as partial differential equation, Laplace and Fourier transforms, we derive a Black-Scholes-Merton type formula for pricing timer options. This work mo- tivates some theoretical study of Bessel processes and Feller diffusions as well as their numerical implementation. In the second part, we analyze the valuation of options on VIX under Gatheral’s double mean-reverting stochastic volatility model, which is able to consistently price options on S&P 500 (the Standard and Poor’s 500 index), VIX and realized variance (also well known as historical variance calculated by the variance of the asset’s daily return).
    [Show full text]
  • Hedging Volatility Risk
    Journal of Banking & Finance 30 (2006) 811–821 www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf Hedging volatility risk Menachem Brenner a,*, Ernest Y. Ou b, Jin E. Zhang c a Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, NY 10012, USA b Archeus Capital Management, New York, NY 10017, USA c School of Business and School of Economics and Finance, The University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong Received 11 April 2005; accepted 5 July 2005 Available online 9 December 2005 Abstract Volatility risk plays an important role in the management of portfolios of derivative assets as well as portfolios of basic assets. This risk is currently managed by volatility ‘‘swaps’’ or futures. How- ever, this risk could be managed more efficiently using options on volatility that were proposed in the past but were never introduced mainly due to the lack of a cost efficient tradable underlying asset. The objective of this paper is to introduce a new volatility instrument, an option on a straddle, which can be used to hedge volatility risk. The design and valuation of such an instrument are the basic ingredients of a successful financial product. In order to value these options, we combine the approaches of compound options and stochastic volatility. Our numerical results show that the straddle option is a powerful instrument to hedge volatility risk. An additional benefit of such an innovation is that it will provide a direct estimate of the market price for volatility risk. Ó 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: G12; G13 Keywords: Volatility options; Compound options; Stochastic volatility; Risk management; Volatility index * Corresponding author.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns
    THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE • VOL. LXI, NO. 1 • FEBRUARY 2006 The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns ANDREW ANG, ROBERT J. HODRICK, YUHANG XING, and XIAOYAN ZHANG∗ ABSTRACT We examine the pricing of aggregate volatility risk in the cross-section of stock returns. Consistent with theory, we find that stocks with high sensitivities to innovations in aggregate volatility have low average returns. Stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility relative to the Fama and French (1993, Journal of Financial Economics 25, 2349) model have abysmally low average returns. This phenomenon cannot be explained by exposure to aggregate volatility risk. Size, book-to-market, momentum, and liquidity effects cannot account for either the low average returns earned by stocks with high exposure to systematic volatility risk or for the low average returns of stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility. IT IS WELL KNOWN THAT THE VOLATILITY OF STOCK RETURNS varies over time. While con- siderable research has examined the time-series relation between the volatility of the market and the expected return on the market (see, among others, Camp- bell and Hentschel (1992) and Glosten, Jagannathan, and Runkle (1993)), the question of how aggregate volatility affects the cross-section of expected stock returns has received less attention. Time-varying market volatility induces changes in the investment opportunity set by changing the expectation of fu- ture market returns, or by changing the risk-return trade-off. If the volatility of the market return is a systematic risk factor, the arbitrage pricing theory or a factor model predicts that aggregate volatility should also be priced in the cross-section of stocks.
    [Show full text]
  • Do Equity Prices Reflect the Ultra-Low Interest Rate Environment?
    27 FEBRUARY 2020 — N O . 1 Do equity prices reflect the ultra-low interest rate environment? Søren Lejsgaard Autrup Jonas Ladegaard Hensch The viewpoints and conclusions stated are the responsibility Principal Economist Economist of the individual contributors, and do not necessarily reflect ECONOMICS AND ECONOMICS AND the views of Danmarks Nationalbank. MONETARY POLICY MONETARY POLICY [email protected] [email protected] ECONOMIC MEMO — DANMARKS NATIONALBANK 27 FEBRUARY 2020 — N O . 1 Do equity prices reflect the ultra-low interest rate environment? The equity risk premium has Investors face a choice when deciding where to about doubled after the financial invest today: Get a certain return on bonds crisis, amid a sharp decline in offering very low or negative returns, or buy a interest rates and an unchanged risky equity and expect to get around 7 per cent per annum, but with downside and upside required return on equities. risks. Before the financial crisis of 2007-08, the trade-off looked different: The expected return The increase in the premium on equities was at the same level, but the entailed a lower pass-through of alternative looked much more favorable with monetary policy rates to the total bond yields around 4 per cent. In other words, financing costs of corporations. the equity risk premium, defined as the That may help to explain why additional return required as compensation for corporate investments have not investing in equities rather than risk-free assets rebounded faster and stronger (bonds), has about doubled to around 7 per after the financial crisis. cent. Still, bonds are in high demand and no major, global rotation between asset classes has taken place so far.
    [Show full text]
  • Risk Management of Investments in Structured Credit Products
    Risk Management of Investments in Structured Credit Products Background A growing number of FDIC-supervised institutions are experiencing deterioration in financial performance as a result of investments in structured credit products.1 The underlying collateral of certain structured credit products has performed poorly. As a result, the level of credit support for senior tranches has diminished, the volume and severity of credit rating downgrades have increased, liquidity has declined, prices are not transparent, and price volatility has increased. Consequently, an increasing number of financial institutions are recognizing other-than-temporary impairment (OTTI) charges and substantial fair value markdowns. Some institutions have invested in structured products in volumes representing concentrations of capital. In some cases, significant purchases were initiated after the credit market turmoil began and, in some cases, funding came from brokered deposits or other volatile funding sources. The FDIC is concerned that financial institutions are not appropriately identifying and controlling the risks inherent in complex structured credit products. Examiners are identifying weaknesses in management’s understanding of product risks, due diligence efforts, portfolio diversification standards, and application of proper accounting standards. Purpose This letter clarifies the application of existing supervisory guidance to structured credit products. Guidance referenced comes primarily from the 1998 “Supervisory Policy Statement on Investment Securities and End-User Derivatives Activities” (Policy Statement), and the “Uniform Agreement on the Classification of Assets and Appraisal of Securities” (Uniform Agreement).2 Topics addressed in this letter include investment suitability and due diligence, the use of external credit ratings, pricing and liquidity, and adverse classification of investment securities. FDIC-supervised institutions should revisit outstanding guidance and incorporate this document’s clarifications into existing policies and processes.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Portfolio Theory, Part One
    Modern Portfolio Theory, Part One Introduction and Overview Modern Portfolio Theory suggests that you can maximize your investment returns, given the amount of risk (or volatility) you are willing to take on. This is the idea to be developed and evaluated during this 10-part series. Part One provides an introduction to the issues. by Donald R. Chambers e are inundated with advice ory” or MPT. The most important advances emerged: efficient market Wregarding investment deci- point of MPT is that diversification theory and equilibrium pricing sions from numerous sources (bro- reduces risk without reducing expected theory. kers, columnists, economists) and return. MPT uses mathematics and Led by Professor Eugene Fama, through a variety of media (televi- statistics to demonstrate diversifica- MPT pioneers established a frame- sion, magazines, seminars). But tion clearly and carefully. work for discussing the idea that the suggested answers regarding This series focuses on relatively security markets are informationally investment decisions not only vary simple and easy-to-implement efficient. This means that secu- tremendously but often rity prices already reflect directly conflict with each MPT does not describe or prescribe invest- available information and other—leaving the typical that it is therefore not investor in a quandary. ing perfectly. But even if it’s not perfect, possible to use available On top of this MPT has major implications that should be information to identify complexity, conditions under-priced or over- change. Markets crash considered by every investor. priced securities. and firms once viewed as In the wake of difficult providing solutions, such as Merrill investment concepts.
    [Show full text]
  • Volatility and the Alchemy of Risk
    Volatility and the Alchemy of Risk Reflexivity in the Shadows of Black Monday 1987 Christopher Cole The Ouroboros, a Greek word meaning ‘tail debt expansion, asset volatility, and financial Artemis Capital Managment devourer’, is the ancient symbol of a snake engineering that allocates risk based on that consuming its own body in perfect symmetry. volatility. In this self-reflexive loop volatility The imagery of the Ouroboros evokes the can reinforce itself both lower and higher. In infinite nature of creation from destruction. The a market where stocks and bonds are both sign appears across cultures and is an important overvalued, financial alchemy is the only way to icon in the esoteric tradition of Alchemy. feed our global hunger for yield, until it kills the Egyptian mystics first derived the symbol very system it is nourishing. from a real phenomenon in nature. In extreme The Global Short Volatility trade now heat a snake, unable to self-regulate its body represents an estimated $2+ trillion in financial temperature, will experience an out-of-control engineering strategies that simultaneously exert spike in its metabolism. In a state of mania, the influence over, and are influenced by, stock snake is unable to differentiate its own tail from market volatility.2 We broadly define the short its prey, and will attack itself, self-cannibalizing volatility trade as any financial strategy that until it perishes. In nature and markets, when relies on the assumption of market stability to randomness self-organizes into too perfect generate returns, while using volatility itself symmetry, order becomes the source of chaos.1 as an input for risk taking.
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity Effects in Options Markets: Premium Or Discount?
    Liquidity Effects in Options Markets: Premium or Discount? PRACHI DEUSKAR1 2 ANURAG GUPTA MARTI G. SUBRAHMANYAM3 March 2007 ABSTRACT This paper examines the effects of liquidity on interest rate option prices. Using daily bid and ask prices of euro (€) interest rate caps and floors, we find that illiquid options trade at higher prices relative to liquid options, controlling for other effects, implying a liquidity discount. This effect is opposite to that found in all studies on other assets such as equities and bonds, but is consistent with the structure of this over-the-counter market and the nature of the demand and supply forces. We also identify a systematic factor that drives changes in the liquidity across option maturities and strike rates. This common liquidity factor is associated with lagged changes in investor perceptions of uncertainty in the equity and fixed income markets. JEL Classification: G10, G12, G13, G15 Keywords: Liquidity, interest rate options, euro interest rate markets, Euribor market, volatility smiles. 1 Department of Finance, College of Business, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, 304C David Kinley Hall, 1407 West Gregory Drive, Urbana, IL 61801. Ph: (217) 244-0604, Fax: (217) 244-9867, E-mail: [email protected]. 2 Department of Banking and Finance, Weatherhead School of Management, Case Western Reserve University, 10900 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland, Ohio 44106-7235. Ph: (216) 368-2938, Fax: (216) 368-6249, E-mail: [email protected]. 3 Department of Finance, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, New York University, 44 West Fourth Street #9-15, New York, NY 10012-1126. Ph: (212) 998-0348, Fax: (212) 995-4233, E- mail: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Two Harbors Investment Corp
    Two Harbors Investment Corp. Webinar Series October 2013 Fundamental Concepts in Hedging Welcoming Remarks William Roth Chief Investment Officer July Hugen Director of Investor Relations 2 Safe Harbor Statement Forward-Looking Statements This presentation includes “forward-looking statements” within the meaning of the safe harbor provisions of the United States Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995. Actual results may differ from expectations, estimates and projections and, consequently, readers should not rely on these forward-looking statements as predictions of future events. Words such as “expect,” “target,” “assume,” “estimate,” “project,” “budget,” “forecast,” “anticipate,” “intend,” “plan,” “may,” “will,” “could,” “should,” “believe,” “predicts,” “potential,” “continue,” and similar expressions are intended to identify such forward-looking statements. These forward-looking statements involve significant risks and uncertainties that could cause actual results to differ materially from expected results. Factors that could cause actual results to differ include, but are not limited to, higher than expected operating costs, changes in prepayment speeds of mortgages underlying our residential mortgage-backed securities, the rates of default or decreased recovery on the mortgages underlying our non-Agency securities, failure to recover certain losses that are expected to be temporary, changes in interest rates or the availability of financing, the impact of new legislation or regulatory changes on our operations, the impact
    [Show full text]
  • Asset Pricing Implications of Volatility Term Structure Risk
    Asset Pricing Implications of Volatility Term Structure Risk CHEN XIE ABSTRACT I find that stocks with high sensitivities to changes in the VIX slope exhibit high returns on average. The price of VIX slope risk is approximately 2.5% annually, statistically significant and cannot be explained by other common factors, such as the market excess return, size, book-to-market, momentum, liquidity, market volatility, and the variance risk premium. I provide a theoretical model that supports my empirical results. The model extends current rare disaster models to include disasters of different lengths. My model implies that a downward sloping VIX term structure anticipates a potential long disaster and vice versa. The current level of market volatility is a standard indicator of market-wide risk. The market volatility term structure, which is calculated from prices of options with different expirations, reflects the market's expectation of future volatility of different horizons. So the market volatility term structure incorporates information that is not captured by the market volatility itself. In particular, the slope of the volatility term structure captures the expected trend in volatility. I investigate in this paper whether the market volatility term structure slope is a priced source of risk. The time-varying market volatility term structure slope reflects changes in expectations of future market risk-return, thus, it should induce changes in the investment opportunity set and should be a state variable. The Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model (ICAPM) of Merton (1973) then predicts that changes in the market volatility term structure must be a priced risk factor in the cross-section of risky asset returns.
    [Show full text]
  • Portfolio Optimization: Thinking Outside the Style Box
    Portfolio Optimization: Thinking Outside the Style Box Asset Allocation, Portfolio Optimization and Optimization Through Hedged Equity By Micah Wakefield, CAIA®, AAMS®, AWMA® February 23, 2017 February 2017 Portfolio Optimization Thinking Outside the Style Box - 2 CONTENTS Revisions 3 Objectives 4 Portfolio Optimization 5 An Alternative Approach to Portfolio Optimization 10 Portfolio Improvement through Hedged Assets 12 Specific Asset Comparisons for Use in Alternative Portfolio Optimization 16 The Defined Risk Portfolio 18 Swan Global Investments | 970-382-8901 | swanglobalinvestments.com February 2017 Portfolio Optimization Thinking Outside the Style Box - 3 REVISIONS A. Initial Release January 31, 2015 Micah J. Wakefield, AWMA®, AAMS® Director of Research and Product Development Swan Global Investments B. Second Release October 1, 2016 Micah J. Wakefield, CAIA®, AWMA®, AAMS® Director of Research and Product Development Swan Global Investments C. Third Release February 23, 2017 Micah J. Wakefield, CAIA®, AWMA®, AAMS® Director of Research and Product Development Swan Global Investments Swan Global Investments | 970-382-8901 | swanglobalinvestments.com February 2017 Portfolio Optimization Thinking Outside the Style Box - 4 OBJECTIVES Swan is focused on helping provide financial advisors with the thought leadership necessary to differentiate themselves and make their businesses stronger and more valuable. The purpose of this document is to highlight our theoretical view that a diversified hedged assets portfolio is a more effective and
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity and Volatility
    Liquidity and Volatility Itamar Drechsler, Alan Moreira, Alexi Savov∗ October 2020 Abstract Liquidity provision is a bet against private information: if private information turns out to be higher than expected, liquidity providers lose. Since information gen- erates volatility, and volatility co-moves across assets, liquidity providers have a neg- ative exposure to aggregate volatility shocks. As aggregate volatility shocks carry a very large premium in option markets, this negative exposure can explain why liquid- ity provision earns high average returns. We show this by incorporating uncertainty about the amount of private information into an otherwise standard model. We test the model in the cross section of short-term reversals, which mimic the portfolios of liquidity providers. As predicted by the model, reversals have large negative be- tas to aggregate volatility shocks. These betas explain their average returns with the same risk price as in option markets, and their predictability by VIX in the time series. Volatility risk thus explains the liquidity premium among stocks and why it increases in volatile times. Our results provide a novel view of the risks and returns to liquidity provision. JEL Codes: Keywords: Liquidity, volatility, reversals, VIX, variance premium ∗Drechsler: University of Pennsylvania and NBER, [email protected]; Moreira: Uni- versity of Rochester, [email protected]; Savov: New York University and NBER, [email protected]. We thank Markus Brunnermeier, Pete Kyle, Mathieu Fournier, Yunzhi Hu, David Schreindorfer, Daniel Schmidt, Mark Westerfield, and Zhaogang Song for discussions; Kent Daniel, Greg Duffie, Ron Kaniel, Bryan Kelly, Maureen O’Hara, and Christian Opp for their comments; as well as partici- pants at NBER Asset Pricing, Cornell, CBOE Derivatives Conference, European Finance Association, Insead Finance Conference, American Finance Association, University of Texas at Austin, Washington University at St.
    [Show full text]