<<

Asymptotics of a Two-Scale Sto chastic Mo del

 y z

J.P. Fouque G. Papanicolaou K.R. Sircar

To Jacques-Louis Lions on the occasion of his seventieth birthday

Abstract

We present an asymptotic analysis of derivative prices arising from a sto chastic volatility

mo del of the underlying asset price that incorp orates a separation b etween the short tick-by-

tick time-scale of uctuation of the price and the longer less rapid time-scale of volatility

uctuations. The mo del includes leverage or skew e ects a negative correlation b etween price

and volatility sho cks, and a nonzero market price of volatility . The results can be used

to estimate the latter parameter, which is not observable, from at-the-money Europ ean option

prices. Detailed simulations and estimation of parameters are presented in [6].

1 Intro duction

Sto chastic volatility mo dels have b ecome p opular for derivative pricing and hedging in the last ten

years as the existence of a non at surface or term-structure has b een noticed

and b ecome more pronounced, esp ecially since the 1987 crash. This phenomenon, which is well-

do cumented in, for example, [9 , 12 ], stands in empirical contradiction to the consistent use of

a classical Black-Scholes constant volatility approach to pricing options and similar securities.

However, it is clearly desirable to maintain as many of the features as p ossible that have contributed

to this mo del's p opularity and longevity, and the natural extension pursued in the literature and

in practice has b een to mo dify the sp eci cation of volatility in the sto chastic dynamics of the

underlying asset price mo del.

One approach, termed the implied deterministic volatility IDV approach [5, Chapter 8], is to

supp ose volatility is a deterministic function of the asset price X : volatility= t; X , so that the

t t

sto chastic di erential equation mo deling the asset price b ecomes

dX = X dt +  t; X X dW :

t t t t t

The function C t; x giving the no-arbitrage price of a Europ ean derivative security at time t when

the asset price X = x then satis es the generalized Black-Scholes PDE

t

1

2 2

 t; xx C + r xC C =0; C +

xx x t

2

with r the constant risk free and with terminal condition appropriate for the contract.

This has the nice feature that the market is complete which, in this context, means that the



CNRS-CMAP, Ecole Polytechnique, 91128 Palaiseau Cedex France, [email protected]. This work

was done while visiting the Department of Mathematics, Stanford University.

y

Department of Mathematics, Stanford University, Stanford CA 94305, [email protected]

z

Department of Mathematics, University of Michigan, Ann Arb or MI 48109, [email protected] 1

derivative's risk can theoretically b e p erfectly hedged by the underlying, and there is no volatility

risk premium to b e estimated.

However, while attempts to infer a lo cal volatility surface from market data by tree metho ds

[13 ] or relative-entropy minimization [2 ] or interp olation [15 ] have yielded interesting qualitative

prop erties of the risk-neutral probability distribution used by the market to price derivatives

such as excess skew and leptokurtosis in comparison to the lognormal distribution, this approach

has not pro duced a stable surface that can b e used consistently and with con dence over time.

For this reason, we concentrate on the \pure" sto chastic volatility approach of [8 ] reviewed in

[16 , Section 1.2] or [3 ], in which volatility  is mo deled as an It^o pro cess driven by a Brownian

t

motion that has a comp onent indep endent of the Brownian motion W driving the asset price.

t

There has b een a lot of analysis of sp eci c It^o mo dels in the literature [14 , 17 , 7] bynumerical and

analytical metho ds, many of which have ignored skew e ects and/or the volatility risk premium

for tractability. Our goal [6 ] is to estimate these parameters from market data and to test their

stability over time and thus the p otential usefulness of sto chastic volatility mo dels for hedging

derivatives. What is to our knowledge new here in comparison with previous empirical work on

sto chastic volatility mo dels is our keeping of these two factors, use of high-frequency intraday

data, and an asymptotic simpli cation of option prices predicted by the mo del that allows for easy

estimation of the volatility risk premium from at-the-money market option prices.

The latter exploits the separation of time-scales rst intro duced in this context in [16 ]. It is

often observed that while volatility might uctuate considerably over the many months comprising

the lifetime of an options contract, it do es not do so as rapidly as the sto ck price itself. That

is, there are p erio ds when the volatility is high, followed by p erio ds when it is low. Within these

p erio ds, there might be much uctuation of the sto ck price as usual, but the volatility can be

considered relatively constantuntil its next \ma jor" uctuation. The \minor" volatility uctuations

within these p erio ds are relatively insigni cant, esp ecially as far as option prices, which come from

an average of a functional of p ossible paths of the volatility, are concerned.

Many authors, for example [1], have prop osed nonparametric estimation of the pricing measure

for derivatives. The analysis in [16 ] is indep endent of sp eci c mo deling of the volatility pro cess, but

results in bands for option prices that describ e p otential volatility risk in relation to its historical

auto correlation decay structure, while obviating the need to estimate the risk premium. However,

the market in at-the-money Europ ean options is liquid and its historical data can b e used to estimate

1

this premium . For this reason, we shall attempt this with a mo del that is highly parametric, but

complex enough to re ect an imp ortantnumb er of observed volatility features:

1. volatility is p ositive;

2. volatility is rapidly mean-reverting see for example [10 ];

3. volatility sho cks are negatively correlated with asset price sho cks. That is, when volatility

go es up, sto ck prices tend to go down and vice-versa. This is often referred to as leverage [4 ],

and it at least partially accounts for a skewed distribution for the asset price that lognormal

or zero-correlation sto chastic volatility mo dels do not exhibit. The skew is do cumented in

empirical studies of historical sto ck data.

2 Mo del

The mo del wecho ose is that volatility is the exp onential of a mean-reverting Ornstein-Uhlenbeck

OU pro cess or, equivalently, log  is mean-reverting OU. With a suitable initial distribution,

t

1

This was suggested to us by Darrell Due. 2

the volatility pro cess is stationary and ergo dic which allows us to use averaging principles to ap-

proximate the option price, separating the minor and ma jor uctuations. This mo del has b een

considered in [14 ] and it is related to EGARCH mo dels which, as shown in [11 ], are weak approx-

imations to the continuous-time di usion. Another mo del that is stationary and can be similarly

implemented and analyzed is when  is a mean-reverting Feller or Cox-Ingersoll-Ross pro cess [3 ].

t

The nal ingredient is to mo del the two time scales describ ed previously. To this end, we

intro duce a small parameter " > 0 describing the discrepancy between the scales, and mo del the

"

volatilityas =  , where  is exp onential OU. Thus the volatilityisthe pro cess \sp eeded-

t t

t="

t

up" to re ect that there are many ma jor uctuations over the life of the options contract this time

scale is O 1 in the usual time-unit of years, but not as many as there are minor It^o uctuations.

We de ne Y := log  and supp ose it satis es

t t

^

dY = m Y dt + dZ

t t t

" "

^

for constants >0; > 0;m and Z a Brownian motion. Then Y := log  is describ ed by

t

t t

" "

^

p

= dY dt + m Y dZ

t

t t

" "

p

where now and have b een replaced by =" and = " to mo del rapid mean reversion and overall

^

variance of order one. Finally, to incorp orate the correlation skew e ect dhW; Z i = dt,we write

t

p

2

^

Z = W + 1  Z , where W and Z are indep endent Brownian motions, to arrive at the nal

t t t

"

sto chastic volatility mo del for the sto ck price X

t

"

" " Y "

t

dX = X dt + e X dW 1

t

t t t

q

" "

2

p

2 m Y dW + 1  dZ dt + dY =

t t

t t

" "

Then, by the usual no-arbitrage argument, as detailed for example in [16 , Section 1.3], the Europ ean

"

call option price C t; x; y  satis es

y 2

1  xe

" 2y 2 " " " " "

p

C e x C C C + + + + r  xC C 

t xx xy yy x

2 " 2"



"

p

m y  C = 0 3 +

y

" "

" +

C T ; x; y  = x K 

"

where  is the market price of volatility risk whichwe assume constant. If C t; x; y  satis es this

" " " "

equation then from It^o's formula C = C t; X ;Y  satis es the sto chastic di erential equation

t t

"

" " " " " Y " " "

^

t

p p

dC =[rC + r X C +  C ]dt + e X C dW + C dZ 4

t t

x y t x y

" "

p

From this expression we see that an in nitesimal change in the volatility risk = " changes the

in nitesimal rate of return of the option by  times the change in volatility risk. This is why  is

called the market price of volatility risk.

3 Asymptotic Analysis

Now, as "  0, the distinction b etween the time scales disapp ears and the ma jor uctuations o ccur

in nitely often. In this limit, volatility can be approximated by a constant as far as averages of 3

functionals of its path are concerned that is, weakly, and we return to the classical Black-Scholes

"

setting. What is of interest is the next term in the asymptotic approximation of C t; x; y  valid

for small ", that describ es the in uence of ;  and the randomness  >0 of the volatility.

" "

To obtain this, let us write 3 as L C = 0, where

1 1

"

p

L + L + L ; L :=

0 1 2

" "

and

2

1 @ @

2

L := + m y  ;

0

2

2 @y @y

2

@ @

y

L :=  xe  ;

1

@x@y @y

2

1 @ @ @

2y 2

+ e x + r x  : L :=

2

2

@t 2 @x @x

Then, constructing an expansion

p

"

C t; x; y =C t; x; y + "C t; x; y +"C t; x; y + ;

0 1 2

we nd, comparing p owers of "<<1,

L C =0

0 0

1

at the O "  level. Since L involves only y -derivatives and is the generator of the OU pro cess

0

Y , its null space is spanned byany nontrivial constant function, and it must b e that C do es not

t 0

dep end on y : C = C t; x.

0 0

1=2

At the next order, O " , wehave

L C + L C =0; 5

1 0 0 1

and since L takes y -derivatives, L C =0. By the same reasoning, 5 implies that C = C t; x.

1 1 0 1 1

Thus, up till O ", the option price do es not dep end on the currentvolatility.

Comparing O 1 terms,

L C + L C =0:

0 2 2 0

Given C t; x, this is a Poisson equation for C t; x; y  and there will b e no solution unless L C

0 2 2 0



is in the orthogonal complement of the null space of L Fredholm Alternative. This is equivalent

0

to saying that L C has mean zero with resp ect to the invariant measure of the OU pro cess. We

2 0

denote this

hL C i =0;

2 0 ou

2

where hi denotes the exp ectation with resp ect to this invariant measure whichis N m;  , where

ou

2 2

 := =2 :

Z

1

2

2 1

 y m =2

p

e f y dy : hf i =

ou

2

1

2

2y

Since C is indep endent of y and L only dep ends on y through the e co ecient, hL C i =

0 2 2 0 ou

hL i C , and

2 ou 0

2

@ @ 1 @

2 2

+ r x hL i = L ^ := + ^ x  ;

2 ou BS

2

@t 2 @x @x

2

2 2y 2m+2

. where ^ := he i = e

ou 4

Thus C t; x = C t; x;^ , and the rst term in the expansion is the Black-Scholes pricing

0 BS

formula with the averaged volatility constant ^ . The  and  havethus far played no role, and we

pro ceed to nd the next term in the approximation, C t; x.

1

Comparing terms of O ", we nd

L C = L C + L C  ; 6

0 3 1 2 2 1

whichwe lo ok at as a Poisson equation for C t; x; y . Just as the Fredholm solvability condition

3

for C determined the equation for C , the solvability for 6 will give us the equation for C t; x.

2 0 1

Substituting for C t; x; y  with

2

1

C = L  L hL i  C ;

2 2 2 ou 0

0

this condition is

E D

1

=0; L C L L  L hL i  C

2 1 1 2 2 ou 0

0

ou

where

hL C i = hL i C = L ^ C

2 1 ou 2 ou 1 BS 1

since C do es not dep end on y .

1

De ning

D E

1

A := L L  L hL i  ;

1 2 2 ou

0

ou

the equation determining C is

1

L ^ C = AC ;

BS 1 0

as C do es not dep end on y .

0

Again, using that L acts only on y -dep endent functions, we can write

0

* ! !+

2 2

@ 1 @ @

y 2

A =  xe ;  y x

2

@x@y @y 2 @x

ou

where

1

2 00 0 2y 2y

L y =  y + m y  y =e he i ;

0 ou

2

and so

2 3

@ @

2 3

+ Bx ; A = Ax

3 2

@x @x

with

1

y 0

A :=  he  i

ou

2



y 0 0

B :=  he  i h i :

ou ou

2

Thus wemust solve

3 2

@ C @ C

BS BS

3 2

L ^ C = Ax ^ +Bx ^ 

BS 1

3 2

@x @x

 

2

=2 d

1

d xe

1

p

p

B A 1+ ; =

^ 2  T t

^ T t

where

1

2

log x=K +r + ^ T t

2

p

d = ;

1

^ T t 5

and where we have used the explicit expression for the Black-Scholes price C ^ . Using the

BS

Green's function for the Black-Scholes PDE, as given for example in [16 , App endix C], and loga-

rithmic transformations to reduce to Gaussian integrals, we nd that

2

d =2

p

1

xe d

1

p

C = A +A B  T t :

1

^

^ 2

Finally,we compute

3m

2e

2 2

9 =2 5 =2 y 0

e e he  i =

ou

2

2

2^

0

h i = ;

ou

and so

2

d =2

p p

1

xe d 

1

2

p

C =  T t T t ; 7 + ^

1

^

^ 2

p

2 2

3m 9 =2 5 =2 "

where := e e e = is a p ositive constant. Note that to order ", C is decreasing

in .

" " "

We can now calculate the implied volatility I de ned by C = C I . Constructing an

BS

p

"

expansion I =^ + "I + ,we nd that

1

 

1

@C t; x;^ 

BS

I = C t; x

1 1

@ ^

d   ^

1

p

; 8 = 1

^

^ T t

which shows that

"   

2 2

2 3 =2  =2

p

K

^ e e

" 1=2 1

p

I =^ + log + O   r T t 2^  ; 9 

" x 2 "

2  T t

2

m+ 2 2

where we have used the expression for ab ove and where ^ = e and  = =2 . We have

1 "

 . also expressed the expansion for I in terms of the inverse of the fast mean reversion rate 

"

For  < 0, which is the usual case, this gives a decreasing implied volatility curve when plotted

against strike price K , that is, a decreasing smirk.

The analysis gives rise to an explicit formula describing the geometry of the implied volatility

surface across strike prices and expiration dates. In particular, the relationship to the risk premium

parameter  in 9 considerably simpli es the pro cedure for its estimation, which otherwise would

b e a computationally-intensiveinverse problem for the PDE 3.

4 Conclusions

We have shown that an incomplete market asset mo deled by a fast mean reverting sto chastic

volatility leads to an asymptotic formula for options pricing and asso ciated implied volatility 9.

This formula involves in a direct way the otherwise unobservable market price of volatility risk

, which can then be estimated by tting it to observed smirks observed implied volatility as a

function of strike price K . The other parameters in the mo del, the mean and variance of the log

2

volatility m and  and the fast mean reversion rate =", can be estimated from historical asset

price data. The remaining parameter of the mo del, the skew , can in principle also b e estimated

from historical asset price data but it is b etter in practice to estimate it by tting formula 9 to

option pricing data, as is done for the market price of volatility risk . This is done in [6 ]. 6

References

}

[1] Y. Ait-Sahalia and A. Lo. Nonparametric estimation of state-price densities implicit in nancial

asset prices. Technical rep ort, Graduate Scho ol of Business, University of Chicago, November

1996.

[2] M. Avellaneda, C. Friedman, R. Holmes, and D. Samp eri. Calibrating volatility surfaces via

relative-entropy minimization. Appl. Math. Finance, 41:37{64, 1997.

[3] C. Ball and A. Roma. Sto chastic Volatility Option Pricing. J. Financial and Quantitative

Analysis, 294:589{607, Decemb er 1994.

[4] F. Black. Studies in sto ck price volatilitychanges. In Proceedings of the 1976 Business Meeting

of the Business and Economic Statistics Section, pages 177{181. Amer. Statist. Asso c., 1976.

[5] D. Due. Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory, 2nd ed. Princeton University Press, 1996.

[6] J.P. Fouque, G. Papanicolaou, and K.R. Sircar. A Two-Scale Sto chastic Volatility Mo del:

Asymptotic Analysis and Estimation. Preprint, 1998.

[7] S. Heston. A closed-form solution for options with Sto chastic Volatility with applications to

b ond and currency options. Review of Financial Studies, 62:327{343, 1993.

[8] J. Hull and A. White. The Pricing of Options on Assets with Sto chastic Volatilities. J.

Finance, XLI I2:281{300, June 1987.

[9] J. Jackwerth and M. Rubinstein. Recovering probability distributions from contemp oraneous

security prices. Early Draft, Octob er 1995.

[10] A. Melino and S.M. Turnbull. Pricing Foreign Currency Options with Sto chastic Volatility.

J. of Econometrics, 45:239{265, 1990.

[11] D.B. Nelson. Arch mo dels as di usion approximations. J. Econometrics, 451-2:7{38,

July/Aug 1990.

[12] M. Rubinstein. Nonparametric Tests of Alternative Option Pricing Mo dels. J. Finance,

XL2:455{480, June 1985.

[13] M. Rubinstein. Implied binomial trees. J. Finance, LXIX3:771{818, July 1994.

[14] L. Scott. Option Pricing when the Variance changes randomly: Theory, Estimation, and an

Application. J. Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 224:419{438, Decemb er 1987.

[15] D. Shimko. Bounds of probability. RISK, 64:33{37, April 1993.

[16] K.R. Sircar and G.C. Papanicolaou. Sto chastic volatility, smile and asymptotics. Submitted

to Applied , April 1997.

[17] E. Stein and J. Stein. Sto ck Price Distributions with Sto chastic Volatility: An Analytic

Approach. Review of Financial Studies, 44:727{752, 1991. 7