Rethinking Development Strategies: Some Lessons from East Asian Experience

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Rethinking Development Strategies: Some Lessons from East Asian Experience Part Two RETHINKING DEVELOPMENT STRATEGIES: SOME LESSONS FROM EAST ASIAN EXPERIENCE Introduction 73 Introduction Rapid growth, rising living standards and in- linkages have added a distinct dimension to the East creased international competitiveness in the Asian growth experience. Following the lead of economies of East Asia have caught the attention the earlier Report, it also examines the role of poli- of policymakers and researchers in other develop- cies in linking exports to investment, as well as in ing regions, as well as in the developed world. A upgrading and diversifying export structures. In broad debate has consequently opened up on the this context, the complementarity between effec- lessons that can be drawn for meeting the wider tive export promotion measures and import challenges of economic development. The region’s substitution policies is examined. Differences performance relative to other regions can no longer among countries in the choice and effectiveness of be regarded as a passing phenomenon. But how policies are explored, as well as those within the such high and sustained rates of growth have been region between the first-tier NIEs and the second- achieved among a large group of economies is still tier ones (Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand). the subject of debate. To date opinion has been divided. On one view, the experience confirms the From this perspective the issue of replicating case for “getting prices right” through the free play East Asian success outside the region comes into of market forces. On another, it points to the lim- sharper focus. Broadly speaking, outward-oriented its of price signals as a guide to the process of development is a dynamic process where invest- capital accumulation and technological catching- ment, imports, exports and industrial upgrading are up, and confirms the benefits to be drawn from closely intertwined. Such a process is consistent appropriate forms of government intervention. with varying degrees of import substitution and Both these interpretations have tended to pose stark export orientation, and with concentration on dif- choices for other developing countries seeking to ferent products and markets. There is thus emulate the East Asian example: the market ver- considerable room for manoeuvre in a pragmatic sus the State; inward- versus outward-oriented approach to development policy in a globalizing development; investment or exports as the engine world, which can accommodate differences in lev- of growth. els of industrial development, natural resource endowments and macroeconomic constraints. This issue of TDR pursues a different line. In TDR 1994 the analysis focused on the links be- Replication by a large number of countries tween capital accumulation, technological progress not only requires the successful pursuit of trade, and economic growth in the first-tier East Asian industrial and technology policies by developing newly industrializing economies (NIEs) - Hong countries, but also open markets in the North. This Kong, Republic of Korea, Singapore and Taiwan in turn will depend upon finding solutions to the Province of China. It examined possible conflicts severe labour market problems which continue to as well as complementarities between the State and beset many advanced industrial economies. As last the market in evolving government-business rela- year, this year’s Report rejects the claim, which tions built around a profit-investment nexus has become louder over the past year, that grow- animated by strategic policy interventions and ap- ing import penetration by developing countries of propriate institutions. Building on that research, their domestic markets is to blame for these prob- this year’s Report emphasizes the interdependence lems, assesses the scope for increased North-South of exports and investment and its role in accelerat- trade, and argues that outward-oriented develop- ing structural change and industrial growth. In ment in the South and expansionary policies in the particular, it considers the extent to which mutu- North provide the basis for a new global policy ally reinforcing regional trade and investment dialogue. 74 Trade and Development Report, 1996 However, there are also new challenges con- shaping the regional integration process. The chap- fronting policymakers in developing countries ter also assesses the implications of recent shifts seeking to emulate the East Asian type of export- in competitiveness for growth and employment in oriented industrialization. In the first place, Japan, as well as for industrialization and devel- compared to the first-tier NIEs, they can certainly opment of the developing countries of the region. expect closer surveillance of their domestic trade Chapter II seeks to account for the success of the and investment policies, which will be subject to East Asian economies in linking a rapid pace of WTO disciplines. The Report assesses from this investment and industrial upgrading to exports. standpoint the new trading environment and the The role of trade and industrial policies in animat- scope for permissible policy alternatives for pro- ing an investment-export nexus is emphasized, and moting industrialization in the South. Moreover, differences in export performance among econo- given the uncertain economic prospects in the ad- mies in the region are related to differences in policy vanced industrial economies, the regional success orientation, including policies relating to FDI and of East Asia not only encourages a fresh look at TNCs. The final chapter examines the issue of rep- the potential gains from South-South economic co- licating the East Asian export performance on a large operation, but also widens the opportunities for scale. In particular, the danger of a “fallacy of com- such cooperation. position” that may arise from widespread efforts to promote low-skill manufactured exports is exam- Chapter I examines the regional dimension of ined, as well as the potential problems such exports East Asian industrialization and growth, concen- might pose for advanced economies. An assess- trating on trade and investment links among ment is also made of whether the post-Uruguay countries. Particular attention is paid to macro- Round trading regime precludes the policies that economic pressures and government policies in underpinned export success in East Asia. Integration and Industrialization in East Asia 75 Chapter I INTEGRATION AND INDUSTRIALIZATION IN EAST ASIA A. The flying geese paradigm During the past two decades, the economic spective roles of policy and markets in this proc- performance of Japan and a small group of rap- ess, and the stability and sustainability of the idly growing East Asian countries, including the process itself. Republic of Korea, Taiwan Province of China, Hong Kong and Singapore (collectively identified In this process, trade is the most important as the first-tier newly industrializing economies, vehicle for transferring new goods and technology NIEs) has attracted considerable attention. More across countries. Imports from the more advanced recently, strong growth in a second tier of (South- countries (senshinkoku) would allow new goods East) Asian industrializing countries (Indonesia, to be introduced into the “follower” countries Malaysia and Thailand) and the re-emergence of (koshinkoku). They would also allow the transfer China in the world economy have added weight to of technology and capital goods needed for their the idea of a wave of industrial development spread- subsequent production in the “follower” economy ing across a much wider region and focused and, eventually, for their export to other countries. attention on East Asia1 as a new growth pole in the Finally, when a country loses competitiveness in a world economy. particular product, its domestic production is phased out and replaced by imports from the “fol- This regional pattern of industrialization, lowers”, which have succeeded in building up a which has not only proceeded in waves but also competitive industry in that product. Thus, this progressively involved a regional division of la- sequence combines the life-cycle of a particular bour based on an industrial and locational product with a dynamic process of shifting com- hierarchy, has been dubbed as a “flying geese de- parative advantage. The outcome is a constantly velopment paradigm.”2 This paradigm provides a evolving regional division of labour within a group description of the life-cycles of various industries of economies all striving for the common goal of in the course of economic development and of the industrialization. relocation of industries from one country to an- other through trade and foreign direct investment More recently emphasis has been placed on (FDI) in response to shifts in competitiveness.3 FDI as an additional channel for “recycling com- However, there is more at stake in the flying geese parative advantage”. On this view, FDI both shapes paradigm than pure description. The significance and is shaped by the evolution of comparative ad- of the paradigm lies in its analysis of the linkages vantage between the follower countries and the lead between the different countries in a regional hier- country. Domestic investment withdraws from archy, the mechanisms by which development is those sectors suffering from loss of competitive- transmitted from one country to another, the re- ness (e.g. labour-intensive sectors such as textiles 76 Trade and Development Report, 1996 Box 4 THEORIES OF TRADE AND
Recommended publications
  • SWUTC/09/167861-1 the US-Brazil-China Trade and Transportation Triangle
    Technical Report Documentation Page 1. Report No. 2. Government Accession No. 3. Recipient's Catalog No. SWUTC/09/167861-1 4. Title and Subtitle 5. Report Date March 2009 The U.S.-Brazil-China Trade and Transportation Triangle: 6. Performing Organization Code Implications for the Southwest Region 7. Author(s) 8. Performing Organization Report No. Dr. Leigh B. Boske and John C. Cuttino Report 167861 9. Performing Organization Name and Address 10. Work Unit No. (TRAIS) Center for Transportation Research University of Texas at Austin 11. Contract or Grant No. 3208 Red River, Suite 200 10727 Austin, Texas 78705-2650 12. Sponsoring Agency Name and Address 13. Type of Report and Period Covered Southwest Region University Transportation Center Texas Transportation Institute Texas A&M University System 14. Sponsoring Agency Code College Station, Texas 77843-3135 15. Supplementary Notes Supported by general revenues from the State of Texas. 16. Abstract The advent of globalization and more integrated international trade has placed increased demands on transportation infrastructure. This report assesses the impacts of triangular trade between and among the United States, Brazil and China with an emphasis on the effects on the U.S. Southwest region. Triangular trade is viewed through a trade corridor analysis of the three sets of bilateral trading relationships. Special emphasis is given to the transportation services that delimit the capacity to carry out triangular trade with particular attention to the latest developments in services and schedules. While international trade trend analysis may point to China’s explosive consumption of raw materials from the U.S. and Brazil, this report also signals the increasing Chinese presence in the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The Dominican Republic's Trade, Policies, and Effects in Historical Perspective
    Trading development or developing trade? The Dominican Republic’s trade, policies, and effects in historical perspective* LETICIA ARROYO ABAD Profesora asistente del Department of Economics and in the International Politics & Economics, Middlebury College (EEUU). Correo electrónico: [email protected]. La autora es Licenciada en Economía de la Universidad Católica Argentina. Magister en estudios latinoa- mericanos de la University Of Kansas (EEUU). Doctora en economía con especialización en historia económica latinoamericana de la University of California, Davis (EEUU). Entre sus publicaciones tenemos: “Persistent Inequality? Trade, Factor Endowments, and Inequality in Republi- can Latin America”Journal of Economic History 73-1 (2012); y “Between Conquest and Independence: Living Standards in Spanish Latin America”, Explorations in Economic History, 49-2 (2012). Entre sus intereses se encuentran los temas de historia económica latinoamericana, los estudios sobre los estándares de vida, desigualdad e instituciones. AMELIA U. SANTOS-PAULINO Afiliada institucionalmente a la United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (Suiza). Correo electrónico: [email protected]. La autora es Licenciada en Eco- nomía de la Pontificia Universidad Católica Madre y Maestra (República Dominicana) y Doctora en Economía de la University of Kent (Reino Unido). Tenemos entre sus publi- caciones recientes: “Can Free Trade Agreements Reduce Economic Vulnerability?,” South African Journal of Economics Vol. 74, 4 (2011) y “The Dominican Republic Trade Policy Review 2008,” The World Economy Vol. 33,11 (2010). Sus líneas de investigación son: comercio exterior y desarrollo económico. Recibido: 30 de noviembre de 2012 Aprobado: 03 de abril de 2013 Modificado: 15 de mayo de 2013 Artículo de investigación científica * El presente artículo es resultado del proyecto de investigación “Long-term economic growth and 209 development”; financiada por la Foundation and the American Philosophical Society, (EEUU).
    [Show full text]
  • Balance Trade
    SECTION 2 • CHAPTER 4 Balance trade In this Oct. 18, 2011 photo, crew members look on as containers are offloaded from the cargo ship Stadt Rotenburg at Port Everglades in Fort Lauderdale. AP PHOTO/WILFREDO LEE oods and services trade—exports plus imports—now account for nearly one-third of overall U.S. economic Gactivity,2 meaning trade’s importance to the economy has never been greater. The United States is the world’s largest exporter,3 with exports directly supporting an estimated 9.7 million jobs.4 At the same time, the United States is also the world’s largest importer, and herein lies the problem. Over the past 30 years, our trade balance has been shifting in the wrong direction—toward more imports than exports—and reached a $560 billion deficit in 2012.5 While imports can be a boon to U.S. economic ing also carry offsetting costs, including job productivity and American living standards, losses domestically. Second, in order to pay providing consumers and business with for the imports from abroad that exceed U.S. access to a larger variety of goods and ser- exports, the U.S. economy must balance this vices at lower costs than would otherwise be trade deficit by selling assets—stocks, bonds, the case, there is also a price to pay. and other assets such as companies and real estate—to overseas purchasers. Mounting trade deficits present two key problems for the U.S. economy. First, the Our trade imbalance has resulted from a economic benefits made possible by import- number of factors.
    [Show full text]
  • U.S. Protectionism and Trade Imbalance Between the U.S. and Northeast Asian Countries1
    INTERNATIONAL ORGANISATIONS RESEARCH JOURNAL. Vol. 13. No 2 (2018) U.S. Protectionism and Trade Imbalance between the U.S. and Northeast Asian Countries1 S.-C. Park Sang-Chul Park – Doctor, Professor, Graduate School of Knowledge Based Technology and Energy, Korea Polytechnic University; 2121, Jeongwang-Dong, Siheung-City, Gyeonggi-Do, 429-793, Korea; E-mail: [email protected] Abstract Trade growth has slowed since the global financial crisis. In 2016, growth in the volume of world trade was 1.9%, down from the 2.8% increase registered in 2015. Imports to developed countries will be moderate in 2017, while demand for imported goods in developing Asian economies could continue to rise. Despite rising imports into Asia, the ratio of trade growth in the world has been lower than the ratio of global economic growth since 2013. Therefore, many countries have tried to create bilateral, multilateral, regional and mega free trade agreements (FTAs) in order to boost their trade volumes and economic growth. East Asian countries try to build regional FTAs and participate in different mega FTAs such as the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP) and the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP). As a result, their economic interests are rather deeply divided and are related to political and security issues in the East Asian context. At the same time, the protectionism led by the Trump administration in the U.S. stands in contrast to the approach taken by East Asian countries. This paper deals with this development and explores why the U.S. has turned from free and open trade toward so-called fair trade based on a policy of “America first.” It also offers an analysis of the reasons for trade imbalances between the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Managed Trade and Quantitative Restrictions: Issues for Congress
    Updated December 14, 2020 Managed Trade and Quantitative Restrictions: Issues for Congress Background governments often use different types of QRs to achieve Congress plays a prominent role in shaping U.S. trade their trade policy objectives (Table 1). policy, due in part to trade policy’s impact on the overall health of the U.S. economy and specific sectors, the success Table 1. Quantitative Restrictions on Trade of U.S. businesses and workers, and Americans’ standard of Quantitative restrictions (QRs) on trade in goods are living. The Trump Administration and some Members of measures that limit the quantity of a product that may be Congress contend that past trade negotiations and imported or exported. They may be based on the number of agreements have failed to address effectively foreign units, weight, volume, and value. Major types of QRs include: protectionist practices and enhance reciprocal market access Prohibitions. Bans on the importation or exportation of for U.S. firms and workers. They cite as evidence the a product; such provisions may be absolute or disruption of some U.S. industries, difficulties of U.S. firms conditional. in penetrating some foreign markets, and large U.S. merchandise trade deficits—even with countries with which Quotas. Measures indicating the quantity that may be the United States has a free trade agreement. They argue imported or exported; quotas can be global or bilateral. that the main goals of U.S. trade policy should be to Licensing requirements. Procedures that require an achieve “fair” and “balanced” trade and to place more application or document (other than that required for emphasis on measurable results (e.g., increased exports and customs purposes) as a prior condition for importation.
    [Show full text]
  • The Causes of the U.S. Trade Deficit
    The Causes of the U.S. Trade Deficit Statement of Robert A. Blecker, Ph.D. Professor of Economics American University and Visiting Fellow Economic Policy Institute Before the Trade Deficit Review Commission Washington, DC August 19, 1999 Executive Summary • There is a long-term worsening trend in the U.S. trade balance since the 1960s, which is due to persistent trade barriers abroad and declining competitiveness of U.S. producers. This long-term deterioration in U.S. trade performance requires either a continuous depreciation of the dollar, or else slower growth in the U.S. compared with our trading partners, in order to avoid rising trade deficits. • There has also been a short-term surge in the U.S. trade deficit in the last few years, which is due to two main factors: a rise in the value of the dollar and slow growth in our trading partners. This situation has been exacerbated by macroeconomic and financial policies of the U.S. government, the International Monetary Fund, and the governments of our major trading partners, including (but not limited to) the policy responses to the recent financial crisis in the emerging market countries. • With the hindsight of the 1990s, we can see that the trade deficit is not a “twin” of the budget deficit, as it appeared to be briefly in the early 1980s. More broadly, we should be suspicious of arguments that always blame trade deficits on low national savings, based on the “identity” between the trade balance and the saving-investment gap. This identity does not prove causality, and is consistent with other causal stories about the trade deficit including those advocated here.
    [Show full text]
  • ASEAN Moves Toward Greater Regional Cooperation in the Face of the EC and NAFTA Deborah A
    American University International Law Review Volume 9 | Issue 3 Article 4 1994 Out of Others' Shadows: ASEAN Moves Toward Greater Regional Cooperation in the Face of the EC and NAFTA Deborah A. Haas Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.wcl.american.edu/auilr Part of the International Law Commons Recommended Citation Haas, Deborah A. "Out of Others' Shadows: ASEAN Moves Toward Greater Regional Cooperation in the Face of the EC and NAFTA." American University International Law Review 9, no. 3 (1994): 809-867. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Washington College of Law Journals & Law Reviews at Digital Commons @ American University Washington College of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in American University International Law Review by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons @ American University Washington College of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. OUT OF OTHERS' SHADOWS: ASEAN MOVES TOWARD GREATER REGIONAL COOPERATION IN THE FACE OF THE EC AND NAFTA Deborah A. Haas* INTRODUCTION In January 1992, the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN or Association) pledged to strengthen economic, political, and security ties among its members.' To achieve these goals, the ministers proposed the creation of an ASEAN Free Trade Agreement (AFTA).2 ASEAN's so-called "mini dragons,"' feeling threatened by potential protectionist * J.D., 1994, Washington College of Law, The American University. 1. ASEAN is the acronym for the Association of Southeast Asian Nations. The Association of Southeast Asian Nations Declaration (Bangkok Declaration), Aug. 8, 1967, Indon.-Malay.-PhiU.-Sing.-Thail., reprinted in 6 I.L.M.
    [Show full text]
  • C the Design of International Trade Agreements
    C THE DESIGN OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS In Section B we discussed a range of reasons why nations may share an interest in cooperating with one another in trade matters. In this section we extend the analysis to examine fundamental issues of treaty design, focusing on two main questions. First, what are the core rules that any good trade agreement must contain so as to reap the envisaged benefits from cooperation? Second, how does the creation of a formal organization (or institution) ensure the effectiveness of rules and foster the objectives of an agreement? The Section begins (Section 1) by asking why institutions1 may be needed along with the rules that make up an agreement. We then go on to examine what specific rules trade agreements must have to realize the benefits of cooperation. Among the principal rules discussed here are those on reciprocal liberalization (Section 2), the preservation of gains from market access commitments (Section 3), contingency protection (Section 4), enforcement (Section 5), and transparency (Section 6). International trade agreements typically include more rules than these, but we have selected those we consider to be among the most important. Relevant provisions in GATT 1994, the WTO Agreement and regional trade agreements will be used to illustrate the expression of these rules. 1. THE ROLE OF INSTITUTIONS Signatories to trade agreements typically confer some authority on an independent agent in the belief that a neutral or internationalized body is more effective in governing trading relations than the signatories themselves. In what follows, we shall attempt to link institutional necessity back to the earlier discussion of the various rationales for trade agreements.
    [Show full text]
  • Topic 3: the Ricardian (Classical) Trade Model
    Topic 3: the Ricardian (Classical) trade model Ricardian model: introduction This will be our first theoretical model that explains our basic questions: What do countries trade? (comparative advantage) What are the gains from trade (GFT)? Do both (all) countries GFT? Before starting the model, let’s consider three (false) common propositions you may hear about international trade. The first two: (1) “Wealthy, high-wage countries cannot afford to trade with low-wage developing countries because their low wage costs would allow them to produce most goods more cheaply and drive firms in richer countries out of business.” We need protection from low-wage imports to avoid seeing our wages brought down to their level. (2) “Low-wage developing countries cannot afford to trade with high-wage countries because labor in those countries is so much more productive because of skills, capital, and technological superiority that they would produce most goods more cheaply and drive LDC firms out of business.” Ricardian model: introduction Which is it? They can’t both be true, even though both are commonly heard in the media and policy circles. The fallacy with both is that they look at only one component of production costs: wages on the one hand and productivity on the other. But productivity and wages (also exchange rates, capital costs, and many other factors) combine to determine unit costs. The US can trade with Mexico or Vietnam to our mutual advantage, because we’re much better at producing some goods (better enough to pay for the high wages) and only a little better at others, so low wages matter there.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of International Migration on International Trade: an Empirical Study of Australian Migrant Intake from Asian Countries
    THE IMPACT OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY OF AUSTRALIAN MIGRANT INTAKE FROM ASIAN COUNTRIES Sidney Mankit LUNG B. Bus. (Hons.) International Trade, Victoria University This thesis is submitted in total fulfilment of the requirements of the degree of Doctor of Philosophy School of Applied Economics Faculty of Business and Law Victoria University Melbourne Australia May 2008 ABSTRACT In the context of established international economic theory, it is well known that international trade of commodities is effectively trading factors of production such as labour and capital. It follows that if factors of production can be moved internationally, then the need for commodity trade is eased, and trade of commodities and movements of factors of production can be substituted for each other. From this, the conclusion can be reached that factor movement is a substitute for commodity trade. Allowing people to migrate from one country to another country involves migration of labour – the movement of a factor of production. The conclusion that factor flows are a substitute for commodity-trade can be re-stated as international immigration is a substitute for international trade. However, this conclusion does not explain the real world in which both international trade and international immigration have increased over time. Thus, established theory of immigration and trade may not be a reliable policy guide for formulating immigration and/or trade policy. It is the purpose of this thesis to formulate an alternative theory, which more effectively explains the relationship between immigration and trade. For the purpose of distinguishing the impact of immigrants on trade from the impact of other factors on trade, this thesis employs a two-step approach.
    [Show full text]
  • A Collection of Financial Keywords and Phrases
    A Collection of Financial Keywords and Phrases Abbreviations: CCCN: Customs Cooperation Council Nomenclature CPI: Consumer price index EC: European Communities ECU: European Currency Unit EEC: European Economic Community EU: European Union LDC: Least Developed Country FDI: Foreign Direct Investment FIR: Factor intensity reversal FTA: Free trade area GATT: General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade GDP: Gross domestic product GMO: Genetically modified organism ICA: International commodity agreement ITA: International Trade Administration ITC: International Trade Commission NAFTA: North American Free Trade Agreement NGO: Non-governmental organization NIC: Newly Industrializing Country NTB: Nontariff barrier MNC: Multinational Corporation MNE: Multinational Enterprise OECD: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development SDR: Special Drawing Right TRIP: Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights UNCTAD: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development VER: Voluntary export restraint WTO: World Trade Organization Abandonment value: The value of a project if the project's assets were sold externally; or alternatively, its opportunity value if the assets were employed elsewhere in the firm. ABC method of inventory control: Method that controls expensive inventory items more closely than less expensive items. Absolute advantage: The ability to produce a good at lower cost, in terms of labor, than another country. An absolute advantage exists when a nation or other economic region is able to produce a good or service more efficiently than a second nation or region. Absolute-priority rule: The rule in bankruptcy or reorganization that claims of a set of claim holders must be paid, or settled, in full before the next, junior, set of claim holders may be paid anything. Absorption and balance of trade: Total demand for goods and services by all residents (consumers, producers, and government) of a country (as opposed to total demand for that country's output).
    [Show full text]
  • THE STANDARD MODEL ASSUMPTIONS General Formulation Combining Features of Various Specific Models Studied So Far Two Goods That C
    ECO 352 – Spring 2010 No. 10 – Mar. 4 THE STANDARD MODEL ASSUMPTIONS General formulation combining features of various specific models studied so far Two goods that can be traded. Bowed-out production possibility frontier. Constant returns to scale; details of factors and production kept in the background. Factors cannot be traded across national borders. Identical homothetic preferences; exact aggregation possible. Country's demands can be found using same indifference curves as “social ICs” Perfectly competitive markets. Two countries, Home and Foreign. Notation: Goods X and Y. Prices PX and PY . Relative price of X is P = PX / PY . Superscript labels: Home none, Foreign * . Autarky A, Free trade T 1 ONE COUNTRY IN AUTARKY Two equivalent representations PPF and social optimum Relative supply and demand P / P XY Y Country’s indiff. curve RS A (P / P ) X Y PPF A RD slope P = P / P XY X X/Y 2 SMALL HOME COUNTRY TRADING WITH GIVEN WORLD RELATIVE PRICE If world relative price of X is If world relative price of X is higher than the Home country's lower than the Home country's autarkic rel. price, Home exports X autarkic rel. price, Home imports X slope = world P / P X Y Y Y slope = world P / P TC X Y TP TC A A TP X X (In each case, TP is production point, TC consumption point, under trade.) In both cases, Home country gains from trade! (TC on higher IC than A) 3 [1] Observe the distinct economic adjustments that bring about this gain: Production shifts toward the good whose relative price is now higher Consumption substitutes away from the good whose relative price is now higher (but income effect may enable higher quantity consumption of both goods) Magnitudes of these adjustments will depend on (check earlier specific models) preferences – elasticity of substitution in demand technology – fixed coefficient versus input substitution factor specificity – length of the run over which adjustment can occur Country utility [2] Country's aggregate utility is U-shaped function of PX / PY , and minimum in autarky! This is just another way to think about gains from trade.
    [Show full text]